Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Effective is Lithium Recycling as a Remedy for Resource Scarcity?

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate to what extent recycling can remedy resource scarcity, and whether market intervention is desired. For doing so, we develop a dynamic model of the global lithium market. An efficient market for resource waste allows consumers to internalize the waste value when they buy the resource. Without a market for lithium waste, we show that the efficient outcome can alternatively be realized through a proper set of subsidies to either buyers or sellers of both virgin and recycled lithium. We find that optimal subsidies may become quite substantial in the second half of this century. The size of these subsidies depends, however, on several uncertain assumptions such as technological progress in recycling, quality-grade of recovered lithium, and demand elasticity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the numerical simulations, we consider several consuming sectors and several producing countries. Moreover, we let utility and cost functions change exogenously over time, reflecting income growth and technological change. The qualitative insights drawn in this section would not change if we incorporated these features in the analytical model.

  2. The effects of market power and strategic behavior in this context have been studied by, e.g., Grant (1999), Sourisseau et al. (2017), Martin (1982) and Ba and Mahenc (2018). For instance, the latter study shows that a monopolistic extractor will slow down extraction vis-à-vis the socially optimal solution when facing a prospective recycler.

  3. In the numerical simulations we also account for transport costs as well as the costs of adjusting output from the base year level to the optimal level. (See “Appendix 1” for more details).

  4. Note that the lithium stock Lt is measured in value terms, not physical terms, as recycled lithium enters into Lt through yt = xt + qwt.

  5. For more information on GAMS program and MCP solver see Brooke et al. (1996). GAMS release 2.25; a user's guide, GAMS Development Corporation, Washington, DC (EUA), ibid. and GAMS documentation.

  6. Thus, we run the model 65 years beyond the time horizon we consider. All shadow prices are set equal to zero in the last period of the simulation. Whereas the analytical model has an infinite time horizon, this is not possible for the numerical model. By running the model sufficiently many years beyond our time horizon, the results are practically identical to the results of an infinite time horizon model (this is confirmed by running the model for even longer periods).

  7. The numbers for “reserves” are much smaller, and less relevant for a long-run analysis. For instance, USGS’ “reserves” in Bolivia are close to zero, while identified resources are in the same range as Chile. (See Fig. 8 in “Appendix 4” for more details).

  8. Kushnir and Sanden (2012). Assume similar lithium content per EV battery as we do, and project that even with a low level of vehicle population growth (0.2 cars/capita), EV adoption reaches about 350 million EVs by 2030. Alternatively, the Clean Energy Ministerial forum launched a campaign “EV30@30” to accelerate EV, and reach 30% market share for electric vehicles in the total of all passenger cars, light commercial vehicles, buses and trucks by 2030 IEA (2018a). Global EV Outlook 2018, Towards cross-modal electrification, OECD, IEA (2018b). Global EV Outlook 2017, Two million and counting. Paris, OECD/IEA- International Energy Agency.

  9. Whereas the quantities obviously are the same in the two alternative efficient solutions, the consumer prices are different.

  10. If price discrimination is difficult, the efficient solution could alternatively be realized through a common subsidy to delivery of used lithium.

  11. This is not the case initially, however, when the lithium price increases rapidly.

  12. Hydro vil gjenvinne elbil-batterier i et samarbeid med Batteriretur og metallkonsernet Glencor. https://batteriretur.no/hydro-vil-gjenvinne-elbil-batterier-i-et-samarbeid-med-batteriretur-og-metallkonsernet-glencor/.

  13. As far as we know, there exists no empirical studies of demand elasticities of lithium. Thus, the size of this elasticity is very uncertain, especially in the long run when the price sensitivity depends for instance, on the availability of substitutes. Therefore, we perform sensitivity analysis with respect to this elasticity.

  14. As far as we know, there exists no empirical studies of demand elasticities of lithium. Thus, the size of this elasticity is very uncertain, especially in the long run when the price sensitivity depends for instance, on the availability of substitutes. Therefore, we perform sensitivity analysis with respect to this elasticity.

References

  • Andersson M, Soderman ML, Sanden BA (2017) Are scarce metals in cars functionally recycled? Waste Manag 60:407–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andre F, Cerda E (2006) On the dynamics of recycling and natural resources. Environ Resour Econ 33(2):199–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ba BS, Mahenc P (2018) Is recycling a threat or an opportunity for the extractor of an exhaustible resource? Environ Resour Econ. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0293-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg E, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl KE (2002) Oil exploration under climate treaties. J Environ Econ Manag 44(3):493–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloomberg (2017) Electric Vehicle Outlook 2017. New Energy Finance’s annual long-term forecast of the world’s electric vehicle market

  • Boyce JR (2012) Recycling of non renewable resource and the least cost first principle

  • Brooke A, Kendrick D, Meeraus A (1996) GAMS release 2.25; a user’s guide, GAMS Development Corporation, Washington, DC (EUA)

  • Ciacci L, Reck BK, Nassar NT, Graedel TE (2015) Lost by design. Environ Sci Technol 49(16):9443–9451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciez RE, Whitacre JF (2016) The cost of lithium is unlikely to upend the price of Li-ion storage systems. J Power Sources 320:310–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochilco (2013). Mercado Internacional del Litio. Santiago de Chile, Comision Chilena del Cobre, Chilean Mining Ministry

  • Comibol (2017) 2017, from http://www.comibol.gob.bo/

  • European-Commission (2016) Raw Materials Scoreboard. Luxembourg, European Commission

  • Farzin YH (1992) The time path of scarcity rent in the theory of exhaustible resources. Econ J 102:813–830

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaines L, Richa K, Spangenberger J (2018) Key issues for Li-ion battery recycling. Mrs Energy Sustain 5:14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galaxy (2015) Annual financial report. Galaxy Resources Limited

  • Grant D (1999) Recycling and market power: a more general model and re-evaluation of the evidence. Int J Ind Organ 17(1):59–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimsrud K, Rosendahl KE, Storrosten HB, Tsygankova M (2016) Short run effects of bleaker prospects for oligopolistic producers of a non-renewable resource. Energy J 37(3):293–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson DA (1980) Increasing extraction costs and resource prices: some further results. Bell J Econ 11(1):335–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1978) Resource extraction and recycling with environmental costs. J Environ Econ Manag 5(3):220–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2018a) Global EV Outlook 2017, Two million and counting. OECD/IEA- International Energy Agency, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2018b) Global EV Outlook 2018, Towards cross-modal electrification. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Kushnir D, Sanden BA (2012) The time dimension and lithium resource constraints for electric vehicles. Resour Policy 37(1):93–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Pindyck RS (1981) The pricing of durable exhaustible resources. Q J Econ 96(3):365–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mackenzie W (2017) Lithium’s role in a decarbonising world

  • Martin RE (1982) Monopoly power and the recycling of raw materials. J Ind Econ 30(4):405–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemaska-Lithium (2017) Retrieved 6, November, 2017, from http://www.nemaskalithium.com/en/

  • Orocobre (2015) Annual report. Orocobre Limited: 132

  • Pashardes P (1986) Myopic and forward looking behaviour in a dynamic demand system. Int Econ Rev 27(2):387–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pehlken A, Albach S, Vogt T (2017) Is there a resource constraint related to lithium ion batteries in cars? Int J Life Cycle Assess 22(1):40–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pittel K, Amigues JP, Kuhn T (2010) Recycling under a material balance constraint. Resour Energy Econ 32(3):379–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reck BK, Graedel TE (2012) Challenges in metal recycling. Science 337(6095):690–695

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richa K, Babbitt CW, Gaustad G, Wang X (2014) A future perspective on lithium-ion battery waste flows from electric vehicles. Resour Conserv Recycl 83:63–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohr S, Wagner S, Baumann M, Mullier S, IEEE (2017) A techno-economic analysis of end of life value chains for lithium-ion batteries from electric vehicles. In: 2017 twelfth international conference on ecological vehicles and renewable energies (Ever)

  • Roskill (2019) Lithium market report, outlook to 2028

  • Schulze WD (1974) The optimal use of non-renewable resources: the theory of extraction. J Environ Econ Manag 1(1):53–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM, Wan FY (1976) Extraction costs in theory of exhaustible resources. Bell J Econ 7(2):359–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sourisseau S, De Beir J, Huy TH (2017) The effect of recycling over a mining oligopoly

  • Stewart MB (1980) Monopoly and the intertemporal production of a durable extractable resource. Q J Econ 94(1):99–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sverdrup HU (2016) Modelling global extraction, supply, price and depletion of the extractable geological resources with the LITHIUM model. Resour Conserv Recycl 114:112–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swain B (2017) Recovery and recycling of lithium: a review. Sep Purif Technol 172:388–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Geological Survey (2017). Minerals commodity symmaries 2017, U.S. Geological Survey, p 202

  • Wang X, Gaustad G, Babbitt CW, Bailey C, Ganter MJ, Landi BJ (2014) Economic and environmental characterization of an evolving Li-ion battery waste stream. J Environ Manage 135:126–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein MC, Zeckhauser RJ (1974) Use patterns for depletable and recycleable resources. Rev Econ Stud 41:67–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood E, Neubauer J, Brooker AD, Gonder J, Smith KA (2012) Variability of battery wear in light duty plug-in electric vehicles subject to ambient temperature battery size and consumer usage. In: International battery, hybrid and fuel cell electric vehicles symposium 26 (EVS 26)

  • Yaksic A, Tilton JE (2009) Using the cumulative availability curve to assess the threat of mineral depletion: the case of lithium. Resour Policy 34(4):185–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziemann S, Weil M, Schebek L (2012) Tracing the fate of lithium-The development of a material flow model. Resour Conserv Recycl 63:26–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zou H, Gratz E, Apelian D, Wang Y (2013) A novel method to recycle mixed cathode materials for lithium ion batteries. Green Chem 15(5):1183–1191

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions on a previous version of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Diana Roa Rubiano.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Cost Function

To make the model fit better with the current situation in the lithium market, we add two cost elements for lithium extractors. In the numerical simulations, the cost function looks like:

$$c^{E} \left( {A_{jt} } \right) = c_{j0} e^{{\eta_{j} A_{jt} - \tau_{E} }} x_{jt} - c_{j}^{T} x_{jt} - c_{jt}^{add} \left( {x_{jt} ,x_{j0} } \right)x_{jt}$$
(27)

So total cost depends on three parts. The first part, \((c_{j0} e^{{\eta_{j} A_{jt} - \tau_{E} t}} x_{jt} )\) adopted from e.g. Grimsrud et al. (2016), assumes unit extraction costs (starting at \(c_{j0}\)) increase with accumulated supply \((A_{jt}\)) and decrease with (exogenous) technological progress \(\left( {\tau_{E} = 0.05} \right)\). The parameter \(\eta_{j}\) represents the rising costs rate as accumulated production increases and is calibrated to the initial stock levels of lithium resources for each producer. The second part, (\(c_{j}^{T} x_{jt}\)), is simply linear transportation costs to the world market. The third part, \(c_{jt}^{add} \left( {x_{jt} ,x_{j0} } \right),\) is a quadratic term to consider that it is costly to ramp up production substantially in the short to medium term, and also that sunk costs make sudden output reductions less profitable. One particular example is Bolivia, which has enormous and profitable lithium resources, but where production is close to zero due to institutional barriers such as constraints on property rights and on foreign investments. The term \(c_{jt}^{add} \left( {x_{jt} ,x_{j0} } \right)\) equals zero if production equals the base year output, is quadratic in deviation from the base year output, and reduces gradually over time.

The first order condition for producer j, subject to a positive outcome \((x_{jt} > 0)\) is:

$$\frac{{\delta c^{E} \left( A \right)}}{\delta x} = c_{j0} e^{{\eta_{j} A_{jt} - \tau_{E} }} - c_{j}^{T} - c_{jt}^{add} \left( {x_{jt} ,x_{j0} } \right)$$
(28)

Table 5 displays the value of a range of parameters applied in the numerical model.

Table 5 Parameters applied in the model

Appendix 2

2.1 Utility and Demand Functions

We assume the following standard utility function for use of lithium \(y_{it}\) (in all consuming sectors i):

$$U_{it} \left( {y_{it} } \right) = \varPhi_{i} + \frac{{\alpha_{i} }}{{1 + \alpha_{i} }}y_{i0} \sigma_{it} \left( {\frac{{y_{it} }}{{y_{i0} \sigma_{it} }}} \right)^{{\frac{{1 + \alpha_{i} }}{{\alpha_{i} }}}}$$
(29)

where \(\varPhi_{i}\) is a constant, \(\alpha_{i}\) represents the (long-term) price elasticity of demand, and \(y_{i0}\) denotes the initial demand level. The factor \(\sigma_{it}\) is an exogenous growth function reflecting the underlying growth in demand. The elasticity \(\alpha_{i}\) is − 0.5 in the benchmark scenarios.Footnote 13 This gives the following marginal utility function:

$$U_{it}^{ '} \left( {y_{it} } \right) = \left( {\frac{{ y_{it} }}{{y_{i0} \sigma_{it} }}} \right)^{{\frac{1}{{\alpha_{i} }}}}$$
(30)

And thereby the derived demand function that we use in the model numerical simulations:

$$y_{it} - y_{i0} \sigma_{it} \left( {\frac{{p_{t} }}{{p_{0} }}} \right)^{{\alpha_{i} }} \ge 0 \bot y_{it} \ge 0$$
(31)

The elasticity \(\alpha_{i}\) is − 0.5 in the benchmark scenarios.Footnote 14 The growth function \(\sigma_{it}\) is calibrated based on projections from the IEA (2018a, b) for the medium term to 2030, and Kushnir and Sanden (2012) for the longer term, using a logistic functional form with several parameters. Obviously, the long-run growth in demand is highly uncertain.

The demand growth factor \(\sigma_{it}\) is calibrated based on the growth rates shown in Table 6, and the following functional form:

$$\sigma_{it} = \frac{{\sigma_{i1} }}{{\sigma_{i2} + \sigma_{i3} e^{{ - \sigma_{i4} t}} + \sigma_{i5} e^{{ - \sigma_{i6} t^{2} }} }}$$
(32)
Table 6 Annual Growth rate in lithium demand in sector i (given price in 2015)

The calibrated parameters are displayed in Table 7.

Table 7 Parameters in the demand growth function

Appendix 3

3.1 Recycling Cost Function

From the recycling costs function (18) we derive the following first order conditions:

$$\frac{\delta CR}{\delta w} = e^{{ - \kappa_{t} }} \left[ {cr_{0} - \ln \left( {1 - \left( {\frac{w}{l}} \right)^{\rho } } \right)} \right] + \frac{{\rho e^{{ - \kappa_{t} }} \left( {\frac{w}{l}} \right)^{\rho } }}{{1 - \left( {\frac{w}{l}} \right)^{\rho } }} = P^{L}$$
(33)
$$\frac{\delta CR}{\delta l} = e^{{ - \kappa_{t} }} \left[ { - \rho \frac{{\left( {\frac{w}{l}} \right)^{\rho + 1} }}{{1 - \left( {\frac{w}{p}} \right)^{\rho } }}} \right]$$
(34)

Or equivalent to

$$\frac{\delta CR}{\delta l} = e^{{ - \kappa_ t}} \left[ {\rho w\frac{{\left( {\frac{w}{l}} \right)^{\rho } }}{{\left( {\left( {\frac{w}{p}} \right)^{\rho } - 1} \right)l}}} \right]$$

Table 8 displays the parameters value applied in the numerical calculation of equations (18), (33) and (34).

Table 8 Parameters in the recycling cost function

Appendix 4

4.1 Resources and Subsidies Analysis

Figure 8 shows accumulated extraction for individual countries in the benchmark scenario. It also shows, for each country, when accumulated extraction surpasses the currently identified resources. We see that Australia and Chile, the two biggest producers today, will run out of identified resources around 2065. Chile has large resources and continues as one of the largest producers throughout the century, whereas Australia has rather limited resources compared to the others. In the first half of our time horizon, Argentina and China also have large identified resources and are important suppliers. In the second half of this century, USA and the rest of the world become important suppliers and Bolivia is the biggest producer of lithium at the end of the century. Up to date, these estimates are susceptible to change when more resources are identified, and producers tend to accelerate their extraction rates.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Accumulated production and identified resources of lithium

Figure 9 shows the optimal subsidy rates in the transport sector across scenarios. We see that the subsidy rates in 2100 vary between 14 and 30 USD per kg of LCE. As a comparison, the initial price of lithium in 2016 is 8.7 USD per kg of LCE. However, until 2050 all subsidies remain below 7 USD per kg of LCE.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Optimal subsidies (shadow price of lithium in use) in the Transport sector across scenarios

Figure 10 shows how net present value (NPV) of welfare gains (relative to unregulated market) and subsidy payments are affected if the optimal subsidies end prematurely in different years—in percent of the corresponding numbers in the efficient solution. For instance, whereas the welfare gains in the efficient solution (vis-à-vis market solution) is 4.5 billion USD, the welfare gain drops by almost 90 percent, to 0.5 billion USD, if the subsidies end in 2060. Total subsidy payments drop from 100 to around 25 billion USD. Hence, ending the subsidies prematurely implies that most of the welfare gains are lost. This shows the importance of establishing a market for recycled lithium, so that subsidies are no longer needed. The figure also shows the share of lithium being recycled in different years in the efficient solution. We see e.g. that in 2060, this share is 90 percent

Fig. 10
figure 10

NPV of welfare gains and subsidy payments if subsidies end prematurely in the given year. Percent of efficient solution (ES). Share of lithium being recycled in the efficient solution in the different years

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rosendahl, K.E., Rubiano, D.R. How Effective is Lithium Recycling as a Remedy for Resource Scarcity?. Environ Resource Econ 74, 985–1010 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00356-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00356-5

Keywords

Navigation