Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The long time scales of the climate–economy feedback and the climatic cost of growth

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This paper is based on the perception that the inertia of climate and socio-economic systems are key parameters in the climate change issue. In a first part, it develops and implements a new approach based on a simple integrated model with a particular focus on an innovative transient impact and adaptation modeling. In a second part, a climateeconomy feedback is defined and characterized. The following results were found. 1) It has a long characteristic time, which lies between 50 and 100 years depending on the hypotheses; this time scale is long when compared to the system's other time scales, and the feedback cannot act as a natural damping process of climate change. 2) Mitigation has to be anticipated since the feedback of an emission reduction on the economy can be significant only after a 20-year delay and is really efficient only after at least 50 years. 3) Even discounted, production changes due to an action on emissions are significant over more than one century. 4) The methodology of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), which neglects the feedback from impacts to emissions, is acceptable up to 2100, whatever is the level of impacts. This analysis allows also to define a climatic cost of growth as the additional climate change damages due to the additional emissions linked to economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. More information on the TEF/ZOOM approach and its applications can be found at http://www.lmd.jussieu.fr/ZOOM.

  2. It has already been mentioned that this article does not aim at providing an assessment of the climate change damages but aims at improving our understanding of the coupling processes between climate and economy.

  3. Temperatures should here be understood as climate indexes, measuring the mean state of climate.

  4. This scenario can be interpreted as a scenario in which the impacts of a given climate change are twice as high as in the ‘moderate impacts’ case, but also as a scenario in which the climate sensitivity is twice as high and the impacts of a given climate change are unchanged.

  5. http://www.lmd.jussieu.fr/ZOOM.

  6. Note that if a step function is here used as the perturbation of the model, the relationship (26) allows to build the response of the model to any other kind of perturbations.

  7. Here we assume a strictly positive discount rate. About the use of zero discount rate, see Haurie [22].

  8. Note that the system is linearized around its current state, not around a reference trajectory.

  9. ZOOM is a TEF-dedicated solver developed by authors and colleagues.

References

  1. W. Nordhaus, To slow or not to slow: The economics of the Greenhouse Effect, Econ. J. 101 (1991) 920–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. W. Cline, The Economics of Global Warming (Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  3. R. Mendelsohn and J. Neumann, The Impact of Climate Change on the United States Economy (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  4. S. Fankhauser and R. Tol, On climate change and economic growth, Resour. Energy Econ. 27 (2005) 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. R. Tol, New estimates of the damage costs of climate change: part II. Dynamic estimates, Environ. Resour. Econ. 21(2) (2002) 135–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. J. Green, Division of radiative streams into internal transfer and cooling to space, Q. J. Royal Meteorol. Soc. 93 (1967) 371–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. M. Cherkaoui, J. Dufresne, R. Fournier, J. Grandpeix and A. Lahellec, Monte-Carlo simulation of radiation in gases with a narrow-band model and a net-exchange formulation, J. Heat Transfer. 118 (1996) 401–407.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  8. S. Hallegatte, A. Lahellec and J.-Y. Grandpeix, The characterization of the water feedback in climate change with the use of a 0D model. J. Atmos. Sci. 2005 (submitted).

  9. IPCC, in: Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis, eds. J.T. Houghton, Y. Ding, D.J. Griggs, M. Noguer, P.J. Van der Linden, X. Dai, K. Maskell and C.A. Johnson (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  10. R. Solow, A contribution to the theory of economic growth, Q. J. Econ. 70(1) (1956) 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. W. Nordhaus, Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change (MIT, Cambridge, 1994).

    Google Scholar 

  12. IPCC, in: Special Report on Emissions Scenarios, eds. N. Nakicenovic and R. Swart (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  13. IPCC, in: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability, eds. J.J. McCarthy, O.F. Canziani, N.A. Leary, D. Dokken and K.S. White (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  14. J. Gallup, J. Sachs and A. Mellinger, Geography and Economic Development. CID Working Paper 1 (Harvard Center for International Development, Cambridge, 1999).

  15. P.D. Cox, R. Betts, C. Jones, S. Spall and I. Totterdell, Acceleration of global warming due to carbon-cycle feedback in a coupled climate model, Nature 408 (2000) 184–187.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  16. P. Friedlingstein, J.-L. Dufresne, P. Cox and P. Rayner, How positive is the feedback between climate change and the carbon cycle, Tellus 55B(2) (2003) 692–700.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  17. R. Tol, The damage costs of climate change towards a dynamic representation, Ecol. Econ. 19 (1996) 67–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. S. Fankhauser, J. Smith and R. Tol, Weathering climate change. Some simple rules to guide adaptation investments, Ecol. Econ. 30(1) (1999) 67–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. R. Tol, New estimates of the damage costs of climate change: part I. Benchmark estimates, Environ. Resour. Econ. 21(1) (2002) 47–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. P. Ambrosi, J.-C. Hourcade, S. Hallegatte, P. Lecocq, P. Dumas and M. Ha Duong, Optimal control models and elicitation of attitudes towards climate damages, Environ. Model. Assess. 8(3) (2003) 133–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. H. Bode, Network Analysis and Feedback Amplifier Design (Van Nostrand, New York, 1945).

    Google Scholar 

  22. A. Haurie, Turnpike in multi-discount rate environment and GCC policy evaluation. NCCR Working Paper (2002) 4–10.

  23. J.W.H. Liu, The multifrontal method for sparse matrix solution: Theory and practice, SIAM Rev. 34 (1992) 82–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author wishes to thank Alain Lahellec, Jean-Yves Grandpeix and Robert Franchisseur for their support, together with Patrice Dumas, Frédéric Ghersi, Jean-Charles Hourcade and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and remarks. The remaining errors are entirely the author's.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stéphane Hallegatte.

Appendices

Appendix A: The transfer evolution formalism A.1 Tangent linear system analysis

As explained in the article, the model is mathematically represented by a set of equations of two kinds:

  1. 1.

    cells:

    $$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } }}{{\partial t}} = G_{\alpha } {\left( {\eta _{\alpha } ,\varphi _{1} ,\varphi _{2} , \ldots } \right)}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial \eta _{\beta } }}{{\partial t}} = G_{\beta } {\left( {\eta _{\beta } ,\varphi _{1} ,\varphi _{2} , \ldots } \right)}} \hfill} \\ { \ldots \hfill} \\ \end{array} $$
    (A‐1)
  2. 2.

    transfers:

    $$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\varphi _{1} = f_{1} {\left( {\eta _{\alpha } ,\eta _{\beta } , \ldots ,\varphi } \right)}} \hfill} \\ {{\varphi _{2} = f_{2} {\left( {\eta _{\alpha } ,\eta _{\beta } , \ldots ,\varphi } \right)}} \hfill} \\ { \ldots \hfill} \\ \end{array} $$
    (A‐2)

Let η be the state vector of the complete system and φ be the vector of the dependent boundary conditions. With initial conditions at time t 0, the system is a well-posed problem.

The method consists in building the first-order development of the dynamical system around its current stateFootnote 8 [η(t n )]. For each cell α, it reads:

$$\frac{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)}}}{{\partial t}} = \frac{{\partial {\left( {\eta _{\alpha } {\left( {t_{n} } \right)} + \delta \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)}} \right)}}}{{\partial t}} = G_{\alpha } {\left( {\eta _{\alpha } {\left( {t_{n} } \right)},\varphi {\left( {t_{n} } \right)}} \right)} + {\left( {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } }}}} } \right)}{\left( {\eta _{\alpha } {\left( {t_{n} } \right)},\varphi {\left( {t_{n} } \right)}} \right)}\delta \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)} + {\left( {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \varphi }}}} } \right)}{\left( {\eta _{\alpha } {\left( {t_{n} } \right)},\varphi {\left( {t_{n} } \right)}} \right)}\delta \varphi {\left( t \right)} + {\user1{\mathcal{O}}}{\left( {{\left( {t - t_{n} } \right)}^{2} } \right)}$$
(A‐3)

where \(\delta \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)} = \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)} - \eta _{\alpha } {\left( {t_{n} } \right)}\) and δφ(t) = φ(t) − φ(t n ).

The tangent linear system (TLS) corresponding to system (A-3) is, for each cell α:

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\frac{{\partial {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)}}}{{\partial t}} = G_{\alpha } \left| {_{{t_{n} }} } \right. + \left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)} + \left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \varphi }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi {\left( t \right)}}} \\ {{{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi {\left( t \right)} = {\sum\nolimits_\beta {\left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial f}}{{\partial \eta _{\beta } }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\beta } {\left( t \right)} + \left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial f}}{{\partial \varphi }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi {\left( t \right)}} }}} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(A‐4)

where the suffix β sweeps the list of subdomains.

We approximate the true time evolution of the model \({\left( {\delta \eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)}{\text{ }}and{\text{ }}\delta \varphi {\left( t \right)}} \right)}\) by \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\alpha } {\left( t \right)}\) and \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi {\left( t \right)}\), the TLS solutions, respectively, since they differ only by \({\user1{\mathcal{O}}}{\left( {{\left( {t - t_{n} } \right)}^{2} } \right)}\).

In formulation (A-4), the Jacobian matrices appear to contain critical information for the analysis of the interactions between variables. The TLS can be solved by various methods, including Laplace transforms. Rather than Laplace transformation, we shall use the more convenient Borel transformation defined by:

$$f{\left( t \right)}\xrightarrow{{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}}{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ f \right]}{\left( \tau \right)} = \frac{1}{\tau }{\int_0^\infty {{\text{e}}^{{ - t \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {t \tau }} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} \tau }} f{\left( t \right)}\operatorname{d} t} } = \frac{1}{\tau }\widetilde{f}{\left( {\frac{1}{\tau }} \right)}$$
(A‐5)

where \(\widetilde{f}{\left( p \right)}\) stands for the Laplace transform of f(t). Contrary to the Laplace variable, the Borel variable τ is real and homogeneous with time.

Because \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\partial f} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial f} {\partial t}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial t}} \right]} = {\left( {1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \tau }} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} \tau } \right)}{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ f \right]}\), the Borel transform of equation (A-4) reads:

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\alpha } } \right]} = {\overbrace {{\left[ {\left. {1 - \tau \underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} } \right]}^{{ - 1}} \tau G_{\alpha } \left| {_{{t_{n} }} } \right.}^{{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{{\alpha ,{\text{dec}}}} } \right]}}} + {\overbrace {\tau {\left[ {\left. {1 - \tau \underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \eta _{\alpha } }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} } \right]}^{{ - 1}} \left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial G_{\alpha } }}{{\partial \varphi }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} }^{\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} }}{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]}}} \\ {{{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]} = {\sum\nolimits_\beta {\left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial f}}{{\partial \eta _{\beta } }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{\beta } } \right]} + \left. {\underline{\underline {\frac{{\partial f}}{{\partial \varphi }}}} } \right|_{{t_{n} }} {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]}} }}} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(A‐6)

If the cell variables \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta \) are eliminated from the second equation, the complete system of equations (which includes cells) becomes:

$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta } \right]} = {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{{{\text{dec}}}} } \right]} + \underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]}}} \\ {{{\left[ {1 + \underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{C}}}} } \right]}{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]} = {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi _{{{\text{ins}}}} } \right]}}} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(A‐7)

where the quantities \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{{{\text{dec}}}} } \right]}\), \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} \), \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{C}}}} \) and \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi _{{{\text{ins}}}} } \right]}\)depend onτ and can be calculated from the elementary Jacobian matrices and vectors at time t n .

The first equation of (A-7) describes the evolution of the state variables. The state variables evolve because 1) of their internal inertial evolutions \({{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{{{\text{dec}}}} }\) (which would be obtained if transfer models were changed to constant transfer model with \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi = 0\)) and 2) of the evolution of their boundary conditions \({\left( {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi \ne 0} \right)}\). The matrix \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} \) describes the influence of transfer variables on state variables and independently of the type of model used for these transfers (\(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} \) is independent of the model of \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi \)).

In the second equation, \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi _{{{\text{ins}}}} \) represents the variation of transfer variables if \({\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta = {\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta _{{{\text{dec}}}} \) (i.e., if the cell models were changed to decoupled models with \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{F}}}} = 0\)). Consequently, \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{C}}}} \) represents the effect of cell and transfer coupling.

The developed expression of the matrix \(\underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{C}}}} \) shows how the partial derivatives defined at the cell and transfer level combine. The coefficients of the coupling matrix are rational fractions of the variable τ. This is the way the full dynamic of the system bounds the remaining variables after an elimination process.

Numerical solution of the transfer evolution formalism

For large systems, the above matrices are huge and sparseand exhibit an internal structure that depends upon the connections between cells and transfers. The full algorithm of the ZOOMFootnote 9solver follows a technique called ‘relaxed supernodes hyper multifrontal method’ (cf. [23]). We focus here on the principles of the resolution that explain how the system dynamics is described by the coupling coefficients.

Equivalence between Borel transform and the Crank–Nicolson scheme

It is easily shown that the Crank–Nicolson resolution of the system (A-4) with a time step δt is identical to its Borel transform (A-7), with the correspondence \(\tau \leftrightarrow \frac{{\delta t}}{2}\).

To demonstrate this equivalence, let \(\widehat{\delta }X\) be the time evolution of variable X approximated by a Crank–Nicolson scheme, and consider the linear system:

$$\frac{{\partial \eta {\left( t \right)}}}{{\partial t}} = A\eta {\left( t \right)}$$
(A‐8)

If η(t) = η 0 + δη(t), with δη(0) = 0, it may be rewritten as:

$$\frac{{\partial {\left( {\eta _{0} + \delta \eta {\left( t \right)}} \right)}}}{{\partial t}} = A{\left( {\eta _{0} + \delta \eta {\left( t \right)}} \right)}$$
(A‐9)

If a Crank–Nicolson scheme is applied to system (A‐9), with a time step δt, the discretized equation reads:

$$\frac{{\widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( {\delta t} \right)}}}{{\delta t}} = A\frac{1}{2}{\left( {2\eta _{0} + \widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( {\delta t} \right)}} \right)}$$
(A‐10)

which gives the time evolution of η, since \(\widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( {\delta t} \right)} \approx \delta \eta {\left( {\delta t} \right)}\) for small δt.

For any t > 0, \(\widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( t \right)}\) is given by:

$$\widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( t \right)} = {\left( {1 - \frac{t}{2}A} \right)}^{{ - 1}} A\eta _{0} t$$
(A‐11)

Now, the Borel transform of system (A-9) reads:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\frac{{\partial \delta \eta {\left( t \right)}}}{{\partial t}}} \right)} = \frac{1}{\tau }{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\delta \eta } \right)}{\left( \tau \right)}} \\ { = {\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {A{\left( {\eta _{0} + \delta \eta {\left( t \right)}} \right)}} \right)}} \\ { = A{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\eta _{0} } \right)} + A{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\delta \eta } \right)}{\left( \tau \right)}} \\ \end{array} $$
(A‐12)

which can be rewritten (because \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( k \right)} = k\)) as:

$${\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\delta \eta } \right)}{\left( \tau \right)} = {\left( {1 - \tau A} \right)}^{{ - 1}} A\eta _{0} \tau $$
(A‐13)

Equation (A-11) and (A-13) show that the Crank–Nicolson integration of a linear system is equivalent to the Borel transform of the system through the relationship:

$$\widehat{\delta }\eta {\left( t \right)} = 2{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left( {\delta \eta } \right)}{\left( {\frac{t}{2}} \right)}$$
(A‐14)

Time evolution of the model

For each time step, the ZOOM solver solves the second matrix equation of (A-7) for \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^o }\varphi } \right]}\). The first equation isthen solved for \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^o }\eta } \right]}\). Thanks to property (A-14), this gives an approximation of the temporal evolution of the model variables between t n and t n + δt.

TLS Analysis

As is well known, poles of Laplace transform of TLS solutions are eigenmodes of the system. The same holds for Borel transform: determining the poles of the Borel transform yields the complete dynamic of the system.

ZOOM is able of computing numerically the Borel transform of the TLS solution \({\left( {{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\eta } \right]}{\left( \tau \right)}{\text{ and }}{\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi } \right]}{\left( \tau \right)}} \right)}\) on the real axis τ > 0. The problem of describing the dynamics of a system is thus reduced to that of determining the poles of the Borel transform of the TLS solution from its numerical values on the positive real axis.

In particular, in equation (A-7), the poles of \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^o }\varphi } \right]}{\left( \tau \right)}\) are 1) the poles of \({\user1{\mathcal{B}}}{\left[ {{\mathop \delta \limits^ \circ }\varphi _{{{\text{ins}}}} } \right]}\), i.e., the poles of the model without taking into account the interactions between subsystems and 2) the poles of \({\left( {1 + \underline{\underline {\user1{\mathcal{C}}}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} \), i.e. the poles corresponding to the subsystem interaction. The inverse Borel transform of equation (A-7), obtained by an identification of simple elements, provides the full dynamics of the model. The methodology consists here in fitting the Borel transform with a linear combination of sigmoid and bump functions, which are the only possible Borel transforms of linear differential equation solutions. From the characteristic times of the corresponding poles and their residue, the original function can easily be reconstructed without inverse Borel transform.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hallegatte, S. The long time scales of the climate–economy feedback and the climatic cost of growth. Environ Model Assess 10, 277–289 (2005). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-005-9013-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-005-9013-7

Keywords

Navigation