Skip to main content
Log in

A Tradable Permit System in an Intertemporal Economy

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is known that in an intertemporal competitive economy, a tradable permit system may not achieve efficiency without setting appropriate permit interest rates (i.e., rewards for holding permits). To find the rates, however, we need to know in advance the path of efficient permit prices, which is difficult to obtain. This study intends to solve this problem in two ways. First, we analyze a special case in which the permit interest rates are given by a simple rule. For example, if the marginal abatement cost of pollution emission is constant, then the appropriate rate is to equal the monetary interest rate. As is the case for global warming, if the damage is caused in the future far beyond the planning period of the environmental program, the appropriate rate coincides with the marginal self-recovery of environmental stock under certain conditions. As a second approach, we propose a tradable permit system with a permit bank, as a mechanism by which the permit interest rates are generated endogenously without governmental intervention other than the issuance of permits. However, we also show that this approach raises the problem of indeterminacy of the equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is also called permit trading ratio or permit discount rate in the literature.

  2. Such a special case is studied by Cronshaw and Kruse (1996) and Rubin (1996) where only the total emissions over a planning period matter. In that case, the efficient equilibrium price of permits follows the Hotelling rule.

  3. Stokey (1998), Newell et al. (2005) and Jouvet et al. (2005) use infinite time horizon general equilibrium models. The focus of these papers is different from the present paper: Stokey (1998) compares policy instruments including a tradable permit system; Newell et al. (2005) focus on the price fluctuations of permits under uncertainty; and Jouvet et al. (2005) highlight the distribution problem of permits.

  4. An exception is the Lead Trading Program in the United States (1982–1987), where no banking was allowed initially. However, it was allowed in late 1984.

  5. While the permit interest rate determines the intertemporal relative prices of the permits, the number of permits issued determines the initial price level.

  6. The notation \(f_{x}\) for a function \(f\) denotes the partial derivative with respect to its argument \(x\): \(f_{x}:=\partial f/\partial x\).

  7. When the corner solution (no abatement) is socially optimal, our results derived from the firms’ side should be modified to include the relevant Lagrange multiplier.

  8. The domain of \(F\) is given by \(\{(K,X)\in \mathbb R _{+}^{2}:X\le \bar{X}(K)\}\), where \(\bar{X} (K)=\max \left\{ \sum _{i=1}^{m}\phi ^{i}(K^{i})\right.\left.|\sum _{i=1}^{m}K^{i}\le K\right\} .\)

  9. Alternatively, we may consider a tradable permit system in which the permits \(B^{i}(t)\) are issued at each time instant \(t\ge 0\). This is equivalent to the once-and-for-all issuance of the permits \(B_{0}^{i}\) such that

    $$\begin{aligned} B_{0}^{i}=\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }B^{i}(t)\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}a(s)ds\right] dt, \end{aligned}$$

    because we eliminate uncertainty and the borrowing constraint in this paper.

  10. All proofs are presented in the “Appendix”.

  11. See Lemma 6.1 in the “Appendix”.

  12. If the marginal abatement cost of the pollution \(F_{X}(K,X)\) is also constant, we have \(a(t)=r(t)=\rho \) for all \(t\ge 0\). In this case, the associated Hamiltonian is linear in \(X\). Then, the optimal path is composed of a singular control (interior steady state) and a bang-bang control (no production or no abatement). The existence of equilibrium excludes the bang-bang control, implying that the economy is always at an interior steady state. Then, \(a(t)=r(t)=\rho \) holds.

  13. See, for example, Stokey (1998), and Aghion and Howitt (1998), chapter 5 for a theoretical treatment. Note that the increasing part of the optimal Environmental Kuznets Curve in the Stokey’s model is due to the existence of the corner solutions.

  14. The reason for this is simply that the production technology of the economy is the same as the one in the flow pollution model.

  15. As the optimal pollution stock and emissions \((S^{*}(t),X^{*}(t))\) depend on the planning period \(T\), the permit interest rate \(a(t)\) also depends on \(T\) in principle. Here, we suppress \(T\) in these functions.

  16. (2.52) can be translated into a very familiar form in environmental and resource economics literature. Define the quality of the environment by \(E=\bar{S}-S\). Then the law of motion of \(E\) is given by \(\dot{E}=\theta E-X\).

  17. This explanation is conveyed by a referee of this journal. We are grateful to the referee for the insightful suggestion.

References

  • Akao K, Managi S (2007) A tradable permit system in an intertemporal economy. Waseda University, GIARI Working Paper

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Wallace WE (1988) The theory of environmental policy, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson C, Burtraw D, Cropper M (2000) Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: what are the gains from trade? J Polit Econ 108:1292–1326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (2003) Trade and the environment: theory and evidence. Princeton University Press, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Cronshaw MB, Kruse J (1996) Regulated firms in pollution permit markets with banking. J Regul Econ 9:179–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gren I-M, Folmer H (2003) Cooperation with respect to cleaning of an international water body with stochastic environmental damage: the case of the Baltic Sea. Ecol Econ 47:33–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (2007) Climate change 2007—the physical science basis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Jouvet P-A, Michel P, Rotillon G (2005) Optimal growth with pollution: how to use pollution permits? J Econ Dyn Control 29:1597–1609

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kling C, Rubin J (1997) Bankable permits for the control of environmental pollution. J Public Econ 64:101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruger J, Pizer W (2004) Greenhouse gas trading in Europe: the new grand policy experiment. Environment 46(8):8–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Mayraz G, Nickell S (2008) The marginal utility of income. J Public Econ 92(8–9):1846–1857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiby P, Rubin J (2001) Intertemporal permit trading for the control of greenhouse gas emissions. Environ Resour Econ 19:229–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Léonard D (1987) Costate variables correctly value stocks at each instant: a proof. J Econ Dyn Control 11:117–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery WD (1972) Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs. J Econ Theory 5:395–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell R, Pizer W, Zhang J (2005) Managing permit markets to stabilize prices. Environ Resour Econ 31:133–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1999) Discounting and public policies that affect the distant future. In: Portney PR, Weyant JP (eds) Discounting and intergenerational equity. Resource for the Future, Washington, DC, pp 145–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin J (1996) A model of international emission trading, banking, and borrowing. J Environ Econ Manag 31:269–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey NL (1998) Are there limits to growth? Int Econ Rev 39:1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smulders S (1999) Endogenous growth theory and the environment. In: van den Berg JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 610–621

    Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg TH (2006) Emissions trading: principles and practice, 2nd edn. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Yates AJ, Cronshaw MB (2001) Pollution permit markets with intertemporal trading and asymmetric information. J Environ Econ Manag 42:104–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas A (2003) Economic growth and environment. In: Mäler K-G, Vincent J (eds) Handbook of environmental economics, vol 3. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1220–1271

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to two anonymous referees of this journal for their detailed and helpful comments and the constructive criticism. Financial supports are acknowledged: MEXT Kakenhi (K. Akao: 23330065, 19530161, 18078004, GCOE E11; S. Managi: 70372456, 24330070).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ken-Ichi Akao.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

1.1 Proposition 2.1

The proof proceeds in three steps. First, we characterize the choices of individual firms at equilibrium. Second, we relate the aggregated values of individual firms’ choices to the representative firm. Finally, we verify that the aggregated values are the solution to the profit maximization problem of the representative firm.

Lemma 6.1

At equilibrium, the following hold:

$$\begin{aligned}&\text{ Arbitrage} \text{ condition}\text{:} a(t)=r(t)-\frac{\dot{p}(t)}{p(t)},\end{aligned}$$
(6.1)
$$\begin{aligned}&\text{ Market} \text{ clearing} \text{ condition}\text{:} \sum _{i=1}^{m}y^{ie}(t)=0, \end{aligned}$$
(6.2)

and, for each firm \(i\), profit maximization condition:

$$\begin{aligned} F_{k}^{i}(k^{ie}(t),x^{ie}(t))&= r(t),\end{aligned}$$
(6.3)
$$\begin{aligned} F_{x}^{i}(k^{ie}(t),x^{ie}(t))&= p(t),\end{aligned}$$
(6.4)
$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }p(t)y^{ie}(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) dt&= \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }p(t)x^{ie}(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) dt-p(0)B_{0}^{i}, \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.5)

where (6.5) implies that the no-Ponzi game condition in (2.12) holds with equality.

Proof

For firm \(i\), the current value Hamiltonian is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} H^{i}(k,x,y,b,\zeta ^{i})=\left[ F^{i}(k,x)-r(t)k-p(t)y\right] +\zeta ^{i}\left[ a(t)b-x+y\right] . \end{aligned}$$

The first order conditions are:

$$\begin{aligned} \text{(a)} F_{k}^{i}(k^{ie}(t),x^{ie}(t))&= r(t); \text{(b)} F_{x} ^{i}(k^{ie}(t),x^{ie}(t))=\zeta ^{i}(t), \text{(c)} \zeta ^{i} (t)=p(t),\end{aligned}$$
(6.6)
$$\begin{aligned} \dot{\zeta }^{i}(t)&= \zeta ^{i}(t)\left[ r(t)-a(t)\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(6.7)

The transversality condition is:

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\zeta ^{i}(t)b^{i}(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0} ^{t}r(s)ds\right) =0. \end{aligned}$$
(6.8)

(6.6) implies (6.3) and (6.4). (6.6 c) and (6.7) imply the arbitrage condition (6.1). (6.1) is rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} \exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}a(s)ds\right) =\frac{p(t)}{p(0)}\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.9)

Substitute (6.6 c) and (6.9) into (6.8) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }p(0)b^{i}(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}a(s)ds\right) =0, \end{aligned}$$
(6.10)

which shows that the no-Ponzi game condition in (2.12) holds at equilibrium. The initial value problem (2.11) is solved as:

$$\begin{aligned} b^{i}(T)=\left[ \int \limits _{0}^{T}(-x^{ie}(t)+y^{ie}(t))\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0} ^{t}a(s)ds\right) dt+B_{0}^{i}\right] \exp \left( \int \limits _{0}^{T}a(t)dt\right) .\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(6.11)

Then, substitute (6.11) into (6.10) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }p(0)\left[ \int \limits _{0}^{T}(-x^{ie}(t)+y^{ie}(t))\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}a(s)ds\right) dt+B_{0}^{i}\right] =0. \end{aligned}$$
(6.12)

Then, substitute (6.9) into (6.12) and arrange to obtain (6.5). Finally, the market clearing condition (6.2) must hold at equilibrium. \(\square \)

Lemma 6.2

For each point in time \(t\), (i) the equilibrium firms’ choice \(\{k^{ie} (t),x^{ie}(t)\}_{i=1}^{m}\) is the solution for the problem (2.1). (ii) The aggregate production function satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} F_{K}\left( K^{e}(t),X^{e}(t\right) )=r(t) \text{ and} F_{X}\left( K^{e}(t),X^{e}(t\right) )=p(t), \end{aligned}$$
(6.13)

where \(K^{e}(t)=\sum _{i=1}^{m}k^{ie}(t)\) and \(X^{e}(t)=\sum _{i=1}^{m} x^{ie}(t)\).

Proof

(i) The Lagrangian associated with the problem on the right-hand side of (2.1) is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} L(K,X)=\sum _{i=1}^{m}F^{i}(k^{i},x^{i})+\xi \left( K-\sum _{i=1}^{m} k^{i}\right) +\eta \left( X-\sum _{i=1}^{m}x^{i}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.14)

By the concavity of \(F^{i}\) and the Inada condition, the necessary and sufficient condition for the solution is given by \(K=\sum _{i=1}^{m}k^{i} \), \(X=\sum _{i=1}^{m}x^{i}\),

$$\begin{aligned} F_{k}^{i}(k^{i},x^{i})&= F_{k}^{j}(k^{j},x^{j})=\xi \text{ and} \nonumber \\ F_{x}^{i} (k^{j},x^{j})&= F_{x}^{j}(k^{j},x^{j})=\eta \text{ for} \text{ all} i,j\in \{1,2,\ldots ,m\}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.15)

This in fact holds by (6.3) and (6.4). (ii) By the envelope theorem:

$$\begin{aligned} F_{K}\left( K^{e}(t),X^{e}(t\right) )=\xi \text{ and} F_{X}\left( K^{e}(t),X^{e}(t\right) )=\eta . \end{aligned}$$
(6.16)

Then, (6.13) follows from (6.3), (6.4), (6.15) and (6.16).

Proof of Proposition 2.1

(a) The representative firm’s problem (2.13) is formally the same as the individual firm’s problem (2.9). As the problem is a concave program, the first order condition and the transversality condition are sufficient for optimality. As shown in (6.13) in Lemma 6.2, \(\left( K^{e}(t),X^{e}(t\right) )\) satisfies the first order condition. The aggregate balance of permits \(B^{e}(t)=\sum _{i=1}^{m}b^{ie}(t)\) satisfies the no-Ponzi game condition in (2.13) with equality because each firm satisfies the same condition. This implies that the transversality condition is satisfied as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }p(0)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}a(s)ds\right) B^{e}(t)=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }p(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) B^{e}(t)=0,\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(6.17)

where the first equality follows from (6.9). The market clearing condition determines the aggregate permit trade as \(Y^{e}(t)=\sum _{i=1} ^{m}y^{ie}(t)=0\). (b) From the proof so far, it is obvious that the results hold independent of the permit distribution, as far as all \(m\) firms exist at equilibrium. This condition holds because of the concavity of the production function and the Inada condition, even if a firm is not endowed with any permits and has to buy permits at each point in time. That is, such a firm can gain a nonnegative profit as seen from:

$$\begin{aligned} F^{i}(k,x)=F^{i}(k,x)-F^{i}(0,0)\ge F_{K}^{i}(k,x)k+F_{X}^{i}(k,x)x=rk+px. \end{aligned}$$
(6.18)

1.2 Proposition 2.2

When the equilibrium path is optimal, i.e., \((c^{e}(t),X^{e}(t),K^{e} (t))=(c^{*}(t),X^{*}(t),K^{*}(t))\) and the equilibrium prices \((r^{e}(t),p^{e}(t))\) are given as in the first order conditions for the firm (2.19), the first order conditions for the households (2.21) are satisfied with \(\lambda (t)=\lambda ^{*}(t)\). Then, what we have to prove here is that the household satisfies the transversality conditions (2.21 c) and the no-Ponzi game condition in (2.17). Because \(m^{e}(t)=K^{*}(t)\) at equilibrium, this follows from the transversality condition for the social planner’s problem (2.8) and from (2.8):

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\rho t}\lambda ^{*}(t)K^{*}(t)=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\rho t}\lambda ^{*}(t)m(t)=\lambda ^{*}(0)\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }m(t)\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right] =0, \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.19)

where the second equality is obtained from (2.21 b).

1.3 Proposition 2.3

The proof is quite similar to the proof of Proposition 2.2. Therefore, we address the differences. Suppose that an equilibrium path is optimal, i.e., \((c^{e}(t),X^{e}(t),K^{e}(t),S^{e}(t))=(c^{*}(t),X^{*}(t),K^{*}(t),S^{*}(t))\). By (2.19 b) and (2.34), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} p^{e}(t)=F_{X}(K^{*}(t),X^{*}(t))=\frac{\xi ^{*}(t)}{\lambda ^{*}(t)}A_{X}(S^{*}(t),X^{*}(t)). \end{aligned}$$
(6.20)

Substitute this and (2.21 b) into (2.19 c) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} a(t)=\left( \rho -\frac{\dot{\lambda }^{*}(t)}{\lambda ^{*}(t)}\right) -\left( \frac{\dot{\xi }^{*}(t)}{\xi ^{*}(t)}+\frac{d\ln \left[ A_{X}(S^{*}(t),X^{*}(t))\right] }{dt}-\frac{\dot{\lambda }^{*} (t)}{\lambda ^{*}(t)}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.21)

From (2.36), we have (2.39). Notice that \(\xi ^{*} (t)=-V_{S}(K^{*}(t),S^{*}(t))\) by Léonard (1987).

1.4 Proposition 2.4

Note first that (2.50) is the finite time version of (2.15). Regarding (2.51), by the same argument as the proof of Proposition 2.3, we obtain (6.21) for the global warming model. Substitution of (2.43) and (2.44) into (6.21) yields (2.51). Finally, for this model, (2.19 b and c) and (2.21 a and b) hold. They imply (2.27) in Proposition 2.2.

1.5 Proposition 3.1

Let \(r^{*}\) and \(p^{*}\) be the equilibrium prices. Suppose that the household expects the path of pollution \(\tilde{X}(t)=X^{*}(t)\) for the flow pollution model and \(\tilde{S}(t)=S^{*}(t)\) for the stock pollution model. For the flow pollution model, there are the costates \(\lambda ^{*}(t)\) and \(\mu ^{*}(t)\) with which the optimal controls \(c^{*}(t)\) and \(X^{*}(t)\) satisfy (2.52.8). Then, it is easy to see that the optimal path satisfies the sufficient conditions for the firm (3.4) and the household (3.5). Notice that the firm’s transversality condition is satisfied:

$$\begin{aligned} Q(T)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{T}r^{*}(t)dt\right) =Q(0)-\int \limits _{0}^{T}p^{*}(t)X^{*}(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r^{*}(s)ds\right) dt=0,\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.22)

where the first equality follows from (3.1) and the second equality follows from (3.6). The same argument is applied to the stock pollution model.

1.6 Proposition 4.1

Recall that the steady state \(\left( K_{\infty },z_{ss}\right) \) of the system of differential equations (4.7 a) and (4.7 c) depends on \(\omega \). If \(\omega =K_{ss}/z_{ss}^{\left( 1-\alpha +\alpha /\sigma \right) }\), then \(K_{\infty }=K_{ss}=K_{0}\) and the equilibrium path keeps the initial stock level, which is socially optimal. If \(\omega >K_{ss}/z_{ss}^{\left( 1-\alpha +\alpha /\sigma \right) }\), then \(K_{\infty }>K_{ss}\). This case is illustrated in Fig. 1 where point A is \(K_{ss}\). Because the equilibrium path increases along the stable manifold, \(z(t)<z_{ss}\) and \(K(t)>K_{ss}\) for all \(t\ge 0\). This implies that (4.7 d) is not satisfied:

$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }\left[ K(t)/z(t)\right] e^{-\rho t}dt>\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }\left( K_{ss}/z_{ss}\right) e^{-\rho t}dt=B_{ss}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.23)

Therefore, this case is ruled out. Consider the case of \(\omega <K_{ss} /z_{ss}^{\left( 1-\alpha +\alpha /\sigma \right) }\). This time, point B on Fig. 1 is \(K_{ss}\). The symmetric argument concludes that this case is also ruled out. Therefore, we have a unique \(\omega =K_{ss}/z_{ss}^{\left( 1-\alpha +\alpha /\sigma \right) }\) and a unique equilibrium path satisfying (4.7) that coincides with the optimal path of the social planner’s problem.

1.7 Proposition 4.2

We prove Proposition 4.2 in a heuristic way. Take arbitrarily a path of interest rates \(r(t)\) (\(t>0\)) such that \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }r(t)=\rho \). Note that we do not determine \(r(0)\), but it does not invalidate the argument below. Using \(r(t)\), \(F(K(t),X(t))\) is written as:

$$\begin{aligned} F(K(t),X(t))=\frac{r(t)}{\alpha }K(t). \end{aligned}$$
(6.24)

From (4.10 a, c), there is \(c_{0}>0\) and it holds that:

$$\begin{aligned} c(t)=\exp \left[ \int \limits _{0}^{t}\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }ds\right] c_{0}=-\dot{K}(t)+\frac{r(t)}{\alpha }K(t), K(0)=K_{0}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.25)

This equation is solved as:

$$\begin{aligned} K(t)=\exp \left[ \int \limits _{0}^{t}\frac{r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] \left\{ K_{0}-c_{0}\int \limits _{0}^{t}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{s}\left( \frac{r(\nu )}{\alpha }-\frac{r(\nu )-\rho }{\sigma }\right) d\nu \right] ds\right\} . \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.26)

The no-Ponzi game condition (4.10 b) is satisfied only if:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{0}=\frac{K_{0}}{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{r(s)}{\alpha }-\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }\right) ds\right] dt}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.27)

Note that the denominator on the right-hand side of (6.27) is finite because

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{r(t)}{\alpha }-\frac{r(t)-\rho }{\sigma } =\frac{\rho }{\alpha }>0 \end{aligned}$$
(6.28)

(see Lemma 6.4 below). With (6.27), the no-Ponzi game condition (4.10 b) holds as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\liminf _{t\rightarrow \infty }K(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}F_{K} (K(s),X(s))ds\right) \nonumber \\&=\liminf _{t\rightarrow \infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right] \exp \left[ \int \limits _{0}^{t}\frac{r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] \nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad \times \left\{ K_{0}-c_{0}\int \limits _{0}^{t}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0} ^{s}\left( \frac{r(\nu )}{\alpha }-\frac{r(\nu )-\rho }{\sigma }\right) d\nu \right] ds\right\} \nonumber \\&=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\exp \left[ \int \limits _{0}^{t}\frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] \left\{ K_{0}-c_{0}\int \limits _{0}^{t} \exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{s}\left( \frac{r(\nu )}{\alpha }-\frac{r(\nu )-\rho }{\sigma }\right) d\nu \right] ds\right\} \nonumber \\&=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{K_{0}-c_{0}\int _{0}^{t}\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{s}\left( \frac{r(\nu )}{\alpha }-\frac{r(\nu )-\rho }{\sigma }\right) d\nu \right] ds}{-\exp \left[ \int _{0}^{t}\frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] }\nonumber \\&=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{c_{0}\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{r(s)}{\alpha }-\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }\right) ds\right] }{\frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(t)}{\alpha }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t} \frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] }\nonumber \\&=\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{c_{0}\alpha }{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(t)}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{r(s)}{\alpha }-\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }\right) -\frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) r(s)}{\alpha }ds\right] \nonumber \\&=\frac{c_{0}\alpha }{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \rho }\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\frac{\rho -(1-\sigma )r(s)}{\sigma }ds\right] \nonumber \\&=0, \end{aligned}$$
(6.29)

because \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\rho -(1-\sigma )r(t)=\sigma \rho >0\). Letting \(Q_{0}=F_{X}(K_{0},X(0))B_{0}\), the differential equation in (4.10 d) is rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{Q}(t)=r(t)Q(t)-(1-\alpha )F(K(t),X(t)),\quad Q(0)=Q_{0} , \end{aligned}$$
(6.30)

and this is solved as:

$$\begin{aligned} Q(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) -Q_{0}=-(1-\alpha )\int \limits _{0} ^{t}F(K(s),X(s))\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds. \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.31)

Using the following result:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int \limits _{0}^{t}F(K(s),X(s))\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds\nonumber \\&=\int \limits _{0}^{t}\left( \dot{K}(s)+c(s)\right) \exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s} r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds\nonumber \\&=\left[ K(s)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) \right] _{s=0}^{t}\nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad +\alpha \int \limits _{0}^{t}\alpha ^{-1}r(s)K(s)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0} ^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds+\int \limits _{0}^{t}c(s)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds\nonumber \\&=K(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(\nu )d\nu \right) -K_{0}\nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad +\alpha \int \limits _{0}^{t}F(K(s),X(s))\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s} r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds+\int \limits _{0}^{t}c(s)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds, \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.32)

we have:

$$\begin{aligned} Q(t)&= \exp \left[ \int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right] \nonumber \\&\quad \times \left[ Q_{0}+K_{0}-K(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(\nu )d\nu \right) -\int \limits _{0}^{t}c(s)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{s}r(\nu )d\nu \right) ds\right] . \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.33)

The no-Ponzi game condition (4.10 e) holds if and only if:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{0}=\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }c(t)\exp \left( -\int \limits _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) dt-K_{0}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.34)

Using (6.27), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{0}&= \frac{K_{0}\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ \int _{0}^{t}\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }ds\right] \exp \left( -\int _{0}^{t}r(s)ds\right) dt}{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{r(s)}{\alpha } -\frac{r(s)-\rho }{\sigma }\right) ds\right] dt}-K_{0}\nonumber \\&= K_{0}\left\{ \frac{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\frac{\rho -(1-\sigma )r(s)}{\sigma }ds\right] }{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{\rho -(1-\sigma )r(s)}{\sigma }+\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }r(s)\right) ds\right] dt}-1\right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(6.35)

As:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{0}=F_{X}(K_{0},X(0))B_{0}=(1-\alpha )(K_{0}/X(0))^{\alpha }B_{0}, \end{aligned}$$
(6.36)

when we choose:

$$\begin{aligned} X(0)&= K_{0}^{-\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }}\left[ (1-\alpha )B_{0}\right] ^{\frac{1}{\alpha }}\nonumber \\&\quad \times \left\{ \frac{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\frac{\rho -(1-\sigma )r(s)}{\sigma }ds\right] }{\int _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int _{0}^{t}\left( \frac{\rho -(1-\sigma )r(s)}{\sigma }+\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }r(s)\right) ds\right] dt}-1\right\} ^{-\frac{1}{\alpha }}, \end{aligned}$$
(6.37)

the no-Ponzi game condition holds and (4.10 e) is satisfied. Finally, \(X(t)\) (\(t>0\)) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} X(t)=\left( \frac{r(t)}{\alpha }\right) ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}K(t). \end{aligned}$$
(6.38)

Summing up the above results, we have:

Lemma 6.3

For any positive measurable function \(r:(0,\infty )\rightarrow \mathbb R _{++}\) satisfying \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }r(t)=\rho \), there is an equilibrium path on which \(r(t)\) is the equilibrium interest rate. The equilibrium path is characterized by: (a) (6.25) for the consumption path with the initial value (6.27), (b) (6.26) for the capital stock path, (c) (6.38) for the pollution path with the initial value (6.37), and (d) (6.33) for the path of the permit values with the initial value given by (6.36).

Proof of Proposition 4.2

The statement in Proposition 4.2 is an immediate result from the above lemma.

Lemma 6.4

If measurable function \(\xi (t)\) satisfies \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\xi (t)=\xi >0\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt<\infty . \end{aligned}$$

Proof

As \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\xi (t)=\xi >0\), there are positive numbers \(\varepsilon \) and \(T\) such that \(|\xi (t)-\xi |<\varepsilon \) for all \(t>T\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned}&\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt\nonumber \\&=\int \limits _{0}^{T}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt+\int \limits _{T}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt.\nonumber \\&=\int \limits _{0}^{T}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt+\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{T}\xi (s)ds\right] \int \limits _{T}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{T}^{t} \xi (s)ds\right] dt\nonumber \\&<\int \limits _{0}^{T}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt+\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{T}\xi (s)ds\right] \int \limits _{T}^{\infty }\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{T}^{t} |\xi -\varepsilon |ds\right] dt\nonumber \\&=\int \limits _{0}^{T}\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{t}\xi (s)ds\right] dt+\exp \left[ -\int \limits _{0}^{T}\xi (s)ds\right] \frac{\exp \left( |\xi -\varepsilon |T\right) -1}{|\xi -\varepsilon |}\nonumber \\&<\infty . \end{aligned}$$
(6.39)

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Akao, KI., Managi, S. A Tradable Permit System in an Intertemporal Economy. Environ Resource Econ 55, 309–336 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9628-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9628-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation