Skip to main content
Log in

Decentralization, agency costs, and the new economic constitution of China

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article examines the evolution of the rules that govern central-local government relations in the Chinese political economy. Although the federalism that accompanied China’s market reforms has substantially facilitated economic growth, it has also created powerful incentives for local authorities to abuse their powers, significantly increasing the agency costs to the central government of maintaining political stability and creating a national market. This article analyzes the institutional design of the nascent Anti-Monopoly Law (AML), known to officials and academics as China’s new “Economic Constitution”. It demonstrates that the major purpose of the AML is to break up the so-called “administrative monopolies”, or bureaucratic fiefdoms over local economies. In contrast to existing academic treatment, it will study the AML in the framework of competition for influence over economic policy between rent-seeking central and local actors. It argues that the AML, despite its stated purposes, is indeed designed to reduce the policy-making powers of the regions to the comparative advantage of the central government. The AML can thus be modeled as a new constitutional contract that the center wishes to enter into with the localities in order to repeal the existing rules of decentralization. It will be further shown that the AML, reflecting the allocation of power in the Chinese state, prioritizes the political imperatives of recentralization over the facilitation of competitive markets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Bahl, R. (1995). Comparative federalism: Trends and issues in the United States, China, and Russia. In J. Roy (Ed.), Macroeconomic management and fiscal decentralization (pp. 73–102). Washington: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bai, L. (2011). Zuigaofa zhishicanquanting fuzeren jiu fanlongduan minshisusong shifajieshi jingqiu yijiangao jieshou benbao zhuanfang jizhongrenzhizhi yonghao jingjixianfa. [Interview with the Person-in-Charge of the Supreme People’s Court Intellectual Property Rights Tribunal on the invitation of submission of opinion for the judicial interpretation of anti-monopoly civil litigation: Combine the intelligence of many to make full use of the economic constitution]. People’s Daily (26 May 2011). http://cpc.people.com.cn/GB/64093/64387/14481370.html. Accessed 1 June 2011.

  • Bardhan, P. (2005). Scarcity, conflicts, and cooperation: Essays in the political and institutional economics of development. Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J., & Weingast, B. (1998). Analytic narratives. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergsten, C., Freeman, C., Lardy, N., & Mitchell, D. (2008). China’s rise: Challenges and opportunities. Washington: Center for Strategic and International Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents? The political economy of good government. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1979). The economic constitution and the new deal: Lessons for late learners. In G. Walton (Ed.), Regulatory change in an atmosphere of crisis: Current implications of the Roosevelt years (pp. 13–26). New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cao, C. (2007). Guanche luoshi fanlongduanfa chujin gongping gongzheng jingzheng. [Implement and give effect to the anti-monopoly law, advance fair and just competition]. Department of Price, National Development and Reform Commission. http://www.competitionlaw.cn/show.aspx?id=4532&cid=17. Accessed 1 June 2011.

  • Chen, H. (2008). Fanlongduanfazhongguotese de jingjixianfa [Anti-monopoly law: An economic constitution with Chinese characteristics], lilun tantao [Explorations into Theory], 6, 170–172.

  • Cho, Y. (2008). Local people’s congresses in China: Development and transition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R., Kyriacou, A., & Bacaria, J. (2003). A theory of menu federalism: Decentralization by political agreement. Constitutional Political Economy, 14, 167–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R., & Swedenborg, B. (2006). Introduction: Rational choice politics and political institutions. In R. D. Congleton & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy: Analysis and evidence (pp. 1–36). Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deng, X. (1984). Collected works of Deng Xiaoping. Beijing: Foreign Language Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowdle, M. (2002). Of parliaments, pragmatism, and the dynamics of constitutional development: The curious case of China. New York University Journal of International Law and Politics, 35, 1–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emch, A. (2008). Abuse of dominance in China: A paradigmatic shift? European Competition Law Review, 29, 615–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer, S. (2010). The impact of China’s antitrust law and other competition policies on U.S. companies. Loyola Consumer Law Review, 23, 34–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filippov, M., Ordeshook, P., & Shvetsova, O. (2004). Designing federalism: A theory of self-sustainable federal institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, T. (2002). Comparative administrative procedure: Evidence from Northeast Asia. Constitutional Political Economy, 13, 247–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, T., & Moustafa, T. (2008). Introduction: The function of courts in authoritarian politics. In T. Ginsburg & T. Moustafa (Eds.), Rule by law: The politics of courts in authoritarian regimes (pp. 1–22). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, T., & Posner, E. (2010). Subconstitutionalism. Stanford Law Review, 62, 1583–1628.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, Y., & Hu, A. (2004). The administrative monopoly in China’s economic transition. Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 37, 265–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanzlik, M. (2008). The implications of China’s anti-monopoly law for investors: Problematic protection of intellectual property. Entrepreneurial Business Law Journal, 3, 75–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • He, Q. (2009). Thirty years of reform and opening and the construction of rule of law in China. In X. Zhang & W. Gu (Eds.), The development and interaction of law in Mainland China, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Macao (pp. 3–23). Hong Kong: China Review Academic Publishers Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helm, D., & Smith, S. (1987). The assessment: Decentralization and the economics of local government’. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 3(2), i–xix.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Y. (2008). Capitalism with Chinese characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the state. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Huo, Z. (2008). A tiger without teeth: The antitrust law of the People’s Republic of China. Asian-Pacific Law and Policy Journal, 10, 32–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jagtenberg, R. (2000). Comments on Liu Junhai’s legal reforms in China. In J. Denthier (Ed.), Governance, decentralization and reform in China, India and Russia (p. 412). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, P. (2008). Licensing in China: The new Anti-Monopoly Law, the abuse of IP rights and trade tensions. Les Nouvelles: Journal of the Licensing Executives Society International, XLIII(2), 106–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, S. (2009). The new authoritarianism in the Middle East and North Africa. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landry, P., Tong, Y., & Shen, M. (2009). Introduction: Markets, courts and Leninism. The China Review, 9, 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Law, D. (2009). A theory of judicial review and judicial power. Georgetown Law Journal, 97, 723–801.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, C. (2004). Political localism versus institutional restraints: Elite recruitment in the Jiang era. In B. Naughton & D. Yang (Eds.), Holding China together: Diversity and national integration in the post-Deng era (pp. 29–69). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G. (2009). Can the PRC’s new anti-monopoly law stop monopolistic activities: Let the PRC’s telecommunications industry tell you the answer. Telecommunications Policy, 33, 360–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lieberthal, K. (2004). Governing China: From revolution through reform (2nd ed.). New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, C. (2003). A quiet revolution: An overview of China’s judicial reform. Asian-Pacific Law and Policy Review, 4, 255–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, S. (2009). Research on the efficiency of China’s anti-monopoly law. Asian Social Science, 5, 97–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, J., Tao, R., & Liu, M. (2006). Decentralization and local governance in China’s economic transition. In P. Bardhan & D. Mookherjee (Eds.), Decentralization and local governance in developing countries: A comparative perspective (pp. 305–327). Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdams, R. (2000). A focal point theory of expressive law. Virginia Law Review, 86, 1649–1729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M., Noll, R., & Weingast, B. (1994). Legislative intent: The use of positive political theory in statutory interpretation. Law and Contemporary Problems, 5(1), 3–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, K., & Meng, Y. (2009). Against antitrust functionalism: Reconsidering China’s antimonopoly law. Virginia Journal of International Law, 49, 379–429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naughton, B., & Yang, D. (2004). Holding China together: Introduction. In B. Naughton & D. Yang (Eds.), Holding China together: Diversity and national integration in the post-Deng era (pp. 1–28). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). A transaction cost theory of politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2, 355–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peerenboom, R. (2009). More law, less courts: Legalized governance, judicialization, and dejudicialization in China. In T. Ginsburg & A. Chen (Eds.), Administrative law and governance in Asia (pp. 175–201). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pieke, F. (2009). The good communist: Elite training and state building in today’s China. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, E. (2000). Agency models in law and economics. John M. Olin law and economics working paper No. 92. Chicago: University of Chicago Law School.

  • Saich, T. (2011). Governance and politics of China (3rd ed.). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, J. (2010). Administrative monopoly and China’s new anti-monopoly law: Lessons from Europe’s state aid doctrine. Washington University Law Review, 87, 869–895.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott Tanner, M., & Green, E. (2008). Principals and secret agents: Central versus local control over policing and obstacles to ‘rule of law’. In D. C. Clarke (Ed.), China’s legal system: New developments, new challenges (pp. 66–120). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shih, V. (2008). Factions and finance in China: Elite conflict and inflation. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shue, V. (2010). Legitimacy crisis in China? In P. Gries & S. Rosen (Eds.), Chinese politics: State, society, and the market (pp. 41–68). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephenson, M. (2010). Statutory interpretation by agencies. In D. Farber & A. O’Connell (Eds.), Research handbook on public choice and public law (pp. 285–332). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sun, J. (2010). On the defects of administrative monopoly in China’s “anti-monopoly law” and its improvement. Canadian Social Science, 6, 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian, G. (2010). The impacts of the Chinese anti-monopoly law on IP commercialization in China & general strategies for technology-driven companies and future regulators. Duke Law and Technology Review, 4, 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (2011). Positive constitutional economics II—a survey of recent developments. Public Choice, 146, 205–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X. (2008). Highlights of China’s new anti-monopoly law. Antitrust Law Journal, 75, 133–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11, 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wibbels, E. (2005). Decentralized governance, constitution formation, and redistribution. Constitutional Political Economy, 16, 161–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, M. (2005). Competition policy and law in China, Hong Kong and Taiwan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, M. (2009). Foreign investment in China: Will the Anti-Monopoly Law be a barrier or a facilitator? Texas International Law Journal, 45, 127–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, D. (2004). Economic transformation and state building in China. In B. Naughton & D. Yang (Eds.), Holding China together: Diversity and national integration in the post-Deng era (pp. 120–148). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Yueh, L. (2010). The economy of China. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X. (2009). Fiscal decentralization and political centralization in China: Implications for growth and inequality. In S. Fan, R. Kanbur, & X. Zhang (Eds.), Regional inequality in China: Trends, explanations and policy responses (pp. 226–243). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, S. (2006). Political liberalization without democratization. In S. Zhao (Ed.), Debating political reform in China: Rule of law vs democratization (pp. 230–246). New York: ME Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zou, S., Sun, Y., & Zhang, Z. (2006). Jingjixianfa buru zhengshi lifachengxutoushi fanlongduanfa caoan shouci tiqing shenyi. [The economic constitution enters the official legislative process – an analysis of the first review of the anti-monopoly bill]. Xinhua News Agency. http://big5.xinhuanet.com/gate/big5/news.xinhuanet.com/politics/2006-06/25/content_4746891.htm. Accessed 1 June 2011.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric C. Ip.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ip, E.C., Law, M.K.H. Decentralization, agency costs, and the new economic constitution of China. Const Polit Econ 22, 355–372 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-011-9110-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-011-9110-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation