Skip to main content
Log in

Finance, governments, and trade

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study how financial transactions may respond to exogenous variation in trade opportunities not only directly, but also through policy channels. In more open economies, governments may find it more difficult to fund and enforce public policies that substitute private financial transactions, and more appealing to deregulate financial markets. We propose a simple theoretical model of such policy-mediated relationships between trade and financial development. Empirically, we document in a country panel dataset that, before the 2007–2008 crisis, financial market volumes were robustly and negatively related to the share of government consumption in GDP in regressions that also include indicators of financial regulation and trade openness, and we seek support for a causal interpretation of this result in instrumental variable specifications.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This variable measures government activity in terms of general government consumption of goods and services, which mostly corresponds to the salaries of public employees, such as teachers and administrators of tax and subsidy schemes which obviously reduce private financial activity. The transfers entailed by such schemes are potentially more relevant but very difficult to measure consistently across countries. World Development Indicators, The World Bank (http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators) include a “Public Transfers” variable that is sparse and of dubious quality, and indeed proves uninformative in Epifani and Gancia’s (2009) regressions aimed at testing the hypothesis that openness influences the size of government through its effect on tax policy’s ability to change the terms of trade. Exploring the relevance of the “Public Social Expenditure” indicator from the OECD Social Expenditure Database (www.oecd.org/els/social/expenditure) in the small sample of countries for which it is available, we have found that demographic trends explain much of its variation and confound the empirical picture.

  2. This indicator, which aggregates information on a wide variety of financial market institutions, is also significantly correlated with the stock market capitalization to GDP ratios considered in Sect. 6, when we assess the results’ robustness to alternative measures of de facto financial market activity.

  3. It would be possible to extend the model to allow for individual-level investment. Then, a smaller \( \mu \) could improve the quality of investment-savings matching, to imply higher output, and/or increase the pre-tax income dispersion indexed by \( \Updelta \), as leverage amplifies the ex post implications of idiosyncratic shocks.

  4. Totally differentiating the first-order conditions,

    $$ \frac{\partial \mu }{{\partial z_{1} }} = - \frac{{\partial^{2} U}}{{\partial \omega^{2} }}\frac{1}{\left| H \right|}\frac{{\partial {{\upalpha}}}}{{\partial z_{1} }}, \frac{\partial \omega }{{\partial z_{2} }} = - \frac{{\partial^{2} U}}{{\partial \mu^{2} }}\frac{1}{\left| H \right|}\frac{\partial U}{\partial Y}\frac{{\partial^{2} Y}}{{\partial \omega \partial z_{2} }} $$

    where \( \left| H \right| \) denotes the Hessian determinant, which is positive at a maximum. For example, if more openness increases the dispersion of incomes, then the same factors that foster openness may also foster financial development (as in Rajan and Zingales 2003) as less expensive private financial contracts substitute the income-smoothing public policies that international openness makes more costly to implement.

  5. Many contributions do choose to interpret the relationship between government activities and economic outcomes in terms of differently oriented policy-making frameworks. La Porta et al. (2002), for example, view the fact that public ownership of banks is negatively related to financial and economic development as evidence that intrusive economic policies aim at inefficient rent appropriation. The constrained-maximization mechanism we outline is an arguably plausible element of the process that generates policy data. We do not try to disentangle its implications from those of variation of policy objectives, which is observationally equivalent in general and may in practice be related to the instrumental variables we use.

  6. Such pre-determined indicators are preferable for our purposes to time-varying measures that might be causally influenced by shocks that also drive financial development. As regards ease of trade, tariff indexes convey information on both policy choices and exogenous shocks. It would be similarly hard to disentangle structural relationships in the co-variation between Financial Development and time-varying features of legal systems (such as those documented in Armour et al. 2009), which is empirically strong but arguably less causal, and more difficult to interpret, than the influence exerted by the remote historical roots captured by the Legal Origin indicator.

  7. The results are virtually identical if the trend is replaced by indicators of the intensity of world trade, or shipping costs, or financial globalization. All these phenomena followed tightly correlated trends over the sample period, and all are arguably exogenous to country-specific policies since most countries are either too small or too closed to account for more than a small portion of global imports and exports.

  8. It is not possible to report or interpret the many coefficients of these first-stage regressions. Their partial R2 s for the residual variation unexplained by country fixed effects is 0.32 for Government, 0.53 for Trade, and 0.88 for Financial Structure. All Shea’s partial R2 (Shea 1997) are in the 0.2–0.3 range. When instruments are constructed as in Table 2, using a trend instead of period effects, Shea’s partial R2 s lower than 0.10 give weak statistical evidence of instrument relevance; the second-stage coefficients are very similar, but less reliably estimated. .

  9. The distribution of these statistics depends on details of the data generating process, and significance levels depend on the specific relative-bias null hypothesis one wishes to test; to foster complete confidence in the instruments’ strength, the test statistic should exceed the critical values (in the order of 10) for the Cragg–Donald statistic it generalizes (see Baum et al. 2007).

  10. Some of these variables’ variation may be exogenous to the policies and outcomes of interest, and some may be determined by the same historical and natural characteristics that we bring to bear on the data, by policy choices, and by unobserved independent sources of Financial Development variation. Our main estimation results are also robust to inclusion of GDP and population as endogenous variables (results not reported).

  11. When each of the seven dimensions of financial sector policy aggregated by the IMF index is included separately as a Financial Reforms indicator, only “Prudential regulations and supervision of the banking sector” remains significantly positive; this is the only dimension coded so that more government intervention is expected to support financial development, and excluding it from the Financial Reform Index leaves our results unchanged.

References

  • Abiad, A., Detragiache, E., & Tressel, T. (2010). A new database of financial reforms. IMF Staff Papers, 57(2), 281–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abiad, A., & Mody, A. (2005). Financial reform: What shakes it? What shapes it? American Economic Review, 95(1), 66–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agell, J. (2002). On the determinants of labor market institutions: Rent seeking versus social insurance. German Economic Review, 3(2), 107–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Wacziarg, R. (1998). Openness, country size and the government. Journal of Public Economics, 69(3), 305–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armour, J., Deakin, S., Lele, P., & Siems, M. (2009). How do legal rules evolve? Evidence from a cross-national comparison of shareholder, creditor and worker protection. American Journal of Comparative Law, 57, 579–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C.F., Schaffer, M.E., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/GMM estimation and testing. (Boston College Working Papers in Economics, no. 667).

  • Beck, T. (2002). Financial development and international trade: Is there a link? Journal of International Economics, 57(1), 107–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., & Demirgüç-Kunt, A. (2009). Financial institutions and markets across countries and over time: Data and analysis. (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 4943).

  • Bertola, G., & Koeniger, W. (2007). Consumption smoothing and income redistribution. European Economic Review, 51(8), 1941–1958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertola, G., & Lo Prete, A. (2009). Openness, financial markets, and policies: Cross-country and dynamic patterns. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 95(96), 167–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2010). Optimal taxation and social insurance with endogenous private insurance. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(2), 85–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Do, Q., & Levchenko, A. A. (2007). Comparative advantage, demand for external finance, and financial development. Journal of Financial Economics, 86(3), 796–834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epifani, P., & Gancia, G. (2009). Openness, government and the terms of trade. Review of Economic Studies, 76(2), 629–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A., & Romer, D. (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, 89(3), 379–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2009). Penn World Table Version 6.3, compiled by the Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, August 2009.

  • Huang, Y., & Temple, J.R.W. (2005). Does external trade promote financial development? (CEPR Discussion Papers, no. 5150).

  • Kleibergen, F., & Paap, R. (2006). Generalized reduced rank tests using singular value decomposition. Journal of Econometrics, 127(1), 97–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Government ownership of banks. Journal of Finance, 57(1), 265–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 15(1), 222–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: The politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69, 5–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far? Washington, DC: Peterson Institute.

  • Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 997–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaffer, M.E. (2010). xtivreg2: Stata module to perform extended IV/2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML and k-class regression for panel data models. http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s456501.html.

  • Shea, J. (1997). Instrument relevance in multivariate linear models: A simple measure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(2), 348–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svaleryd, H., & Vlachos, J. (2002). Markets for risk and openness to trade: How are they related? Journal of International Economics, 57, 369–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tressel, T., & Detragiache E. (2008). Do financial sector reforms lead to financial development? Evidence from a new dataset. (IMF Working Papers no. 08/265).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giuseppe Bertola.

Additional information

For helpful comments we thank an anonymous referee and presentation audiences at GEP-University of Nottingham, MWP Lustrum Conference, 26th Annual Congress of the EEA, University of Turin, and EDHEC.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Mathematical derivations

See Tables 5 and 6.

Table 5 Countries in the sample
Table 6 Descriptive statistics

By equation (1), the private financial market is active if disposable incomes are sufficiently different across the model’s two periods or contingencies: the condition

$$ \left( {y_{H} - \tau - \frac{1}{2}\lambda \tau^{2} } \right)\left( {1 - \mu } \right) > \left( {y_{L} + \tau - \frac{1}{2}\lambda \tau^{2} } \right)\left( {1 + \mu } \right) $$

with \( \tau = \mu /\lambda \) implies that

$$ \left( {y_{L} + y_{H} } \right)\mu - \left( {y_{H} - y_{L} } \right) < \frac{{\mu^{3} - 2\mu }}{\lambda } $$

and that the partial derivative of the welfare expression (3) with respect to the financial market spread parameter,

$$ \frac{\partial }{\partial \mu }{ \log }\left( {\left( {Y + \frac{{\mu^{2} }}{\lambda } - \mu \Updelta } \right)^{2} \frac{1}{{4\left( {1 - \mu^{2} } \right)}}} \right) = \left( {\left( {Y + \frac{{\mu^{2} }}{\lambda } - \mu \Updelta } \right)^{2} \frac{1}{{\left( {1 - \mu^{2} } \right)}}} \right)^{ - 1} \left( {Y\mu - \Updelta + \frac{{2\mu - \mu^{3} }}{\lambda }} \right), $$

is negative.

Financial market activity allows net incomes to differ from the consumption levels

$$ c_{H} = \frac{{y_{H} + y_{L} - \lambda \tau^{2} - \left( {y_{H} - y_{L} - 2\tau } \right)\mu }}{{2\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}, c_{L} = \frac{{y_{H} + y_{L} - \lambda \tau^{2} - \left( {y_{H} - y_{L} - 2\tau } \right)\mu }}{{2\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}} . $$

Using the \( {{\uptau}} = {{\upmu}}/{{\uplambda}} \) optimality condition to substitute \( {{\uplambda}} \), the difference between disposable incomes and consumption in high-income realizations is

$$ y_{H} - \tau - \frac{1}{2}\lambda \tau^{2} - c_{H} = \frac{1}{{2(1 - {{\upmu}})}}\left( {\Updelta - \mu Y - \left( {2 - \mu^{2} } \right){{\uptau}}} \right). $$

Dividing this by \( {\text{Y}} \) yields an indicator of financial market activity,

$$ D\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y},\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y},\mu } \right) = \frac{1}{{2\left( {1 - {{\upmu}}} \right)}}\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y} - \mu - \left( {2 - \mu^{2} } \right)\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y}} \right). $$

Using \( 0 < \mu < 1 \) and \( \frac{\Updelta }{Y} = \frac{{y_{H} - y_{L} }}{{y_{H} + y_{L} }} < 1 \), its derivatives can be signed unambiguously:

$$ \frac{{\partial D\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y},\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y},\mu } \right)}}{{\partial \frac{\Updelta }{Y}}} = \frac{1}{{2(1 - {{\upmu}})}} > 0, $$
$$ \frac{{\partial D\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y},\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y},\mu } \right)}}{{\partial \frac{\tau }{Y}}} = - \frac{{2 - \mu^{2} }}{2(1 - \mu )} < 0, $$
$$ \frac{{\partial D\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y},\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y},\mu } \right)}}{\partial \mu } = \frac{1}{{2(1 - {{\upmu}})^{2} }}\left( {\frac{\Updelta }{Y} - 1 - \left( {1 + (1 - {{\upmu}})^{2} } \right)\frac{{{\uptau}}}{Y}} \right) < 0. $$

Appendix 2. Data definitions and sources

2.1 Financial development

“Private Credit by Deposit Money Banks and Other Financial Institutions to GDP” from the World Bank “Financial Development and Structure Database” (Beck and Demirgüç-Kunt 2009).

2.2 Financial structure

This is the IMF “Financial Reform Index”, drawn from the “Financial Reform Database” documented in Abiad et al. (2010). It considers seven dimensions of financial sector policy (credit controls and reserve requirements, interest rate controls, entry barriers, state ownership, prudential regulation of securities markets, banking regulations, and restrictions on the capital account). Each dimension is scored on a graded scale from zero to three, with zero corresponding to the highest degree of repression and three indicating full liberalization for all dimensions except prudential regulation, which is scored higher when more intense. Scores for each category are summed to obtain a country-and-period specific index that takes values between 0 and 21.

2.3 Trade

This is “Openness in Current Prices”, drawn from the Penn World Table, Version 6.3, compiled by Heston et al. (2009). It is defined as the ratio of exports plus imports to GDP.

2.4 Government

The variable “Government consumption share of PPP converted GDP per capita at current prices,” drawn from the Penn World Table, Version 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009).

2.5 Natural openness

As measured by Frankel and Romer (1999) on the basis of bilateral gravity estimates including only geographic characteristics, aggregated to country-specific averages.

2.6 Legal origin

Dummy variables equal to unity for countries in each of the La Porta et al. (1999) legal-origin groups: English Common Law; French Commercial Code; German Commercial Code; Scandinavian Commercial Code; Social/Communist Laws.

2.7 GDP

The product of the variables “Real GDP per capita” and “Population” drawn from the Penn World Table, Version 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). The variable is in millions of US$.

2.8 Population

Drawn from the Penn World Table, Version 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). The variable is expressed in millions of inhabitants.

2.9 Stock market capitalization

The “Stock market capitalization to GDP” from the World Bank “Financial Development and Structure Database” (Beck and Demirgüç-Kunt 2009). Data are not available for eight countries belonging to the French Legal Origin groups and to the Developing countries sample.

Observations are averaged for each country over seven non-overlapping sub-periods of 4 years each. Annual data are interpolated when occasionally missing, and filled backwards and forward using, respectively, the first and last value available in the time series. Variables expressed as ratios to GDP are in percentage points. We report results for the sample of 65 countries listed in Table 5. We follow the common practice of excluding countries with Trade larger than 200 percentage points (Singapore, Malaysia, Hong Kong). We also drop Jordan, which has implausibly large Government observations; Nigeria, where Government jumps from 6 to 25 % in 2000s; and Switzerland and Denmark, where the Financial Development indicators have abnormal level and dynamics. If all available countries are included, the message of the data is broadly similar in most substantive respects.

About this article

Cite this article

Bertola, G., Lo Prete, A. Finance, governments, and trade. Rev World Econ 149, 273–294 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0153-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0153-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation