Skip to main content
Log in

Limit Cycles Under a Negative Effect of Pollution on Consumption Demand: The Role of an Environmental Kuznets Curve

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Since Heal (Explorations in natural resource economics. The Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, Baltimore, 1982), there is a theoretical consensus about the occurrence of limit cycles (through a Hopf bifurcation) under a positive effect of pollution on consumption demand (compensation effect) and about the impossibility under a negative effect (distaste effect). However, recent empirical evidence advocates for the relevance of distaste effects. Our paper challenges the conventional view on the theoretical ground and reconciles theory and evidence. The environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) (pollution first increases in the capital level then decreases) plays the main role. Indeed, the standard case à la Heal (limit cycles only under a compensation effect) only works along the upward-sloping branch of the curve while the opposite (limit cycles only under a distaste effect) holds along the downward-sloping branch. Welfare effects of taxation also change according to the slope of the EKC.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The reader is referred to a brief survey on the pollution effects on human health by Kampa and Castanas (2008).

  2. The reader is referred to a survey on the EKC compiled by Kijima et al. (2010).

  3. Andreoni and Levinson (2001), and, more recently, Managi (2006) and Managi and Kaneko (2009) have found an empirical evidence of increasing returns to scale for abatment activities.

  4. Usually, the EKC defines “an inverted-U-shaped relationship between different pollutants and per capita income” (Dinda 2004), that is an inverted-U-shaped relationship between P and \(y\equiv Y/L=f\left( k\right) \). We observe that, since \(f^{\prime }\left( k\right) >0\) (see Assumption 1), an inverted-U-shaped relationship between P and y is analogous to an inverted-U-shaped relationship between P and k.

  5. In our model, both the cases of stability or instability of the limit cycle with Kuznets effect, are possible. According to different calibrations, we obtain either super or subcritical bifurcations.

  6. In this and the following sections, all the values are evaluated at the steady state. For notational parsimony, we will omit the asterisk \(*\) for functions and elasticities evaluated at the steady state.

  7. See Vissing-Jørgensen (2002) among others.

  8. The interest reader is referred to Bennett and Farmer (2000) among others.

  9. Compare with Fernandez et al. (2012) or Bosi et al. (2016).

  10. In the case of the Netherlands, according to the OECD Environmental Performance Reviews (2015), public environmental protection expenditures represent 1.5% of GDP in 2013.

  11. Matcont version 6p4.

  12. We observe that subcriticity depends on the calibration. A different parametrization may give rise to supercriticity in the EKC case.

References

  • Andreoni J, Levinson A (2001) The simple analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve. J Public Econ 80:269–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennett R, Farmer R (2000) Indeterminacy with non-separable utility. J Econ Theory 93:118–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosi S, Ragot L (2011) Introduction to discrete-time dynamics. CLUEB, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosi S, Desmarchelier D, Ragot L (2016) Preferences and pollution cycles. FAERE working paper, 2016.03

  • Dinda S (2004) Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis: a survey. Ecol Econ 49:431–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez E, Pérez R, Ruiz J (2012) The environmental Kuznets curve and equilibrium indeterminacy. J Econ Dyn Control 36:1700–1717

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein A, Luttmer E, Notowidigdo M (2013) What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 11:221–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heal G (1982) The use of common property resources. In: Smith VK, Krutilla JV (eds) Explorations in natural resource economics. The Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, Baltimore

  • Itaya J-I (2008) Can environmental taxation stimulate growth? The role of indeterminacy in endogenous growth models with environmental externalities. J Econ Dyn Control 32:1156–1180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kampa M, Castanas E (2008) Human health effects of air pollution. Environ Pollut 151:362–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kijima M, Nishide K, Ohyama A (2010) Economic models for the environmental Kuznets curve: a survey. J Econ Dyn Control 34:1187–1201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznetsov Y (1998) Elements of applied bifurcation theory. Applied mathematical sciences, vol 112. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Managi S (2006) Are there increasing returns to pollution abatement? Empirical analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve in pesticides. Ecol Econ 58:617–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Managi S, Kaneko S (2009) Environmental performance and returns to pollution abatement in China. Ecol Econ 68:1643–1651

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mélières M-A, Maréchal C (2015) Climate change: past, present and futur. Wiley-Blackwell, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Michel P, Rotillon G (1995) Disutility of pollution and endogenous growth. Environ Resour Econ 6:279–300

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2015) OECD environmental performance reviews: the Netherlands 2015. OECD Publishing

  • Sinn H-W (2008) Public policies against global warming: a supply side approach. Int Tax Public Finance 15:360–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vissing-Jørgensen A (2002) Limited asset market participation and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. J Polit Econ 110:825–853

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David Desmarchelier.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

The consumer’s Hamiltonian function writes

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{H}\equiv e^{-\rho t}u\left( c,P\right) +\tilde{\lambda }\left[ \left( r-\delta \right) h+w-c\right] \end{aligned}$$

The first-order conditions are given by \(\partial \tilde{H}/\partial \tilde{\lambda }=\left( r-\delta \right) h+w-c=\dot{h}\), \(\partial \tilde{H}/\partial h=\tilde{\lambda }\left( r-\delta \right) =-\tilde{\lambda }^{\prime }\), \(\partial \tilde{H}/\partial c=e^{-\rho t}u_{c}-\tilde{\lambda } =0\). Setting \(\lambda \equiv e^{\rho t}\tilde{\lambda }\), we find \(\dot{\lambda }-\rho \lambda =e^{\rho t}\tilde{\lambda }^{\prime }\) and, therefore, \(\lambda \left( r-\delta -\rho \right) =-\dot{\lambda }\). Finally, the budget constraint \(\dot{h}=\left( r-\delta \right) h+w-c\), now binding, writes at equilibrium \(\dot{k}=\left( r-\delta \right) k+w-c\).   \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

Focus on Eq. (12). \(\dot{P}=0\) implies

$$\begin{aligned} P=\frac{k^{*}}{a}\left[ b-\gamma \left( \tau k^{*}\right) \tau \right] \equiv P\left( k^{*}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(34)

with

$$\begin{aligned} P^{\prime }\left( k^{*}\right) =\frac{1}{a}\left[ b-\tau \left( 1+\theta \right) \gamma \left( \tau k^{*}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Under Assumption 3.1, if \(k^{*}<\tilde{k}\) then \(P^{\prime }\left( k\right) >0\) while if \(k^{*}>\tilde{k}\) then \(P^{\prime }\left( k^{*}\right) <0\).    \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

At the steady state, \(\dot{\lambda }=\dot{k}=\dot{P}=0\). Equation (10) gives (15).

Assumption 1 implies that there exists a unique \(k^{*}>0\) verifying (15). Replacing this value into Eq. (12) gives \(P^{*}=\left[ bk^{*}-\gamma \left( \tau k^{*}\right) \tau k^{*}\right] /a\). Since \(b>\gamma \left( m^{*}\right) \tau \), there exists a unique \(P^{*}>0\). Replacing \(\left( k^{*},P^{*}\right) \) into Eq. (11), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} c^{*}=c\left( \lambda ^{*},P^{*}\right) =\rho k^{*}+w\left( k^{*}\right) >0 \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Equation (6) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^{*}=u_{c}\left( c^{*},P^{*}\right) =u_{c}\left( \rho k^{*}+w\left( k^{*}\right) ,\left[ bk^{*}-\gamma \left( \tau k^{*}\right) \tau k^{*}\right] /a\right) >0 \end{aligned}$$

   \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

Let

$$\begin{aligned} W^{*}\equiv \int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-\rho t}u\left( c^{*},P^{*}\right) \,dt=u\left( c^{*},P^{*}\right) \int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-\rho t} \,dt=\frac{1}{\rho }u\left( c^{*},P^{*}\right) \end{aligned}$$

be the welfare function evaluated at the steady state. We find

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\tau }{W^{*}}\frac{\partial W^{*}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{c^{*} }{u^{*}}\frac{\partial u}{\partial c}\frac{\tau }{c^{*}}\frac{\partial c^{*}}{\partial \tau }+\frac{P^{*}}{u^{*}}\frac{\partial u}{\partial P}\frac{\tau }{P^{*}}\frac{\partial P^{*}}{\partial \tau } \end{aligned}$$

Using (17) and (18), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\tau }{W^{*}}\frac{\partial W^{*}}{\partial \tau }=\left[ \varepsilon _{c}\frac{\rho +\left( \rho +\delta +\tau \right) \frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma }}{\rho +\left( \rho +\delta +\tau \right) \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha } }+\varepsilon _{P}\pi \left( k^{*}\right) \right] \frac{\tau }{k^{*} }\frac{\partial k^{*}}{\partial \tau } \end{aligned}$$

   \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 7

Necessity In a three-dimensional dynamic system, we require at the bifurcation value: \(\lambda _{1}=ib=-\lambda _{2}\) with no generic restriction on \(\lambda _{3}\) (see Bosi and Ragot 2011 or Kuznetsov 1998 among others). The characteristic polynomial of J is given by: \(P\left( \lambda \right) =\left( \lambda -\lambda _{1}\right) \left( \lambda -\lambda _{2}\right) \left( \lambda -\lambda _{3}\right) =\lambda ^{3} -T\lambda ^{2}+S\lambda -D\). Using \(\lambda _{1}=ib=-\lambda _{2}\), we find \(D=b^{2}\lambda _{3}\), \(S=b^{2}\), \(T=\lambda _{3}\). Thus, \(D=ST\) and \(S>0\).

Sufficiency In the case of a three-dimensional system, one eigenvalue is always real, the others two are either real or nonreal and conjugated. Let us show that, if \(D=ST\) and \(S>0\), these eigenvalues are nonreal with zero real part and, hence, a Hopf bifurcation generically occurs.

We observe that \(D=ST\) implies

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}\lambda _{3}=\left( \lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{1}\lambda _{3}+\lambda _{2}\lambda _{3}\right) \left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{3}\right) \end{aligned}$$

or, equivalently,

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) \left[ \lambda _{3} ^{2}+\left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) \lambda _{3}+\lambda _{1} \lambda _{2}\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(37)

This equation holds if and only if \(\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}=0\) or \(\lambda _{3}^{2}+\left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) \lambda _{3} +\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}=0\). Solving this second-degree equation for \(\lambda _{3}\), we find \(\lambda _{3}=-\lambda _{1}\) or \(-\lambda _{2}\). Thus, (37) holds if and only if \(\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}=0\) or \(\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{3}=0\) or \(\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{3}=0\). Without loss of generality, let \(\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}=0\) with, generically, \(\lambda _{3}\ne 0\) a real eigenvalue. Since \(S>0\), we have also \(\lambda _{1}=-\lambda _{2}\ne 0\). We obtain \(T=\lambda _{3}\ne 0\) and \(S=D/T=\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}=-\lambda _{1}^{2}>0\). This is possible only if \(\lambda _{1}\) is nonreal. If \(\lambda _{1}\) is nonreal, \(\lambda _{2}\) is conjugated, and, since \(\lambda _{1}=-\lambda _{2}\), they have a zero real part.    \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 8

Necessity In the real case, we obtain \(D=\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}\lambda _{3}<0\), \(S=\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{1}\lambda _{3} +\lambda _{2}\lambda _{3}>0\) and \(T=\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{3}<0\).

Sufficiency We want to prove that, if \(D,T<0\) and \(S>0\), then \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2},\lambda _{3}<0\). Notice that \(D<0\) implies \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2},\lambda _{3}\ne 0\).

\(D<0\) implies that at least one eigenvalue is negative. Let, without loss of generality, \(\lambda _{3}<0\). Since \(\lambda _{3}<0\) and \(D=\lambda _{1} \lambda _{2}\lambda _{3}<0\), we have \(\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}>0\). Thus, there are two subcases: (1) \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2}<0\), (2) \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2} >0\). If \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2}>0\), \(T<0\) implies \(\lambda _{3}<-\left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) \) and, hence,

$$\begin{aligned} S=\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}+\left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) \lambda _{3}<\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}-\left( \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\right) ^{2}=-\lambda _{1}^{2}-\lambda _{2}^{2}-\lambda _{1}\lambda _{2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

a contradiction. Then, \(\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2}<0\).    \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bosi, S., Desmarchelier, D. Limit Cycles Under a Negative Effect of Pollution on Consumption Demand: The Role of an Environmental Kuznets Curve. Environ Resource Econ 69, 343–363 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0082-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0082-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation