Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Corruption control

  • Published:
Crime, Law and Social Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

How can we explain why countries that apply similar remedies against corruption vary so much in their actual incidence of corruption? While high penalties for business crime may prevent corruption in some situations, it may exacerbate the problem in others. We find enforcement of laws against corruption to depend on the form of cooperation between layers of law enforcement authority in the state administration. Small local differences in honesty and cooperation may lead to large differences in effective law enforcement and in actual levels of corruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Diaz-Cayeros, A., B. Magaloni and Romero, V. (2015). Caught in the crossfire: the geography of extortion and police corruption in Mexico. In S. Rose-Ackerman and P. Lagunes (Eds.) Greed, Corruption, and the Modern State: Essays in Political Economy, (pp. 252–276) Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

  2. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978). Corruption: A study in political economy. New York: Academic Press.

  3. Mookherjee, D., & Png, I. P. L. (1995). Corruptible law enforcers: how should they be compensated? The Economic Journal, 105, 145–159.

  4. Laffont, J. J., & Martimort, D. (1997). Collusion under asymmetric information. Econometrica, 875–911.

  5. Moene, K., & Chand, S. (1997). Breaking the vicious circle of the predatory state. Nordic Journal of Political Economy, 24, 21–29.

  6. Chand, S., & Moene, K. (1999). Controlling fiscal corruption. World Development, 27(7), 1129–1140.

  7. Garoupa, N., & Jellal, M. (2007). Further notes on information, corruption, and optimal law enforcement. European Journal of Law and Economics, 23(1), 59–69.

  8. Lambsdorff, J. G. (2007). The institutional economics of corruption and reform: Theory, evidence and policy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  9. Svensson, J. (2005). Eight questions about corruption. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 19–42.

  10. Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–244.

  11. Ugur, M., & Dasgupta, N. (2011). Evidence on the economic growth impacts of corruption in low-income countries and beyond. London: EPPI-Centre, University of London.

  12. Søreide, T. (2016). Corruption and criminal justice. Bridging economic and legal perspectives. Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

  13. World Justice Project (2015). WJP rule of law index 2015. Washington DC.: World Justice Project.

  14. Voigt, S., & Gutmann, J. (2015). On the wrong side of the law: causes and consequences of a corrupt judiciary. International Review of Law and Economics, 43, 156–166.

  15. Prado, M. M., & Carson, L. D. (2014). Brazilian anti-corruption legislation and its enforcement: potential lessons for institutional design. In IRIBA working paper 09. Manchester: International Research Initiative on Brazil and Africa.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Olken, B. A. (2009). Corruption perceptions vs. corruption reality. Journal of Public Economics, 93(7),950–964.

  17. Olken, B. A., & Pande, R. (2012). Corruption in developing countries. Annual Reviews of Economics, 41(1), 479–509.Søreide, T. (2009). Too risk averse to stay honest? Business corruption, uncertainty and attitudes toward risk. International Review of Law and Economics, 29, 388–395.

  18. Søreide, T. (2009). Too risk averse to stay honest? Business corruption, uncertainty and attitudes toward risk. International Review of Law and Economics, 29, 388–395.

  19. Hjelmeng, E. and Søreide, T. (2016). Bribes, crimes and law enforcement. European Business Law Review, forthcoming.

  20. Høyland, B., Moene, K., & Willumsen, F. (2012). The tyranny of international index rankings. Journal of Development Economics, 97(1), 1–14.

  21. Lambsdorff, J. G. and G. G. (2015). Guest editorial: special issue on corruption at the grassroots-level. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 235(2), 100–114.

  22. Auriol, E. and Lassebie, J. (2015). Capture for the rich, extortion for the poor. Mimeo TSE.

  23. Moene, K. and Søreide, T. (2015). Good governance facades. In S. Rose-Ackerman and P. Lagunes (Eds.) Greed, Corruption, and the Modern State: Essays in Political Economy. (pp. 46–70). Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

  24. World Bank (2013). World development indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Karl Moene.

Appendix

Appendix

This appendix informs about the sources of data presented in Table 1. The countries listed are categorized according to their income levels using income (GNI) per capita- as described by the World Bank: http://data.worldbank.org/about/country-and-lending-groups#OECD_members and World Bank (2013) [24].

Sources for the data included:

Ombudsman function: Whether such an institution exists in the country. Source: International Ombudsman Institute (http://www.theioi.org/ioi-members)

  • Audit institution: Whether in existence. Source: International Organization of Supreme Audit Institutions (http://www.intosai.org/about-us/organisation/membership-list.html)

  • Access to information law: X = yes, law in line with int. best practice; v* = by constitution, citizens have right to information, yet a legal framework for securing access to information is missing. Score included in parenthesis: Global right to Information Rating (RTI): whether legal framework recognizes citizens’ fundamental right of access to information. Country rank based on scope of these laws. RTI Rating is limited to measuring the legal framework, and does not measure quality of implementation. Score based on formal rules securing/supposed to secure Right of Access, Scope, Requesting Procedures, Exceptions and Refusals, Appeals, Sanctions and Protections, and Promotional Measures. http://www.rti-rating.org/

  • Rule of law (overall performance): Source: World Justice Project. Rule of Law Index (http://worldjusticeproject.org/rule-of-law-index)

  • Perceived extent of corruption: Survey-respondents’ perceived extent of corruption. Source: Transparency International Corruption Perception Index (CPI). http://www.transparency.org/cpi2015

Corruption in the judiciary: Source: World Justice Project. Sub-factor behind the Rule of Law Index.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Moene, K., Søreide, T. Corruption control. Crime Law Soc Change 66, 147–163 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-016-9618-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-016-9618-6

Keywords

Navigation