Skip to main content
Log in

Diversity, identity, and the indeterminacy of the size of nations

A critique of the Alesina school of thought from the viewpoint of evolutionary political economy

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recently economists have explored the impact of ethnic and social diversity on nation size and on the relative efficacy of the production of private and public goods. In a neoclassical framework with perfect and complete information, diversity increases the costs of government, and both the size of government and of the nation are limited. The paper proposes an alternative evolutionary framework building on the economics of identity. With imperfect and incomplete information, the relation between nation size and diversity is indeterminate, because heterogeneity plays an important role for the coordination among actors, and because political organization is crucial for the endogenous formation of preferences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXV(3), 715–753. doi:10.1162/003355300554881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2005). Identity and the economics of organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 9–32. doi:10.1257/0895330053147930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (2005). Interview in Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 23 June 2005, p. 12.

  • Alesina, A., & La Ferrara, E. (2005). Ethnic diversity and economic performance. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII(3), 762–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November, 1027–1055.

  • Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (2003). The size of nations. Cambridge/London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderlini, L., & Felli, L. (1999). Incomplete contracts and complexity costs. Theory and Decision, 46, 23–50. doi:10.1023/A:1004917722235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, D. A. (Ed.). (1993). Neorealism and neoliberalism: The contemporary debate. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1996). Accounting for tastes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D. (1994). A theory of conformity. Journal of Political Economy, 102(5), 841–877.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K. (1994/1998). Game theory and the social contract (Vols. I/II). Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

  • Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVI, 75–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2004). Microeconomics. Behavior, institutions, and evolution. New York, Princeton and Oxford: Russell Sage and Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chisik, R. (2003). Gradualism in free trade agreements: A theoretical justification. Journal of International Economics, 59, 367–397. doi:10.1016/S0022-1996(02)00019-3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B. (2003). The theory of the individual in economics. Identity and value. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. K. (1996). The making of economic policy: A transaction-cost politics perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (Ed.). (1998). Deliberative democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., & Rabin, M. (1996). Cheap talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Field, A. (2001). Altruistically inclined? The behavioral sciences, evolutionary theory, and the origins of reciprocity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1988). Passions within reason. The strategic role of emotions. New York/London: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1977). A theory of the size and shape of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 85(1), 379–399. doi:10.1086/260545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (2005). Review of Alesina and Spolaore: The size of nations. The Independent Review, 10(2), http://www.independent.org/publications/tir/article.asp?issueID=43&articleID=550.

  • Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2006). Endogenous regionalism. Journal of Institutional Economics, 2(3), 297–318. doi:10.1017/S1744137406000427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis, M. (1998). Trust within reason. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1951). Group behavior and international trade. Journal of Political Economy, LIX, 30–46. doi:10.1086/257026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kranton, R. E. (1996). Reciprocal exchange: A self-sustaining system. The American Economic Review, 86(4), 830–851.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (1991). Cognitive limitations and preference evolution. Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics, 147, 241–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (1995). Private truths, public lies. The social consequences of preference falsification. Cambridge/London: Harvard Unversity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J. T. (1994). Trust, ethnicity, and identity. Beyond the new institutional economics of ethnic trading networks, contract law, and gift-exchange. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2005). Endogenizing fractionalization. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1(1), 75–98. doi:10.1017/S1744137405000056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, C. (2002). Endogenous trade policy and lobby formation: An application to the free-rider problem. Journal of International Economics, 57, 449–471. doi:10.1016/S0022-1996(01)00146-5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, S. P., Brock, W. A., & Young, L. (1989). Black hole tariffs and endogenous policy theory. Political economy in general equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: The effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57, 829–862. doi:10.1017/S0020818303574069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLaren, J. (1997). Size, sunk cost, and judge Bowker’s objection to free trade. The American Economic Review, 87(3), 400–420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitra, D. (1999). Endogenous lobby formation and endogenous protection: A long-run model of trade policy determination. The American Economic Review, 89(5), 1116–1134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2000). Capitalism, democracy and rational political behavior. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(1–2), 67–82. doi:10.1007/s001910050006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nooteboom, B. (2002). Trust. Forms, foundations, functions, failures and figures. Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton/Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Opp, K.-D. (1994). The role of voice in a future Europe. Kyklos, 47(3), 385–402. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1994.tb02744.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Opp, K.-D. (2001). Why do people vote? The cognitive-illusion proposition and its test. Kyklos, 54(2/3), 355–378.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pecorino, P. (1998). Is there a free-rider problem in lobbying? Endogenous tariffs, trigger strategies, and the number of firms. The American Economic Review, 88(3), 652–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (2005). Not by genes alone. How culture transformed human evolution. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan, S. (1975). Dimensions of state formation and nation-building: A possible paradigm for research on variations within Europe. In C. Tilly (Ed.), The formation of national states in Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, D. (2005). Economic theory and cognitive science: Microexplanations. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Ursprung, H. W. (1999). Globalization of the economy and the nation state. World Economy, 22(3), 295–352. doi:10.1111/1467-9701.00205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms, B. (1996). The evolution of the social contract. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skyrms, B. (2004). The stag hunt and the evolution of social structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sniderman, P. M., & Levendusky, M. (2005). An institutional theory of political choice. In R. J. Dalton & H.-D. Kinglemann (Eds.), Oxford handbook of political behavior, in press.

  • Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII(2), 392–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaore, E. (2005). National borders and the size of nations. http://www.tufts.edu/~espola01/oxford.pdf.

  • Sugden, R. (2000). Team preferences. Economics and Philosophy, 16, 175–204. doi:10.1017/S0266267100000213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (2002). Beyond sympathy and empathy: Adam Smith’s concept of fellow-feeling. Economy and Philosophy, 18, 63–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1990). Capital, coercion, and European states, AD 900–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (2003). Economic policy making in evolutionary perspective. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13(2), 77–94. doi:10.1007/s00191-003-0148-x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. A. (1995). The myth of democratic failure. Why political institutions are efficient. Chicago/London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgemuth, M. (1998). Entry barriers in politics, or: Why politics, like natural monopoly, is not organized as an ongoing market process, Diskussionsbeitrag, 14-98. Jena: Max-Planck-Institut zur Erforschung von Wirtschaftssystemen.

  • Wohlgemuth, M. (2000). Political entrepreneurship and bidding for political monopoly. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(3), 273–296. doi:10.1007/s001910050015.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgemuth, M. (2002). Evolutionary approaches to politics. Kyklos, 55(2), 223–247. doi:10.1111/1467-6435.00184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yarbrough, B. V., & Yarbrough, R. M. (1998). Unification and secession: Group size and ‘escape from lock-in’. Kyklos, 51(2), 171–196. doi:10.1111/1467-6435.00044.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carsten Herrmann-Pillath.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Herrmann-Pillath, C. Diversity, identity, and the indeterminacy of the size of nations. Eur J Law Econ 27, 15–38 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-008-9060-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-008-9060-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation