Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Optimal Timing of Adoption of a Green Technology

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the optimal timing of adoption of a cleaner technology and its effects on the rate of growth of an economy in the context of an AK endogenous growth model. We show that the results depend upon the behavior of the marginal utility of environmental quality with respect to consumption. When it is increasing, we derive the capital level at the optimal timing of adoption. We show that this capital threshold is independent of the initial conditions on the stock of capital, implying that capital-poor countries tend to take longer to adopt. Also, country-specific characteristics, as the existence of high barriers to adoption, may lead to different capital thresholds for different countries. If the marginal utility of environmental quality decreases with consumption, a country should never delay adoption; the optimal policy is either to adopt immediately or, if adoption costs are “too high”, to never adopt. The policy implications of these results are discussed in the context of the international debate surrounding the environmental political agenda.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Balvers R. J., Bergstrand J. H. (1997) Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates: Closed-Form Theoretical Solutions and Some Empirical Evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance 16 (3):345–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg, A. L. and S. Smulders (1995), ‘Environmental Quality and Pollution-Augmenting Technological Change in a Two-sector Endogenous Growth Model’, Journal of Public Economics 57, 369–391

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. and M. S. Taylor (2003), ‘The Kindergarten Rule of Sustainable Growth’, NBER Working-Paper # 9597

  • Brock, W. and M. S. Taylor (2004a), ‘Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of Theory and Empirics’, NBER Working-Paper # 10854

  • Brock, W. and M. S. Taylor (2004b), ‘The Green Solow Model’, NBER Working-Paper # 10557

  • Chimeli, A. and J. Braden (2002), ‘Environmental Quality, Environmental Protection and Technology Adoption’, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, mimeo

  • Dixit A., Pindyck R. (1994) Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Elbasha, E. H. and T. L. Roe (1996), ‘On Endogenous Growth: The Implications of Environmental Externalities’, Journal of Environmental Economics Management 31, 240–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J. and B. Jovanovic (2001), ‘Accounting for Growth’, in E. Dean, M. Harper and C. Hulten, eds., New Directions in Productivity Analysis, NBER Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 63. Chicago: Chicago University Press

  • Hall, B. H. and B. Khan (2003), ‘Adoption of New Technology’, NBER Working-Paper # 9730

  • Issler J. V., Piqueira N. S. (2000) Estimating Relative Risk Aversion, the Discount Rate, and the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution in Consumption for Brazil Using Three Types of Utility Function. Brazilian Review of Econometrics 20(2):201–239

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan A., Ravikumar B. (2002) Costly Technology Adoption and Capital Accumulation. Review of Economics Dynamics 5:489–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michel P., Rotillon G. (1995) Disutility of Pollution and Endogenous Growth. Environmental and Resource Economics 6(3):279-300

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001), Environmental Goods and Services. The Benefits of Further Trade Liberalization. Paris: OECD

  • Oxley A. (2002) Environment Protection and the WTO. In: Julian Morris (eds), Sustainable Development: Promoting Progress or Perpetuating Poverty?. Profile Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Parente S. (1994) Technology Adoption, Learning by Doing, and Economic Growth. Journal of Economic Theory 63:346–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reis A. (2001) Endogenous Growth and the Possibility of Eliminating Pollution. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 42:360–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P. (1994) New Goods, Old Theory, and The Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions. Journal of Development Economics 43:5–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seierstad, A. and K. Sydsaeter (1987), ‘Optimal Control Theory with Economic Applications’, in C. J. Bliss and M. D. Intrilligator, eds., Advanced Textbooks in Economics. North-Holland

  • Stokey N. (1998) Are There Limits to Growth?. International Economic Review 39:1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece D. J. (1977) Technology Transfer by Multinational Firms: The Resource Cost of Transferring Technological Know-How. Economic Journal 87:242-261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN, Press Release (1999), SG/SM/7237

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and the editor Sjak Smulders for helpful comments. Financial support from NOVAFORUM and FCT is also gratefully ackowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria A. Cunha-e-Sá.

Appendices

Appendix

Determination of V(T)

Derivation of (18)

 

Following Seierstad and Sydsaeter (1997), p. 196, an additional condition at the jump point has to hold. Given the magnitude of the jump, we may write that

$$ K_{T_{+}}-K_{T_{-}}=g(K_{T_{-}},\beta,T)=(\beta-1)K_{T_{-}} $$

Then, at the jump point, we have

$$ \lambda_{T_{+}}-\lambda_{T_{-}}=-\lambda_{T_{+}}\frac{\partial g(K_{T_{-}},\beta, T)}{\partial K_{T_{-}}} $$

that is,

$$ \lambda_{T_{+}}-\lambda_{T_{-}}=-\lambda_{T_{+}}(\beta-1) $$

which is equivalent to (18).

Expression for K t .

Utility can be represented by a function of K t and \({C_{t}/K_{t}}\), that is,

$$ V=\int_{0}^{\infty}\frac{C_{t}^{1-\sigma}(AK_{t})^{-\alpha\mu(1-\sigma)} a^{\mu (1-\sigma)}-1}{1-\sigma}e^{-\rho t}\,dt=\int_{0}^{\infty}\frac{\left(C_{t}/K_{t}\right)^{1-\sigma}K_{t} ^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}A^{-\alpha\mu(1-\sigma)}a^{\mu(1-\sigma)}-1} {1-\sigma}e^{-\rho t}\,dt $$

From (2), and substituting (20), we may write the level of K t at any moment before adoption as

$$ K_{t}=K_{0}e^{\int_{0}^{t}\left(A-\frac{\frac{\sigma-1}{\sigma}A+ \frac{\rho}{\sigma(1-\alpha\mu)}}{1+e^{-\Lambda(T-\tau)}\left[\delta ^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]}\right)d\tau} $$

Solving the integral we obtain

$$ K_{t}=K_{0}e^{At}\left[\frac{1+e^{-\Lambda(T-t)}\left[\delta^ {\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]}{e^{-\Lambda(T-t)}\left[\delta ^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]+e^{\Lambda t}}\right] ^{1/(1-\alpha\mu)} $$
(A1)

Notice that the primitive of \({\frac{\frac{\sigma-1}{\sigma}A+ \frac{\rho}{\sigma(1-\alpha\mu)}}{1+e^{-\Lambda(T-\tau)} \left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]}}\) is given by \({\left[-\frac{1}{1-\alpha\mu}\ln\left(e^{-\Lambda T}\left[\delta^ {\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]+e^{-\Lambda\tau}\right)\right]}\) Thus, with adoption at T, total welfare is given by

$$ \eqalign{ V(T)=& \int_{0}^{T}\frac{(C_{t}/K_{t})^{1-\sigma}K_{t}^{(1-\alpha\mu) (1-\sigma)}A^{-\alpha\mu(1-\sigma)}a_{0}^{\mu(1-\sigma)}-1}{1-\sigma}e^{-\rho t}\,dt+ \cr & +\int_{T}^{\infty}\frac{\left(C_{t}/K_{t}\right)^{1-\sigma}K_{t} ^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}(A)^{-\alpha\mu(1-\sigma)}a_{1}^{\mu (1-\sigma)}-1}{1-\sigma}e^{-\rho(t-T)}\,dt- \cr & -e^{-\rho T}(\gamma\upsilon+f) }<!endaligned> $$

where K t and \({C_{t}/K_{t}}\) in the first integral must be substituted by the expressions in (A1) and (20), respectively. The second integral is given by \({\varphi(K_{T_{+}})}\) where \({K_{T_{+}}=\beta K_{T_{-}}}\) and \({K_{T_{-}}}\) is given by (A1). After some algebra we obtain expression (21).

Proposition 1

 

Proof The derivative of V(T) is \({\frac{\partial V}{\partial T}=a_{0}^{\mu(1-\sigma)}K_{0}^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}L\Gamma +e^{-\rho T}\rho(\gamma\upsilon+f)}\), where Γ is defined as follows

$$ \Gamma=\sigma\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T}\left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)} {\sigma}}-1\right]\right]^{\sigma-1}e^{-\Lambda T}(-\Lambda) \left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right] $$

Recall that \({\Lambda > 0}\) to satisfy the transversality condition on capital (9), and that \({\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T}\left[\delta ^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]\right] > 0.}\)

For \({\delta < 1}\) and

  1. (i)

    \({\sigma < 1: L > 0}\) and \({\Gamma > 0\Longrightarrow \frac{\partial V(T)} {\partial T} > 0}.\)

  2. (ii)

    \({\sigma > 1:L < 0}\) and \({\Gamma < 0\Longrightarrow \frac{\partial V(T)}{\partial T} > 0}\).

Therefore, the country never adopts. □

Proposition 2

 

Proof The derivative of V(T) is \({\frac{\partial V}{\partial T}=e^{-\rho T}F(T)}\) where

$$ F(T)=a_{0}^{\mu(1-\sigma)}K_{0}^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}L\Gamma e^{\rho T}+\rho(\gamma \upsilon+f) $$

and \({\gamma}\) is defined above. Also, recall that costs decrease at the rate \({\rho}\) in present value terms.

Let \({\delta > 1}\). In this case, \({\frac{\partial V}{\partial T}}\) cannot be unambiguously signed, as the first term in F(T) is negative and the second is positive. Thus, we look at the behavior of \({\frac{\partial^{2}V}{\partial T^{2}}=e^{-\rho T} \left(\frac{\partial F}{\partial T}-\rho F(T)\right)}\). Moreover,

$$ \frac{\partial F}{\partial T}=e^{\rho T}\Gamma a_{0}^{\mu(1-\sigma)} K_{0}^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}L\frac{1-\sigma}{\sigma}\left [((1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho)+\sigma\Lambda\frac{e^{-\Lambda T}\left(\delta^ {\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right)}{1+e^{-\Lambda T}\left(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)} {\sigma}}-1\right)}\right] $$

where \({((1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho) > 0}\), \({\Lambda > 0}\) and \({\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T}\left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right] \right] > 0.}\)

  1. (i)

    \({\sigma < 1\Rightarrow L > 0, \Gamma < 0}\) and \({(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1) > 0}\). Thus, in this case, \({{\partial F}/{\partial T} < 0}\), implying that benefits decrease slower than costs. Also, F(0) can be either positive or negative and \({\lim\limits_{T\rightarrow+\infty}F(T)=-\infty.}\) Thus, \({{\partial V}/{\partial T}}\) may be positive or negative for small values of T but it is always negative for large enough T and goes to 0 as \({T\rightarrow+\infty}\). Therefore, we conclude that:

    1. (a)

      if \({\partial V/\partial T > 0}\) at T = 0 this implies that \({F(0) > 0}\) and F(T) decreases with T. At some \(t=T^{\ast}, F(T^{\ast})=0{\Rightarrow\frac{\partial V(T^{\ast})}{\partial T}=0}\) and \({({\partial^{2}V(T^{\ast})}/{\partial T^{2}}) < 0,}\) then \({\partial V/\partial T}\) becomes negative. Thus, \({V(T^{\ast})}\) is a maximum, as in Figure 1, and delaying is optimal;

    2. (b)

      if \({\partial V/\partial T < 0}\) at T = 0, then as F(T) decreases with T, \({\partial V/\partial T < 0}\) for all T, as illustrated in Figure 2, and the country adopts immediately.

  2. (ii)

    \({\sigma > 1\Rightarrow L < 0}\), \({\Gamma > 0}\) and \({(\delta ^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1) < 0}\). Thus, the term outside the square brackets in \({{\partial F}/{\partial T}}\) is positive but the terms inside the square brackets have opposite signs. Recall that \({0 < (1+e^{-\Lambda T}(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1)) < 1}\), and \({(1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho > 0}\). We show that the term inside the square brackets increases with T,

    $$ \frac{\partial\left[((1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho)+\sigma\Lambda\frac{e^{-\Lambda T}(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1)}{1+e^{-\Lambda T}(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1)}\right]}{\partial T}=\frac{-\sigma\left(-\Lambda\right)^{2}e^{-\Lambda T}(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1)}{\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T}(\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1)\right]^{2}} > 0 $$

    At T = 0, we have

    $$ \frac{\partial F}{\partial T}_{\mid T=0}=(1-\delta^{\frac{-(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}})A(1-\alpha\mu) \sigma+(1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho))\delta^{\frac{-(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}} $$

    From (19), in order to have \({\frac{C}{K} < A}\), this last expression has to be positive, implying that \({\frac{\partial F}{\partial T} > 0}\) for all T. Thus, benefits decrease faster than costs.

    F(0) can be either positive or negative and \({\lim\limits_{T\rightarrow+\infty}F(T)=\rho(\gamma\upsilon+f) > 0.}\) Thus, \({{\partial V}/{\partial T}}\) may be positive or negative for small values of T and goes to 0 as \({T\rightarrow+\infty}\). Therefore, we conclude that:

    1. (a)

      if \({\frac{\partial V}{\partial T} > 0}\) at T = 0, then it will always be positive, decreasing to zero as \({T\rightarrow\infty}\), and the country will never adopt;

    2. (b)

      if \({\frac{\partial V}{\partial T} < 0}\) at T = 0, as F(T) increases with T, it will keep increasing. At some \({t=T^{\ast},0 < T^{\ast} < \infty}\), \({F(T^{\ast})=0}\) and \({\frac{\partial ^{2}V(T^{\ast})}{\partial T^{2}} > 0}\), before becoming positive. Therefore, V(T) reaches its minimum at \({T^{\ast}}\). Therefore, the country adopts immediately if \({V(0) > V(\infty)}\) or never adopts. □

Proposition 3

 

Proof. Evaluating (A1) at \({t=T^{\ast}}\) and rearranging terms, we obtain that at \({T^{\ast}}\),

$$ {\small K}_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}=K_{0}{e}^{AT}\left[\frac{e^{-\Lambda T^{\ast}}\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}}{1+e^{-\Lambda T^{\ast}}\left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]}\right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\alpha\mu)}}{\small=K}_{0}\left[\frac{e^{\frac{(1-\sigma)} {\sigma}\left[(1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho\right]T^{\ast}}\delta^{\frac{ (1-\sigma)^{2}}{\sigma}}}{\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T^{\ast}}\left[\delta^ {\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]\right]^{(1-\sigma)}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma)(1-\alpha\mu)}} $$

Let \({\delta > 1}\), \({\sigma < 1}\), and \({0 < T^{\ast} < \infty}\). Rearranging (23), we obtain

$$ \frac{e^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}\left[(1-\alpha\mu)A-\rho\right] T^{\ast}}}{\left[1+e^{-\Lambda T^{\ast}}\left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)} {\sigma}}-1\right]\right]^{1-\sigma}}=\frac{\rho(\gamma\upsilon+f)} {a_{0}^{\mu(1-\sigma)}K_{0}^{(1-\alpha\mu)(1-\sigma)}L\left[\delta^ {\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right]\Lambda\sigma} $$

Substituting in the expression for \({K_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}}\), we obtain (24).

Moreover, let us denote \({\Phi}\) by

$$ \Phi=\left[L^{-1}\frac{\rho(\gamma\upsilon+f)\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma) ^{2}}{\sigma}}}{\left[\delta^{\frac{(1-\sigma)}{\sigma}}-1\right] \sigma \Lambda}\right]^{\frac{1}{(1-\sigma)(1-\alpha\mu)}} > 0 $$

Then,

$$ \frac{\partial K_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}}{\partial f}=a_{0}^{\frac{-\mu}{(1-\alpha\mu)}}\Phi\frac{(\gamma\upsilon+f) ^{-1}}{(1-\sigma)(1-\alpha\mu)} > 0 $$
$$ \frac{\partial K_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}}{\partial \upsilon}= a_{0}^{\frac{-\mu}{(1-\alpha\mu)}}\Phi\left[\frac{(\gamma\upsilon+f) ^{-1}\gamma}{(1-\sigma)(1-\alpha\mu)}\right] > 0 $$
$$ \frac{\partial K_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}}{\partial \gamma}=a_{0}^ {\frac{-\mu}{(1-\alpha\mu)}}\Phi\frac{(\gamma\upsilon+f)^{-1}\upsilon} {(1-\sigma)(1-\alpha\mu)} > 0 $$
$$ \frac{\partial K_{T_{-}^{\ast}}^{\ast}}{\partial a_{0}}=a_{0}^ {\frac{-\mu}{(1-\alpha\mu)}-1}\left(-\frac{\mu}{(1-\alpha\mu)}\right) \Phi < 0 $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cunha-e-Sá, M.A., Reis, A.B. The Optimal Timing of Adoption of a Green Technology. Environ Resource Econ 36, 35–55 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-006-9045-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-006-9045-8

Key words

JEL classifications

Navigation