Skip to main content
Log in

The stability and growth pact, fiscal policy institutions and stabilization in Europe

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Ever since its inception, the EMU has been subject to controversy. The fiscal policy rules embedded in the Maastricht Treaty, and clarified in the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), are probably the most contentious. The SGP has constantly been accused of being too rigid and of forcing procyclicality in fiscal policy. However, in an influential paper Galí and Perotti (2003) concluded that discretionary fiscal policy has actually become more countercyclical in EMU countries since the Maastricht Treaty. This paper argues that this conclusion stands up to several robustness tests using ex-post data, including the use of institutional variables, but not to the use of real-time data. Using ex-post data, there is some evidence pointing to a more countercyclical use of discretionary fiscal policy (or at least to less use of procyclical discretionary fiscal policy). However, the use of real-time data for the period 1999–2006 reveals that discretionary fiscal policy has been designed to be procyclical. Hence, the actual acyclical behaviour of discretionary fiscal policy in the period after 1999 seems to be simply the result of errors in forecasting the output gap, and not the result of a change in the intentions of policy-makers. As a result, there is no evidence to support the view that Maastricht rules have forced euro-area policy-makers to change their behaviour and design countercyclical discretionary fiscal policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In order to reach a balanced panel, some missing AMECO values were carefully linked with observations from the OECD Economic Outlook database. Some cyclically adjusted fiscal data are only available for some countries several years after 1980 in the AMECO database, e.g. Greece (1988), Ireland (1995), Spain (1995) and Sweden (1993). Data on the unadjusted balances, and the (calculated) implied sensitivity to the cycle were taken from the OECD database. Using it together with the output gap from AMECO resulted in linked series. The OECD database is also the source of the US output gap estimate.

  2. Potential output is used as a deflator of all variables, instead of actual output, to reduce endogeneity problems and to minimize the influence of current GDP on the evolution of the fiscal ratios. See Bayoumi and Masson (1995) for a similar use. The output gap is defined as the difference between current and potential output as a fraction of potential output.

  3. The use of primary balance instead of the overall budget balance is motivated by the fact that interest payments are not under the control of the fiscal authorities, but simply reflect the evolution of the interest rate and the past accumulation of budget deficits. See also Brandner, Diebalek et al. (2006) for an application of an unobserved components model to estimate a core balance for Austria.

  4. See Baltagi (2001).

  5. There is however a technical caveat regarding the use of fixed effects with a lagged endogenous variable resulting in inconsistent estimators. The alternative would be to use the estimator proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991). However, the small-sample properties of such an estimator are not well understood. Moreover, as much of the focus is on the difference between the estimates of the gap coefficient between two periods, I have, as Galí and Perotti (2003: note 6) did, opted to present the results with a standard instrumental variables fixed effects estimator. Notwithstanding, Table 6 in the appendix presents some results using the Arellano and Bond estimation method.

  6. This paper makes use of the more recent version of this database (received from the authors in January 2006 and last updated in February 2007), i.e. the version used in Mierau et al. (2007) in Public Choice.

  7. For a discussion on the usefulness and desirability of discretionary fiscal policy, see the excellent surveys by Andersen (2001) and Auerbach (2002).

  8. Galí and Perotti (2003) used OECD data; here the main source of data is the AMECO database, from the European Commission.

  9. Stage II of EMU started only in 1994, and it was clear to participants that phase III would only start on the date limit imposed by article 121 of the Treaty (1999).

  10. The political-institutional variables of Mierau et al. (2006) are only available until 2003.

  11. The difference between the estimates for the gap before and after Maastricht is statistically significant in all regressions.

  12. The inclusion of an interaction term renders the output gap before Maastricht non-statistically significant. At the 10% level, discretionary fiscal policy is found to be countercyclical after Maastricht.

  13. When controlling for institutional variables, discretionary fiscal policy after the introduction of the euro is found to be acyclical in high-deficit countries, since the positive coefficient on the gap is not statistically significant.

  14. Moreover, there is a change in sign in the non-statistically significant coefficient on the output gap. While it is positive in the period before Maastricht, it is negative in the period after the introduction of the euro.

  15. The regression for Portugal presents a low fit to the data.

  16. For instance, the measure of the output gap for 2001 used in the regression was the forecast of the output gap made by the Commission services in the Spring (or Autumn) of 2000.

  17. There are some possible explanations as to why the results of this section differ from the conclusions of Forni and Momigliano (2004): a) the time period is different (1999–2006 versus 1993–2003 in their case); b) this section does not distinguish a reaction to positive output gaps from a reaction to negative ones as the authors did; c) the authors include a dummy for Maastricht restrictions, which is not included in this estimate. To gain more insight into such possibilities, a regression was done using Forni and Momigliano (2004) real-time output gap estimate (in the “expected conditions” case) along with the rest of this paper dataset. For the period 1993–2003, used by the authors, a negative coefficient is found for the gap (signalling a countercyclical policy), yet this coefficient is not statistically significant. Furthermore, when the estimation period is restricted to the euro period (1999–2003), i.e. overlapping most of the time period of the regressions presented in this section, the estimated gap coefficient is very small and positive, and in fact not statistically significant. Hence, it appears that Forni and Momigliano’s (2004) results are possibly dependent on the sample of countries used, and on the specific time frame used. As seen earlier, fiscal policy did not behave homogenously in Europe in the post-Maastricht period. As a result, some structural breaks might have occurred in the period used by the authors (1993–2003).

  18. For example, for France the 1999 forecast for the output gap in 2000, in the “Broad Economic Policy Guidelines”, was predicted to be -2.3%. The ex-post data, as available in the spring of 2007 forecast, pointed to a positive output gap of 2.4%, i.e. to a deviation of 4.7% of the potential GDP. For Germany, the numbers are similar (the initial forecast was -0.7% and the ex-post value is 1.3%). For Italy, the figures for 2000 are 3.1% (ex-ante) vs. 1.8% (ex-post), and for Spain -3.1% (ex-ante) vs. 2.2% (ex-post).

  19. According to Jonung and Larch (2006), there is an even greater degree of optimism in the medium-term growth outlook in national official government’s growth projections for France, Germany, Italy and the United Kingdom. Such optimism has resulted in cyclical conditions that systematically turn out to be better than assumed at the time of presenting the budget deficit.

References

  • Andersen T (2001) Stabilization policy, University of Aarhus, unpublished manuscript, June

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:227–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A (2002) Is there a role for discretionary fiscal policy?, NBER Working Paper No. 9306

  • Baltagi B (2001) Econometric analysis of panel data. 2nd edition, Wiley & Sons Chichester

  • Bayoumi T, Masson P (1995) Fiscal flows in the United States and Canada: lessons for monetary union in Europe. Eur Econ Rev 39:253–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandner P, Diebalek L and Koehler-Toeglhofer (2006) Budget balances decomposed: tracking fiscal policy in Austria. Presented at the Workshop on Fiscal Indicators in the EU Budgetary Surveillance, Brussels, 22 September

  • Brender A, Drazen A (2005) Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. J Mon Econ 52:1271–1295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forni L, Momigliano S (2004) Cyclical sensitivity of fiscal policies based on real-time data. App Econ Q 50:299–326

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Perotti R (2003) Fiscal policy and monetary integration in Europe. Econ Policy 37:533–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jonung L, Larch M (2006) Improving fiscal policy in the EU: the case for independent forecasts. Econ Policy 21:491–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane P (2003) The cyclical behaviour of fiscal policy: Evidence from the OECD. J Pub Econ 87:2661–2675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mierau Jo, Jong-a-Pin R and De Haan J (2006) Do political variables affect fiscal policy adjustment decisions? New empirical evidence, Paper submitted for EPCS2006

  • Mierau J, Jong-a-Pin R and De Haan J (2007) Do political variables affect fiscal policy adjustment decisions? New empirical evidence. Pub Choice 133(3–4):297–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides A, Van Norden S (2002) The unreliability of output-gap estimates in real time. Rev Econ Stat 84:569–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pina Á (2004) Fiscal policy in Portugal: discipline, cyclicality and the scope for expenditure rules, proceedings of the 2nd Conference on Portuguese Economic Development in the European Context, held by the Bank of Portugal in Lisbon, 11–12 March 2004, forthcoming

  • Roubini N, Sachs J (1989) Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in the industrial democracies. Eur Econ Rev 33:903–933

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Volkerink B, De Haan J (2001) Fragmented government effects on fiscal policy: new evidence. Pub Choice 109:221–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woo J (2003) Economic, political, and institutional determinants of public deficits. J Pub Econ 87:387–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wyplosz C (2002) Fiscal Discipline in EMU: rules or institutions? Paper prepared for the April 16, 2002 meeting of the Group of Economic Analysis of the European Commission. http://heiwww.unige.ch/~wyplosz/

Download references

Acknowledgement

The text has benefited from comments received from an anonymous referee and from António Afonso, Martin Larch, Peter Brandner, José Tavares, Alfred Sitz and other participants at the 63rd International Atlantic Economic Conference held in Madrid on 14–18 March 2007, and at the Workshop on the Sustainability of the Public Debt held at Klagenfurt University on 20 May 2007. All remaining errors or omissions are solely my responsibility. A word of recognition is also due to Jochen Mierau, Richard Jong-A-Pin and Jakob de Haan for making their data set on political variables available, and to Reinhard Neck for superbly organizing the two mentioned sessions. The author also acknowledges financial support provided by the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology (FCT) under research grant POCI/EGE/60069/2004 (partially funded by FEDER, programme POCI 2010).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlos Fonseca Marinheiro.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 6 Determinants of cyclically adjusted primary deficit (%Potential GDP)—1980–2003—Arelllano & Bond estimation method—the euro area
Table 7 Determinants of cyclically adjusted primary deficit (%Potential GDP) in the euro area — country level results: 1980–2006

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Marinheiro, C.F. The stability and growth pact, fiscal policy institutions and stabilization in Europe. Int Econ Econ Policy 5, 189–207 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-008-0110-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-008-0110-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation