Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Home-Market and Factor-Endowment Effects in a Gravity Approach

  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper shows how the home-market effect can be estimated in the generalized gravity equation of Bergstrand, taking into account traditional comparative advantage effects arising from differences in factor endowment. The empirical results suggest the presence of significant home-market effects for differentiated goods in many manufacturing industries which may be capital intensive or labour intensive. At the same time, our results suggest that home-market effects can only be detected for data disaggregated at the industry level and not for aggregated data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Anderson, J. E. (1979). A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation. American Economic Review 69 (1): 106–116.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Baier, S. L., and J. H. Bergstrand (2001). The Growth of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs, and Income Similarity. Journal of International Economics 53 (1): 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Bergstrand, J. H. (1985). The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (3): 474–481.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Bergstrand, J. H. (1989). The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor Proportions Theory in International Trade. Review of Economics and Statistics 71 (1): 143–153.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Bergstrand, J. H. (1990). The Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson Model, the Linder Hypothesis and the Determinants of Bilateral Intra-Industry Trade. Economic Journal 100 (403): 1216–1229.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Davis, D. R. (1998). The Home Market, Trade, and Industrial Structure. American Economic Review 88 (5): 1264–1276.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Davis, D. R., and D. E. Weinstein (1998). Market Access, Economic Geography and Comparative Advantage: An Empirical Test. NBER Working Paper 6787. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.

  8. Davis, D. R., and D. E. Weinstein (1999). Economic Geography and Regional Production Structure: An Empirical Investigation. European Economic Review 43 (2): 379–409.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Davis, D. R., and D. E. Weinstein (2003). Market Access, Economic Geography and Comparative Advantage: An Empirical Test. Journal of International Economics 59 (1): 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Deardorff, A. (1982). The General Validity of the Heckscher–Ohlin Theorem. American Economic Review 72 (4): 683–694.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Deardorff, A. (1998). Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World? In J. A. Frankel (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  12. Evenett, S. J., and W. Keller (2001). On Theories Explaining the Success of the Gravity Equation. Journal of Political Economy 110 (2): 281–316.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Feenstra, R. C., J. A. Markusen, and A. K. Rose (1998). Understanding the Home Market Effect and the Gravity Equation: The Role of Differentiating Goods. NBER Working Paper 6804. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.

  14. Feenstra, R. C., J. A. Markusen, and A. K. Rose (2001). Using the Gravity Equation to Differentiate among Alternative Theories of Trade. Canadian Journal of Economics 34 (2): 430–442.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Festoc, F. (1995). The Trade Potential in Sensitive Sectors between the European Union and the Central European Countries: Preliminary Results. Mimeo. Université de Nantes.

  16. Fidrmuc, J. (1998). Effects of Integration of the CEEC into the EU on Austrian Trade Structure. In K. Pichelmann (ed.), The Economic Consequences of Eastern Enlargement of the European Union. The Austrian View. Research Report. Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna.

  17. Grossman, G. M. (1998). Comment. In J. A. Frankel (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  18. Harrigan, J. (2003). Specialization and the Volume of Trade: Do the Data Obey the Laws? In E. K. Choi and J. Harrigan (eds.), The Handbook of International Trade. Malden, Mass.: Blackwell Publishing.

  19. Hanson, G. H., and C. Xiang (2004). The Home Market Effect and Bilateral Trade Patterns. American Economic Review 94 (4): 1108–1129.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Head, K., and J. Ries (2001). Increasing Returns versus National Product Differentiation as an Explanation for the Pattern of U.S.-Canada Trade. The American Economic Review 91 (4): 858–876.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Head, K., T. Mayer, and J. Ries (2002). On the Pervasiveness of Home Market Effects. Economica 69 (275): 371–390.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Helpman, E., and P. Krugman (1985). Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

  23. Krugman, P. (1980). Scale Economies, Product Differentiation and the Pattern of Trade. American Economic Review 70 (5): 950–959.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Krugman, P. (1987). Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate Changes. In S. W. Arndt and J. D. Richardson (eds.), Real-Financial Linkages among Open Economies. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

  25. Lawrence, C., and P. T. Spiller (1986). Product Diversity, Economies of Scale, and International Trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (1): 63–83.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Rauch, J. R. (1999). Networks versus Markets in International Trade. Journal of International Economics 48 (1): 7–35.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Schumacher, D. (1992). A Note on the Human Capital Intensity of EC Trade. Cahiers Economiques de Bruxelles 133: 3–19.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Schumacher, D. (1997). Impact on German Trade of Increased Division of Labor with Eastern Europe. In S. W. Black (ed.), Europe’s Economy Looks East. Implications for Germany and the European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  29. Trionfetti, F. (2001). Using Home-Biased Demand to Test Trade Theories. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv/Review of World Economics 137 (3): 404–426.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Vittas, H., and P. Mauro (1997). Potential Trade with Core and Periphery: Industry Differences in Trade Patterns. In S. W. Black (ed.), Europe’s Economy Looks East. Implications for Germany and the European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  31. Weder, R. (2003). Comparative Home-Market Advantage: An Empirical Analysis of British and American Exports. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 139 (2): 220–247.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Wood, A. (1994a). North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality. Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

  33. Wood, A. (1994b). Give Heckscher and Ohlin a Chance. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv/Review of World Economics 130 (1): 20–49.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dieter Schumacher.

Additional information

JEL no.

F 12

About this article

Cite this article

Schumacher, D., Siliverstovs, B. Home-Market and Factor-Endowment Effects in a Gravity Approach. Rev. World Econ. 142, 330–353 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-006-0070-z

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-006-0070-z

Keywords

Navigation