1 Introduction

Transport accounts for about 23 % of energy-related \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions (Sims and Schaeffer 2014), and 15 % of global greenhouse gas emissions (Blanco et al. 2014). Within the EU, passenger cars represent about 12 % of EU \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions.Footnote 1 In the European Commission launched a strategy to reduce carbon dioxide emission intensity (i.e. emissions per kilometer) for new cars sold in the European Union. Since then, the emission intensity of new sold cars has come down remarkably, especially since 2007.Footnote 2 In 2011, the strategy was updated with a proposal to reduce EU transport greenhouse gas emissions by 60 %, by 2050 as compared to 1990 levels (European Commission 2011b).

The strategy is based on three pillars. The first pillar targets car manufacturers, requiring them to reduce the average emissions of new cars. The associated directive, established in 2009, aims to decrease the average emissions of new sold cars to 130 \(\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km}\) by 2015, and 95 \(\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km}\) by 2020 (European Parliament and Council 2009).Footnote 3 The second pillar aims to ensure that the fuel-efficiency information of new passenger cars offered for sale or lease in the EU is made available to consumers to facilitate an informed choice. Labelling is the major instrument to provide information on fuel consumption and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions of cars. Directive 1999/94/EC obliges Member States to provide this information and to transpose the directive into national laws by 18.1.2001 at the latest (European Parliament and Council 1999).

The third pillar aims to influence consumer’s vehicle purchase choices by increasing taxes on fuel-inefficient cars relative to fuel-efficient cars. The three pillars are expected to reinforce each other. Increasing the tax burden on fuel-intensive cars, relative to the burden on fuel-efficient cars (third pillar), and providing information (second pillar) is expected to increase the sale of fuel-efficient cars, which in turn makes it more profitable for car manufacturers to produce fuel-efficient cars (the first pillar).

Over the past years, many EU countries implemented the third strategy pillar, by greening the car taxes through either a revision of purchase taxes, company car taxes or annual road taxes. Contrary to the first and second pillar policies, car taxes, as all other taxes, are decided on a national level, and as a consequence differ across countries. In 2005, the European Commission proposed to harmonise national vehicle registration and annual road taxes (European Commission 2005), but the proposal was rejected by the member states.

Also the level of, as well as the decline in, the emission intensity of newly purchased cars greatly varies across the European countries. Take for instance petrol cars. In 2010, average emissions from new cars ranged from 130 \(\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km}\) (Portugal) to 160 (Luxembourg). Over the period 2001–2010, the emission intensity of petrol cars fell by on average 12 % across the EU15. \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions of new cars have declined most rapidly in Sweden and Denmark. There are various possible explanations for these different experiences across countries. For example, the fall in Sweden’s emission intensity may be attributed to domestic policies (Huse and Lucinda 2013), or to convergence to the EU average, whereas Denmark’s move from being average to becoming one of the most fuel-efficient countries might be the consequence of its aggressive car tax policies.

In this paper, we exploit the variation in the stringency of vehicle fiscal policies across countries and time to address the following research question: to what extent have national fiscal policies contributed to the decarbonisation of newly sold passenger cars? We construct a simple model of a representative agent to generate predictions regarding the effect of fiscal policies on average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions of new cars. We study changes at the aggregate level and are interested in differences between countries and changes over time within countries.Footnote 4 After presenting the model, we build a dataset in which we compare vehicle tax systems across 15 countries over the years 2001–2010. We use a dataset of vehicle-specific taxes, and use these data to characterize each country’s tax system at year t. More specifically, we construct measures for the level and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of car taxes so that we can compare different tax regimes over countries and years. We differentiate taxes by petrol and diesel, so that we construct 8 variables to provide an elaborate characterization of a country’s vehicle tax system for a given year. Both the construction of the multiple tax proxies and the multi-country sample mark important contributions to the empirical literature, which typically has considered a single-country single-event.Footnote 5

The constructed variables are used to empirically study the effect of the fiscal treatment, especially the car purchase tax, on the fuel efficiency of newly sold cars. We identify the effect by considering dynamic differences between countries in car taxes and in emission intensities. We control for static differences between countries through country fixed effects, control for income and for common dynamic patters (e.g. EU policies) through time fixed effects. We can identify the effect of fiscal policies on car sales as some countries have consistent low purchase taxes (<30 % of car prices) that are not very sensitive to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions (Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Luxembourg, Sweden, United Kingdom), while Spain has low purchase taxes but these have become substantially more \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitive over the period 2001–2010. Greece has high purchase taxes (>30 %) but these became less \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitive over the years, and the remaining countries (Austria, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal) have relatively high purchase taxes \((>\)30 %), with a \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) component that substantially increased over the years [>10 €/(gCO\(_2\)/km)], though the countries differ substantially. Our empirical strategy is based on the correlation between the uneven developments in taxes and patterns in the emission intensities for these countries.

Our research has three characteristics, which, combined, make it unique and add to existing literature: first, unlike most studies, our study deals with the effects of car taxes in multiple countries, thus controlling for year-specific effects. This makes it easier to generalize our results. Second, unlike most studies, our study jointly considers three different types of car-related taxes, i.e. registration taxes, road taxes and fuel taxes. This allows for a better insight in the effect of different components of car-related taxes. Third, we provide a method to decompose registration taxes in two parts: the first part measures the level while the second part measures the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-sensitivity. The decomposition allows for a richer analysis.

We find empirical evidence that fiscal vehicle policies significantly affect emission intensities of new bought cars. We find evidence that especially the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-sensitivity of registration taxes and the level of the fuel taxes are important determinants of the emission intensity of new cars. The diesel–petrol substitution induced by changes in the relative taxes for diesel versus petrol cars is an important factor for the average fleet’s fuel efficiency. We also find higher \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensities with increasing income and a clear convergence pattern between EU countries.

2 Literature

There is an emerging empirical literature on the effects of fiscal policies on the fuel-efficiency of newly sold cars. The general finding is that fiscal policies are an effective tool to influence car purchase decisions. In addition, the literature establishes that purchase taxes are more effective than annual (road) taxes, and that tax reform can cause sizable petrol-diesel substitution.

A strong example of the responsiveness of car purchases to fiscal policies is provided by D’Haultfoeuille et al. (2014). They assess the effect of the “feebate” system that existed in France in 2008 and 2009. In this system, owners of fuel efficient cars could receive a tax rebate whereas fuel inefficient car owners had to pay a fee. The precise rebate and fee thresholds showed up remarkably in the sales for different car types, with large sales increases just below and drops just above the thresholds.

The effectiveness of car taxes can depend on the subtle features of the policy adopted. For example, compared to annual taxes, vehicle acquisition taxes are more effective in directing consumers’ buying decisions (Brand et al. 2013; Gallagher and Muehlegger 2011; Klier and Linn 2015; van Meerkerk et al. 2014). Consumer myopia is considered the main reason for this discrepancy.Footnote 6 For fuel costs the evidence is mixed. Where Busse et al. (2013) and Allcott and Wozny (2014) find that consumers fully value the discounted future fuel costs in their purchase decisions, other research indicates that, when deciding on whether to purchase a more fuel efficient car, consumers tend to calculate the expected savings in fuel costs only for about 3 years (see Greene et al. 2005; Kilian and Sims 2006; Greene et al. 2013).

Another phenomenon identified by the literature is the policy-induced substitution between petrol and diesel cars. Diesel engines are typically more efficient than petrol engines. Hence, when Ireland differentiated its purchase and annual road taxes according to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensities, sales of diesel cars increased, particularly at the expense of large petrol cars (Hennessy and Tol 2011; Rogan et al. 2011; Leinert et al. 2013). In addition to contributing to a reduction in average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, this unanticipated shift towards diesel cars caused an increase in \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) emissions (Leinert et al. 2013). Similar effects have been found in Norway, where a vehicle acquisition tax reform caused a 23 percentage point increase in the diesel market share (Ciccone 2015).

All research discussed above analyses the effect of specific vehicle tax policies in a single country. Hence, these papers cannot control for year-specific effects and the results are not easily generalizable. Specifically, single-country estimates may conflate domestic policies with external changes, e.g. EU-wide developments such as efficiency improvements brought by the EU directive 443/2009 on CO\(_2\) standards.Footnote 7 In our empirical strategy, we can identify the fiscal effects as year fixed effects absorb the effects of the common policies and technological developments. That is, our empirical analysis does not consider a single-event in one country, yet studies more broadly the fiscal treatment of car purchases and ownership in relation to car emissions. There are some previous cross-country and panel-data studies on the effect of fuel prices on fuel efficiency (Burke and Nishitateno 2013; Klier and Linn 2013). The effect of the registration and road tax level on car purchases is previously studied in Ryan et al. (2009), who use a panel structure for EU countries. They conclude that vehicle taxes, notably registration taxes, are likely to have significantly contributed to reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensities of new passenger cars. Ryan et al. (2009) focus on the average level of registration taxes in a country.Footnote 8 We take this analysis one step further by constructing measures of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity in addition to the level of registration and road taxes. This allows us to exploit differences between EU countries in the stringency and timing of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-related vehicle fiscal policies. An important part of our study is thus a more comprehensive characterization of the vehicle tax system that can be used to compare differences across countries and changes over time, based on a large dataset of country–year–vehicle specific prices inclusive and exclusive of taxes.

3 Model

We illustrate the effect of vehicle purchase taxes on the average emission intensity with a simple model. We consider two car types. A representative consumerFootnote 9 maximises (expected future) utility u dependent on the current purchase of cars, \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\), and income m net of purchase expenditures x:

$$\begin{aligned} \max \nolimits _{{{q_1},{q_2}}}u\left( {{q_1},{q_2},m - x}\right) \quad \hbox {s.t.}\; p_1^c{q_1}+ p_2^c{q_2} = x, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(p_i^c\) are costs per quantity, including registration taxes as well as future variable costs and annual taxes. The utility function satisfies the standard assumptions on continuity, differentiability, positive derivatives, and concavity. We also assume that both types are normal goods (increasing consumption with increasing income, decreasing consumption with increasing prices) and that the total budget for cars, x, increases in total income, m.

We do not model consumers’ care about the environmental performance of cars as such (see Achtnicht 2012 for an analysis along those lines), but focus on the effects of government instruments geared to direct consumers’ choices. We assume that the tax is fully shifted to consumers,Footnote 10 so that the consumer price of cars is

$$\begin{aligned} p_i^c =\left( {1+\tau _i}\right) p_i^p , \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(\tau _i\) is a type-specific ad valorem tax and \(p_i^p\) is the producer price.

The tax \(\tau _i\) consists of a uniform component \(\varphi \) and an environmental component, where \(\theta \) is a relative weight of the environmental component. The two car types have different emission intensity, say grams of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) per km, which we denote by \(\beta _i\). Without loss of generality, let \(\beta _2 >\beta _1\), for example because car type 2 is more spacious, has more weight, or is more fancy. The type-specific tax becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _i =\varphi +\theta \beta _i . \end{aligned}$$
(3)

We are interested in the effect of changes in car taxes on the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the car fleet, which we define as

$$\begin{aligned} B=\frac{\beta _1 q_1 +\beta _2 q_2 }{q_1 +q_2 }. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Policy can change the uniform component of the car tax, \(\varphi \), the environmental component, \(\theta \), or both. We define the average car-tax, given by

$$\begin{aligned} T=\frac{\tau _1 q_1 +\tau _2 q_2 }{q_1 +q_2 }=\varphi +\theta B, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

so that we can study shifts in the tax structure while keeping a constant overall tax rate. It is intuitive that an increase in the weight of car-feature \(\theta \), while keeping the average tax rate T constant, will decrease the average emission-intensity of the cars:

Proposition 1

An increase in the weight of environmental performance in taxes, \(\theta \), while keeping average total taxes T constant, will decrease the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity B:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dB}{d\theta }<0. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Proof

The policy in the proposition increases the price of the relatively emission-intensive car and decreases the price of the more fuel-efficient car. The result follows immediately from the assumption that both car types are normal goods. \(\square \)

Thus tilting the car taxes to become more \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-dependent will make the car fleet more \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-efficient. The effect of an overall car tax increase is more subtle. A price increase has a similar effect as an income reduction. Car types with a high income elasticity thus tend to lose market share when taxes uniformly increase. The impact of the tax level therefore depends on the comparative income elasticity of the two car types.

Proposition 2

If the environmental tax component \(\theta \) is sufficiently small, then feature B decreases with an overall tax increase \(\varphi \) (or equivalently an increase in T) if and only if the less fuel-efficient car type has higher income elasticity:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dB}{d\upvarphi }<0\Leftrightarrow \frac{\partial q_2 }{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_2 }>\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_1}. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

Proof

Consider \(\frac{\partial q_2 }{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_2 }>\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_1}\Leftrightarrow \frac{\partial q_2 }{\partial x}\frac{\partial x}{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_2 }>\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial x}\frac{\partial x}{\partial m}\frac{m}{q_1 }\Leftrightarrow \frac{\partial q_2}{\partial x}\frac{m}{q_2 }>\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial x}\frac{m}{q_1 }\Leftrightarrow \frac{\partial q_2 }{\partial x}\frac{x}{q_2 }>\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial x}\frac{x}{q_1 }\). An increase in \(\varphi \) constitutes an equiproportional increase in the prices of all cars when \(\theta =0\). Since cars are a normal good (which we use in the middle equivalence), an increase in car prices decreases demand for all types. When \(\theta =0\), an increase in \(\varphi \) is equivalent to a decrease in the budget for cars. Because type 2 has a larger income- and budget elasticity \(\left( {-\frac{\partial q_2 }{\partial \upvarphi }\frac{\upvarphi }{q_2 }>-\frac{\partial q_1 }{\partial \upvarphi }\frac{\upvarphi }{q_1 }} \right) \), the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-intensity B goes down. By continuity, the result also holds for \(\theta \) sufficiently small. \(\square \)

The typical hypothesis asserts that demand for luxurious cars is more income-elastic. Mannering and Winston (1985) find that large and mid-size cars have a higher income elasticity on average than compact cars. A meta-analysis by Goodwin et al. (2004) finds that fuel consumption is more income-elastic than traffic volume, which is consistent with the idea that wealthier consumers buy less fuel-efficient cars. Heffetz (2011) documents larger income elasticities for more visible consumption categories for a wide array of expenditures.

Larger cars, which are also emission-intensive, tend to be more comfortable. For example, they offer more storage and lower occupant fatality rates in vehicle-to-vehicle crashes—attributes that are more easily dispensable than a car’s basic transportation service. The proposition predicts a decrease in the average pollution intensity if the uniform tax \(\varphi \) increases. Indeed, Bordley (1993) obtains higher (Hicksian) price elasticities for luxury car segments, which together with their higher income elasticity also corroborates Proposition 2. The above literature is also consistent with our own finding reported in Table 6.

For high environmental taxes \(\theta \) the effect may be reverted, as an increase in the uniform tax rate \(\varphi \) can then represent a fall in the relative price of less fuel-efficient cars. As we will see however, the relative importance of the environmental component in total car taxes is modest in European countries, so that the proposition’s condition seems to apply.

In the next section, we construct the country–tax variables. The variable construction will closely follow the decomposition in Eq. (3), where, \(\theta \) and \(\beta _i\) will respectively be the average country–year specific tax rate, and the increase in the tax rate \((\theta )\) for a given increase in car-specific \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions \((\beta _i)\). We then test Propositions 1 and 2 by estimating the effect of the tax system variables (\(\varphi \) and \(\theta \)) on the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of newly purchased vehicles (B in Eq. 4).

4 Data

Here we describe the data used for the empirical analysis. The dependent variable of interest is the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of newly purchased vehicles, which depends on substitution patterns between more and less fuel efficient cars, but also on common fuel efficiency improvements over all cars, which in our econometric strategy is absorbed by time fixed effects. The main explanatory variables are fuel taxes and the two coefficients used in the model in Sect. 3: the average level of registration and annual road taxes, and their \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity. Here, we define the vehicle registration tax as all one-off taxes paid at the time the vehicle is registered, which is usually the time of acquisition. For road taxes, we include all annual recurrent taxes of vehicle ownership. We construct these data for each country, year, and fuel type in our sample using a detailed database with vehicle registration taxes and road taxes at vehicle–country–year level.

4.1 Data Sources

Our first data source is a set of manufacturer price tables as supplied by the European Commission (2011a). These tables form an unbalanced panel with 11930 observations on prices and registration taxes, across 204 car types, 20 countries (15 countries up to 2005) over the years 2001–2010. Petrol cars make up about two-third of all observations.Footnote 11 This source includes the retail price data per country inclusive and exclusive of the registration tax, and allows us to construct the vehicle–country–year specific registration tax. As of 2011, the European Commission no longer collects data on automobile prices. As these prices are a crucial part of our analysis, our series end in 2010. Next we construct vehicle–country–year specific road taxes using our second data source: the ACEA (2010) tax guides and the European Commission (2011a) passenger car dataset. We also take information on fuel taxes from the ACEA tax guides. Because most cars are petrol or diesel, we restrict our sample to these two fuel types. The dataset does not contain car-specific sales data.Footnote 12

The dataset from Campestrini and Mock (2011) contains information on the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the newly purchased diesel and petrol cars (\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions in g/km, weighted by sales) and the shares of diesel cars (see Fig. 5 in “Appendix”). We have this information for the EU15 countries, from 2001 to 2010. As shown in Fig. 1, over this period, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity has come down remarkably, albeit with sizable differences across countries (Fig. 2). Lastly, data on nominal per capita GDP is taken from Eurostat (2014). We deflate all prices (sales prices, taxes, GDP) using a common EU15 price deflator.Footnote 13

Fig. 1
figure 1

\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission-intensity for new cars, EU15 average (the figures averages over 15 countries without weights). Source: Campestrini and Mock (2011)

Fig. 2
figure 2

\(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission-intensity for new petrol cars, by country. Source: Campestrini and Mock (2011)

4.2 Constructing Country Average and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) Sensitivity of Car Taxes

Countries have widely divergent rules for registration and road taxes. In some countries, vehicle registration taxes are based on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, in others, the cylindrical content is used to compute the tax, or the sales price of the car. In many instances, registration taxes combine multiple variables. Rules for annual road taxes vary even more across Europe. Some countries base their annual tax on a car’s engine power (in kW or hp), while other countries use cylinder capacity, \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, weight and exhaust emissions. In addition to the dispersion between countries, for both registration and road taxes, many countries have changed their policies over the period 2001–2010; they adopted (temporary) discounts for fuel efficient cars, or additional charges for cars exceeding specified standards.Footnote 14 We compare tax systems across countries by characterizing each country’s tax system at year t by the two coefficients used in our model in Sect. 3. The first coefficient describes the country–year average tax, the second the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of the tax. Both variables are computed for both the registration and road tax, and for petrol and diesel. We thus construct 8 variables that characterize a country’s vehicle tax system for a given year.

We now provide the details. Let \(CO2_{it}\) be the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of car-type i in year t, \(\tau _{cit}\) the (registration or road) (percentage) tax in country c, and let \(\delta _{cit}\) be the index {0,1} identifying whether the data are available for country c. For the sake of exposition, we do not use subscripts for fuel and tax type (registration vs. road). We construct the country-specific \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity and tax rate for the typical car offered Footnote 15 on the market (denoted by bars on top over the variables):

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{{\textit{CO}}2}_{ct}= & {} \frac{\sum \nolimits _{i} \delta _{cit} {\textit{CO}}2_{it}}{\sum \nolimits _i \delta _{cit}}, \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\tau }_{ct}= & {} \frac{\sum \nolimits _i \delta _{cit} \tau _{cit}}{\sum \nolimits _i \delta _{cit}}. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

That is, the typical car for a country has emissions \( \overline{{\textit{CO}}2}_{ct}\) and pays a tax rate \(\bar{\tau }_{ct}\). We subsequently calculate the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-sensitivity of the tax by comparing how much, for each country–year, the vehicle-specific tax increases for a given increase in the vehicle’s \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, on average, and weighted:

$$\begin{aligned} {\textit{CO}}2{\textit{TAX}}_{ct} =\frac{\sum \nolimits _i w_{cit} \left( {\tau _{cit} -\bar{\tau }_{ct}} \right) }{\sum \nolimits _i w_{cit} \left( {{\textit{CO}}2_{it} -\overline{{\textit{CO}}2}_{ct}} \right) }, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where weights are given by the deviation of the vehicle \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity from the typical \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity:

$$\begin{aligned} w_{cit} =\delta _{cit}\left( {{\textit{CO}}2_{it} -\overline{{\textit{CO}}2}_{ct}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

The squared weights ensure that the denominator in (10) is strictly positive, and that the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity is mainly determined by the tax-differences between the fuel-efficient and fuel-intensive cars.

Yet, if we want to determine a country’s tax pressure and compare between countries, we should not consider the tax of the typical car for that country, but the tax for a typical car that is the same over all countries. Thus, we construct the (virtual) tax rate that would apply to a car with a \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-emission profile  that is typical for the set of all countries:

(12)
(13)

The above method generates 8 variables for each country–year pair. The precise interpretation depends on the details of the input variables, \(\hbox {CO2}_{it}\) and \(\tau _{cit}\). If \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions are measured linearly in \((\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km})\), and taxes in euros, then \(\bar{\tau }_{ct}\) is the tax in euros (€) paid for the car with a typical \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-emission profile while \({\textit{CO}}2{\textit{TAX}}_{ct}\) is the increase as measured in (€/(\(\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km})\)). If taxes are measured ad valorem, then \(\bar{\tau }_{ct}\) is the typical car tax rate in percentages while \({\textit{CO}}2{\textit{TAX}}_{ct}\) is the increase in the tax rate per \(\hbox {gCO}_{2}\hbox {/km}\). Our preferred specification uses the logarithm of one plus tax rates and the logarithm of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, so that variables are interpretable as elasticities, and (with time fixed effects) the construction is independent of price levels. In this case, a decrease of the variable \(\bar{\tau }_{ct}\) of 0.01 means that the tax rate for the typical car has fallen by 1 %. If two car types are completely identical (including prices at the factory gate), but one car is 10 % more fuel efficient, then the consumer price of the more fuel-efficient car is 0.1 \(\times \) CO2TAX per cent below the consumer price of the more fuel-intensive car. All estimations in the main text are based on the double-log variables. We have reproduced our results for a linear model, which is presented in “Linear Model” section of “Appendix”. The appendix also provides the equations with more elaborate references to the details of taking logarithms.

Expressions (12) and (13) can directly be connected to Eq. (3) of the stylized model. Here, \(\textit{TAX}_{ct}\) resembles the country–year specific general tax rate \((\varphi )\), with \({\textit{CO}}2{\textit{TAX}}_{ct}\) the increase in the tax rate for a given increase in vehicle-specific CO\(_2\) emissions \((\theta )\).

Figure 3 below shows a typical breakdown of the vehicle registration tax rate in its level and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity. The charts show the registration taxes paid in the Netherlands, in 2001 (left) and 2010 (right), for a series of petrol (upper) and diesel (lower) cars. The dots are observations for individual car types, described at the beginning of Sect. 4.1. The lines present the ‘predicted’ tax rates based on the two proxy variables TAX and CO2TAX constructed above. As is immediately visible from the left and right panels, the tax rate has become more sensitive to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions between 2001 and 2010, that is, the slope of the line has increased. Figure 4 shows the decomposition of the tax in its average tax rate and the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) tax over the years 2000–2011. The levels of the predicted tax in the panels of Fig. 3 correspond to the values in the left panel in Fig. 4, while the slope of the predicted taxes in the panels of Fig. 3 correspond to the values in the right panel of Fig. 4. The average registration tax rate for petrol cars started at about 50 per cent, and sharply dropped in the last years reaching about 47 per cent in 2010 and 40 per cent in 2011. The \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of registration taxes however has increased substantially for both petrol and diesel cars between 2000 and 2011. Figure 4 (right panel) illustrates this shift. Various tax breaks for fuel-efficient cars came into force, which substantially increased the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of taxes, from about 10 to 25 %, but at the same time reduced the average tax. All other things equal, in 2011, the after-tax price decreases by about 3 % if a car is 10 % more fuel-efficient. The charts in Fig. 4 also show that, in the Netherlands, taxes for diesel cars are persistently above those for petrol cars;Footnote 16 in our results section, we will come back to the effect of tax differentiation between petrol and diesel cars.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Taxes per vehicle, dependent on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensity, for the Netherlands, 2001 (left panels) and 2010 (right panels), petrol (upper) and diesel (lower). Taxes are measured relative to car prices

Fig. 4
figure 4

Registration tax levels for typical vehicle (left), and tax dependence on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensity (right), for the Netherlands, 2000–2011, petrol (green solid) and diesel (black dashed). Note that the figure extends the period (2001–2010) over which we run the regressions. Also note that the y-axis on the left panel should be interpreted as ‘elasticity’: \(\hbox {ln}(1+\uptau )\). Thus, a value of 0.5 implies a tax of exp(0.5) \(=\) 65 per cent. (Color figure online)

Table 1 provides some additional summary statistics and the means for the first and last sample years.Footnote 17 Over 2001–2010, the average registration tax for diesel cars decreased from 46 to 40 per cent (see footnote at table) while for petrol cars the registration tax rate decreased from an average of 39 to 35 %. The extra tax paid for purchasing a high-emission vehicle has increased substantially, however. In 2001, purchasing a diesel vehicle with 10 % higher emissions increased the registration tax rate by approximately 0.6 percentage point on average. By 2010, this has increased to 1.4 percentage point. For some countries, the elasticity of the registration tax rate with respect to emissions is negative. This does not directly imply that fewer taxes are paid for polluting vehicles. If a more polluting car is more expensive, then the absolute tax paid can increase while the tax rate paid can decrease.Footnote 18

In 2001, the road tax rate is on average 2 % of the vehicle’s (tax-exclusive) purchase price, for both diesel and petrol cars. Several countries have no annual road tax. The average elasticity of the annual tax rate with respect to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions has changed from being negative in 2001 to a positive value in 2010. Overall, there is a slight pattern towards lower road tax rates, combined with a greater dependence of the tax rate on the emissions of a car.

Table 1 Summary statistics for constructed tax levels and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity for \(\hbox {EU15}\)

Vehicle fiscal measures are correlated, also when we take out country and time fixed effects. Petrol and diesel registration taxes move in tandem, both for the levels and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity. The same applies to the annual taxes, where correlations exceed 80 %.Footnote 19 Petrol and diesel fuel taxes are also positively correlated. The year fixed effects separate fuel price developments from fuel tax changes. There is almost no correlation between the three groups of tax instruments. For annual taxes, we see a very strong negative correlation between the level of annual taxes and its \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity, implying that the set of annual taxes are strongly multi-collinear, so that we must be careful when interpreting individual coefficients for annual taxes.Footnote 20

5 Econometric Strategy

The benchmark model estimates the dependence of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the new car fleet in country c in year t (as in Fig. 2), separately for diesel and petrol, on the two dimensions of the registration car taxes: its level and its \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity

$$\begin{aligned} {\textit{CO}}2{\textit{int}}_{ct} =\alpha _{1c} +\alpha _{2t} +\beta _1 {\textit{TAX}}_{ct} +\beta _2 {\textit{CO}}2{\textit{TAX}}_{ct} +\sum \nolimits _k \pi _k Z_{ckt} +\varepsilon _{ct}, \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where \(\alpha _{1c}\) and \(\alpha _{2t}\) are country and time fixed effects, and the country–time specific control variables Z include income and gasoline taxes.Footnote 21 \(^,\) Footnote 22 For our preferred model, we use logarithms for the dependent variable. In the linear model (see “Linear Model” section of “Appendix”), the dependent variable is measured in average grams of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions per km.

We add convergence patterns through the control variable, through

$$\begin{aligned} Z_{c1t}= & {} {\textit{CO}}2{\textit{int}}_{c0} \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} Z_{c2t}= & {} \left( {year_t -2001} \right) \times {\textit{CO}}2{\textit{int}}_{c0} , \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where \({\textit{CO}}2{\textit{int}}_{c0}\) is the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the new fleet in the base year 2001. Convergence between countries is measured through a negative coefficient for the interaction term (16). We assume there is no systematic correlation between observed fiscal vehicle policies and unobserved policies such as vehicle retirement plans that could induce omitted variable bias.

We first estimate the model for both fuel types jointly and separately,Footnote 23 with and without the annual taxes. This allows us to assess the effect of tax levels and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-intensities on the emission intensity of diesel cars, petrol cars and the average fleet. We then attempt to decompose these effects into effects stemming from substitution between fuel types, effects from substitution between large and small cars, and effects from increased efficiency holding the car attributes constant. For this decomposition, we first add diesel share, average mass and average horsepower to the control variables Z. Next, we replace \(\textit{CO2int}_{ct}\) by either of these three variables as the dependent variable in (14), leaving all other variables unchanged.

6 Results

6.1 Fuel-Type Specific Effects

Table 2 displays the results for the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity for diesel and petrol cars respectively. Starting with the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of new diesel cars, we find a clear significant effect of registration taxes on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. Especially the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity is an effective instrument to change the characteristics of newly bought vehicles: a 1 % increase in \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of the registration tax reduces the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity by about 0.1 % (second row Table 2). We find no significant effect for road taxes on the emissions by diesel cars. Higher diesel fuel tax rates increase the fuel efficiency of newly acquired diesel vehicles, as expected (Burke and Nishitateno 2013). In addition, we find higher \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensities with increasing income and a clear convergence pattern between EU countries.

Table 2 Dependence of new car fleet emissions on taxes, per fuel type
Table 3 Dependence of car emissions (aggregated over fuels) on taxes

For petrol vehicles, the pattern is similar. The effect of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) tax sensitivity is negative and significant: the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity in 2010 (0.13) reduces the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of new bought cars by about 2 %. An increase in the registration tax level reduces the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of newly acquired vehicles, but the coefficients are insignificant. For petrol vehicles, annual road taxes receive a significant coefficient, yet the signs are opposite to what is expected.Footnote 24 Fuel taxes do not show a significant effect for petrol car purchases.

In our regressions, even though the annual road tax rates enter significantly, excluding them from the regression has only little effect on the coefficient for the other variables. Hence, we can interpret the other coefficients with confidence, and conclude that leaving annual taxes unaccounted for probably does not greatly alter our conclusions.

6.2 Aggregate Effects

Then consider the overall effect of car taxes on the new fleet emission intensity, as reported in Table 3. At first sight, it looks as if registration taxes, and specifically the CO\(_2\) sensitivity, have lost their significance as an important determinant. But this can be explained by the high collinearity between the average and difference of the CO\(_2\) sensitivity of registration taxes.Footnote 25 When both the average and difference in CO\(_2\) sensitivity are included in the estimation, this collinearity causes coefficient estimates to be imprecise, and we lose significance for individual coefficients. But, the joint hypothesis that neither the average, nor the difference in the CO\(_2\) sensitivity of registration taxes has any effect is strongly rejected, at \({p}<0.01\) (bottom part of Table 3). If we only include the policy variables that we expect to have the most important effect on the overall fleet’s CO\(_2\) intensity, we indeed find a strong significant effect for the average CO\(_2\) sensitivity of the registration tax (third column).

The average registration tax level does not affect overall \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity, yet higher registration taxes for diesel cars relative to petrol cars increase the average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of new cars. As will be further discussed in the next section, this latter effect can be explained by changes in the diesel share. For a given vehicle performance, diesel cars typically emit less \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\). Lower overall taxes for diesel cars increase the share of diesel cars and thereby decrease average overall emissions.

By subtracting the log of taxes in 2001 from those in 2010 (Table 1) and multiplying the differences with the coefficients in Table 3, we find that the changes in registration taxes have reduced the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the new cars by 1.3 % on average.Footnote 26 The overall effects are modest; an explanation is that various countries with a major domestic car industry (France, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom) have relatively low registration taxes that are almost independent of emission intensities. Interestingly, based on the results in Table 2, we find that the changes in registration taxes over the period 2001–2010 have caused extant diesel drivers to choose more \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-intensive cars on average. For these drivers, the effect of lower registration tax levels in 2010 compared to 2001 dominates the effect of the increased \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity.

Along the same lines, we find that higher petrol fuel taxes tend to reduce the fleet’s emission intensity, while diesel fuel taxes tend to increase average emissions, though the effect is weak.

Table 4 Transmission of fiscal policies to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity
Table 5 Transmission of fiscal policies to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity; diesel share
Table 6 Transmission of fiscal policies to \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity; vehicle mass and horsepower

6.3 Transmission Mechanisms

Finally, we present an assessment of the transmission channels through which fiscal car taxes change emissions. Consumers can switch between petrol and diesel cars, in response to tax measures, but within a fuel type, they can also respond to tax measures by switching to lighter cars with less powerful engines, or alternatively, they can choose for cars with more fuel efficient engines while keeping the preferred car specifications unaffected (Fontaras and Samars 2010).

In Table 4 we present, for diesel and petrol separately, the effect of fiscal measures on the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity with and without additional controls for diesel share, average vehicle mass and engine power. Columns 1 and 4 show the overall policy effects, conflating the changes in the fleet by those consumers that do not change fuel type, with changes brought by consumers who switch to the other fuel type.Footnote 27 Columns 2 and 5 control for changes in the diesel share. Comparing column 1 versus 2, and column 4 versus 5, then reveals the effect consumers switching between fuels at the margin, captured by the coefficient for the diesel share. Columns 2 and 5 still conflate the policies’ effects through car specifications (weight and power) with those reached through improved efficiency while keeping car weight and power constant. Controlling for these in Columns 3 and 6 then separates the efficiency effect from the effects through car specifications. We discuss the effects of fiscal measures on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions through the diesel share and car specifications in turn.Footnote 28

6.3.1 Diesel Share

Table 5 presents the direct effect of fiscal measures on the diesel share. As we see in this table, a higher \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of registration taxes increases the share of diesel cars. Buyers who decide to acquire a diesel car as a substitute for a petrol car typically buy diesel cars that are smaller compared to the average diesel car, while they substitute away from petrol cars that are large compared to the average petrol car (see Rogan et al. 2011; Hennessy and Tol 2011; Leinert et al. 2013). This finding in the literature is supported by our Table 4; we find that the diesel share has a negative and significant coefficient in both Columns 2 and 5 (Table 4), while these coefficients become substantially smaller once we correct for the average mass and horsepower (columns 3 and 6). These consumers who substitute diesel cars for petrol cars thereby reduce the average emissions of both diesel and petrol cars. Indeed, a closer look at our data (not shown here) shows that diesel cars are on average 20 % heavier compared to petrol and the average weight for both diesel and petrol cars decreases with an increase in the diesel share (see also columns 1 and 3 in Table 6). These observations jointly indicate that part of the emission reduction of new cars in the EU has likely been achieved by lower registration taxes (as observed in Table 1), which translated in an increased share of diesel cars (Table 5), which are typically more fuel efficient than petrol cars, and thus in turn decreases the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the average car. In addition to the average level of registration taxes across fuels, higher registration tax levels for diesel cars compared to petrol cars tend to reduce the diesel share (see the second row in Table 5), as does a lower average \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of registration taxes (third row in Table 5). For fuel taxes, we find that higher diesel (petrol) fuel taxes reduce (increase) the diesel share. Finally, higher road taxes for diesel cars reduce the diesel share.Footnote 29

6.3.2 Mass and Horsepower

Columns 3, 4, 7 and 8 of Table 4 confirm that emission intensities are higher when cars are larger and have more powerful engines. Table 6 presents the effect of fiscal measures on average mass and engine power. Adding mass and horse power reduces the (absolute) coefficient on registration taxes in columns 3 and 7, and 4 and 8 of Table 4 compared to columns 1 and 5, and 2 and 6, respectively, suggesting that registration tax levels affect average mass or engine power of newly purchased vehicles. The effect is, however, statistically insignificant in Table 6, so that we evaluate the evidence as weak. We find no effect for the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of diesel registration taxes on average mass and engine power of new diesel vehicles (column 1 and 2, second row, in Table 6), but a strong significant effect for the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of petrol registration taxes. Taken together with the negative effect of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of diesel registration taxes on diesel \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity, a possible interpretation of this finding is that higher and more \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-sensitive diesel registration taxes push consumer purchase choices towards the technology frontier, providing the same qualities (mass and horsepower) to the consumers, at lower \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. For petrol cars, the effects of registration taxes appear to be transmitted through the car features: higher \((\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of) registration taxes reduce the average mass and horse power of newly purchased vehicles, even among consumers who do not switch to diesel cars in response to the tax changes. There is less indication of a technology effect, and more evidence of switch in the type of cars bought by petrol-car consumers.

We note that the effects of income on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensities appear to be fully transmitted through car features, both for diesel and petrol cars; the effects of income on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity in Table 5 are no longer significant when we control for mass and horsepower. Results suggest that increasing income is mainly used to increase the level of desirable features. We thus find no evidence that consumers use income increases to purchase more environmentally friendly cars. For diesel cars, the effect of diesel fuel taxes is also fully transmitted through the car features.

7 Discussion

We find empirical evidence that fiscal vehicle policies significantly affect emission intensities of new bought cars. A greater \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-sensitivity of registration taxes lead to the purchase of more fuel-efficient cars. A 1 % increase in the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity of vehicle purchase taxes reduces the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of the average new vehicle by about 0.1 %. The changes in registration taxes from 2001 to 2010 have reduced the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission intensity of the average new car by 1.3 %. The diesel–petrol substitution induced by changes in the relative taxes for diesel versus petrol cars is an important factor for the average fleet’s fuel efficiency. We also find higher \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensities with increasing income and a clear convergence pattern between EU countries.

This paper is one of the first including annual road taxes, in addition to registration and fuel taxes, in the analysis of car purchase behaviour. But contrary to Ryan et al., who found that an increase in petrol circulation taxes of 10 % could result in a decrease in fleet \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions of 0.3 g/km in the short run and 1.4 g in the long run, we find that an increase in the annual road tax level and \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) sensitivity increases the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) intensity of new petrol cars. We are not sure what causes this finding. It is not obvious that individuals account for future annual tax expenses, as discussed in Sect. 2. It is possibly because annual road taxes are not salient, but the high collinearity between annual road taxes may also play a role.

We find that higher petrol fuel taxes tend to reduce the fleet’s emission intensity, while diesel fuel taxes tend to reduce average emissions for the diesel fleet but also induce substitution of petrol cars for diesel cars. The finding is consistent with Ryan et al. (2009), but a subtle and important distinction from the general conclusion in the literature that higher petrol prices tend to lead to more fuel efficient cars (Davis and Kilian 2011; Burke and Nishitateno 2013; Klier and Linn 2013).

There is a clear positive potential for fiscal instruments as part of the set of policy measures aimed at reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions from cars.Footnote 30 Our findings thus support the European Commission’s third policy pillar. Yet, we should not overstate the contribution of registration taxes. The overall effect of the registration tax changes that we identify, a 1.3 % improvement of fuel efficiency, is small compared to the overall achievement over the period observed (Fig. 1). Innovation and other policy instruments have played a substantial role. In that context, it is important to understand that various policy instruments can strengthen, but also counter each other. In the European Directive EC/443/2009 car manufacturers are evaluated (from 2015 onwards) based on their average emissions of cars sold across all EU countries. Increased sales of fuel efficient cars in one country thus allows manufactures to sell more fuel inefficient cars in other countries. The principle, sometimes referred to as a ‘waterbed-effect’, implies that environmental gains from fiscal national policies can leak away as the sale of more fuel-efficient cars in a country with a fiscal regime that puts a large premium on \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, is countered by the sale of more fuel-intensive cars in other countries. National fiscal policies, aimed at the demand side, and in line with the third pillar of EU policies, might thus be less effective conditional on the effectiveness of the first pillar of EU policy, aimed at the supply of fuel efficient cars throughout the EU. Given an exogenously set ceiling for the EU-wide \(\hbox {CO}_{2 }\) emissions, there is no clear economic gain from a diversified fiscal regime between EU countries, while there are social costs (Hoen and Geilenkirchen 2006). Indeed, a few years ago, the EU proposed to harmonize vehicle taxes in the EU, but the proposal was rejected by the Member States. We also mention a few other potential disadvantages of fiscal support of fuel efficient cars.

In this paper, we focus on the average emission intensity of new cars. Reducing taxes for small, fuel-efficient cars can lead to scale effects (i.e. more cars) and intensity-of-use effects (i.e. more kilometres per car). Konishi and Meng (2014) show that in a green tax reform in Japan, this scale effect offset the composition effect (i.e. a bigger share of fuel-efficient cars) by approximately two third. In addition, there is a rebound effect. Fuel-efficient cars are cheaper to drive, and a portion of the \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) gains by \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)-based vehicle purchase tax is lost as the fuel-efficient cars increase car travel demand (Khazzoom 1980). The existence of the effect is undisputed, but its magnitude remains an issue of debate (see e.g. Brookes 2000; Binswanger 2001; Sorrell and Dimitroupolos 2008). Frondel and Vance (2014) estimated that 44–71 % of potential energy savings from efficiency improvements in Germany between 1997 and 2012 were lost due to increased driving. The rebound effect may be mitigated if part of the increase in sales of new, clean cars is due to consumers sooner retiring their less-efficient cars.

Of the policies aimed at reducing \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions, excise fuel duties most directly target the environmental objective, specifically since the use of the car is accountable for about 80 % of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions in its life-cycle (Gbegbaje-Das 2013). Fuel excise duties are also closer to the ‘polluter pays-principle’, one of the leading principles of European Environmental Policy (European Parliament and Council 2004). Taxing fuels would lead to more efficient cars and lower mileage without rebound effects (Chugh and Cropper 2014), making it the preferred instrument for reducing road transport emissions. Yet significant fuel tax increases are politically costly.

There are also secondary effects of fiscal policies. When consumers choose lighter cars that are more fuel efficient, not only \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions fall but emissions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) and \(\hbox {PM}_{10}\) as well. A weight reduction of 10 % results in a decrease of the emission of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) with 3–4 % \(\hbox {NO}_\mathrm{x}\) (Nijland et al. 2012). On the other hand, substituting diesel cars for petrol cars improves \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) fuel efficiency by about 10–20 %, yet increases the emissions of \(\hbox {NO}_{\mathrm{x}}\) (Nijland et al. 2012). In the case of \(\hbox {PM}_{10}\) the situation is not clear, as modern petrol cars with direct injection might emit more \(\hbox {PM}_{10}\) than modern diesel cars (Köhler 2013). Lighter cars also reduce fatalities for drivers of other vehicles, pedestrians, bicyclists, and motorcyclists (Gayer 2004; White 2004). The design of the fiscal regime, encouraging lighter cars or encouraging diesel cars, can alter the secondary effects substantially.

We used \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emission data according to the NEDC guidelines. It is known that the tests typically report lower emissions compared to realistic conditions, especially for cars that score very well at the tests (Ligterink and Bos 2010; Ligterink and Eijk 2014). Moreover, the gap between test results and realistic estimates for normal use have increased over time; from about 8 % in 2001 to 21 % in 2011, with a particularly strong increase since 2007 (Mock et al. 2012, 2014). The gap between test values and estimates of realistic use values also affects the estimated emission of air pollutants, particularly the emissions of NOx from diesel cars (e.g. Hausberger 2006; Vonk and Verbeek 2010). To continue the use of test-cycles therefore requires an update of procedures and improvement of their reliability as predictor of real-life use.

Finally, we mention three limitations of our study. We proxy the fiscal treatment of personal vehicles, assuming that taxes change continuously with \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions. Yet, there are indications that consumers are more sensitive to discrete price increases, such as tax breaks for cars that meet specific criteria (see e.g. Finkelstein 2009; Klier and Linn 2015; Kok 2013). This study did not explicitly model these elements of tax design. Second, about half of the new sales in Europe are company cars (Copenhagen Economics 2010). One of the reasons for their widespread use is their beneficial tax treatment (Gutierrez-i-Puigarnau and van Ommeren 2011), including implicit subsidies as employees often do not bear the variable costs of private use (Copenhagen Economics 2010). Therefore, private consumers and business consumers react differently to price signals such as fiscal rules and fuel taxes. We do not have available data on the two separate markets and must leave this topic to future research. Third, we did not consider other fiscal measures such as the scrap subsidies which had major effects on sales in various countries, though the effects on the fuel efficiency is considered limited (Grigolon et al. 2016).