Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Effects on growth of environmental policy in a small open economy

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the effect of environmental policy on economic growth in a small open economy in a neoclassical framework with pollution as an argument in both the utility and production functions. We show that environmental policy imposes a drag on long-run growth in both the open and closed economy cases. The effect of environmental policy on growth is stronger in the open economy case relative to the closed economy model if the country has strong aversion to pollution and thus serves as a net exporter of capital in the international capital market. On the other hand, if the agents in the economy have low aversion to pollution and thus import capital, the effect of environmental care on growth is stronger in the closed economy relative to the open economy. Thus, from our setup, environmental policy is harmful to growth but environmental sustainability need not be incompatible with continued economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Keeler et al. (1971), Forster (1973), Gruver (1976), Brock (1977), Becker (1982), Musu (1989), Tahvonen and Kuuluvainen (1993), van der Ploeg and Withagen (1991) and Selden and Song (1995), for similar studies. However, none of these studies allows for international capital flows.

  2. The idea behind this formulation is that “techniques of production are less costly in terms of capital inputs if more pollution is allowed”. To give the rationale for augmenting the aggregate production function as an input in a more formal way, suppose that gross output is produced with capital and effective labour and takes the following general form \( \tilde{Y} = F(K,LT) \). Suppose further that pollution is proportional to gross output according to the relation \( Z = f(\Upomega )\tilde{Y} \). A constant fraction of the gross output \( \Upomega \) is used as input for abatement. This leaves a net output of \( Y = (1 - \Upomega )\tilde{Y} \) which is available for consumption, investment and export. Assume that \( f(\Upomega ) = \left( {1 - \Upomega } \right)^{1/\alpha } \), where 0 < α < 1. This implies that \( Z = (1 - \Upomega )^{1/\alpha } F(K,LT) \Leftrightarrow 1 - \Upomega = Z^{\alpha } \left[ {F(K,LT)} \right]^{ - \alpha } \). This and the expression for net output gives \( Y = Z^{\alpha } \left[ {F(K,LT)} \right]^{1 - \alpha } \), which is constant returns in Z, K and L and can conveniently be written in the form of (1) as above without loss of generality. For a motivation of having Z as an input, see Chap. 2 of Copeland and Taylor (2003).

  3. Here, r(t) is the net rate of return; R(t) is the gross return on capital and \( \delta \) is the rate of depreciation of capital. The reason why this relationship holds among these variables is that in the absence of uncertainty, capital and loans are perfect substitutes as stores of value and, as a result, they must deliver the same return in equilibrium (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 2004).

  4. In this paper we assume θ ≥1 as these values of θ have empirical support (see Hall 1988; Hahm 1998; Stokey 1998; Gali 2008; Jones 2009).

  5. One way to get this is to assume that r = ρ and n = x = 0, which is what Blanchard and Fischer (1989) do. There are however other parameter constellations that will make g χ  = 0 in (35), and we can allow for these possibilities as well.

  6. If \( \beta = 0 \), then g C  = x + n, which is the growth rate in the standard model without environmental protection. Thus if pollution is useless (has zero partial elasticity) then environmental policy does not create drag on growth.

References

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (2004) Economic growth, 2nd edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker RA (1982) Intergenerational equity: the capital-environment trade-off. J Environ Econ Manag 9:165–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Fisher S (1989) Lectures on macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock W (1977) A polluted golden age. In: Smith VL (ed) Economics of natural and environmental resources. Gordon and Breach, New York, pp 441–461

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier S, Levinson A (2004) Examining the evidence on environmental regulations and industry location. J Environ Dev 13:6–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (1994) North–South trade and the environment. Q J Econ 109:755–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (2003) Trade and the environment: theory and evidence. Princeton University Press, Princeton/Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (2004) Trade, growth and the environment. J Econ Lit 42:7–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Maria C, Smulders S (2004), Trade pessimists vs technology optimists: induced technical change and pollution havens. Adv Econ Anal Policy 4 (article 7)

  • Ederington J, Minier J (2003) Is environmental policy a secondary trade barrier? An empirical analysis. Can J Econ 36:137–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eskeland GS, Harrison AE (2003) Moving to greener pastures? Multinationals and the pollution haven hypothesis. J Dev Econ 70:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forster BA (1973) Optimal capital accumulation in a polluted environment. South Econ J 39:544–547

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali J (2008) Monetary policy, inflation and the business cycle: an introduction to the new keynesian framework. Princeton University Press, Princeton/Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruver G (1976) Optimal investment and pollution control in a neoclassical growth context. J Environ Econ and Manag 5:165–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahm JH (1998) Consumption adjustment to real interest rates: intertemporal substitution revisited. J Econ Dyn Control 22:293–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. J Pol Econ 96:339–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson DJ, Millimet DL (2007) Pollution abatement costs and foreign direct investment inflows to US states: a nonparametric reassessment. Rev Econ Stat 89:178–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javorcik BS, Wei SJ (2004) Pollution havens and foreign direct investment: dirty secret or popular myth? Contrib Econ Anal Policy (Berkeley Electronic Press) 3:1–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (2009) The Costs of economic growth (unpublished)

  • Kalamova M, Johnstone N (2011) Environmental policy stringency and foreign direct investment. OECD environment working papers (no. 33). OECD Publishing, France

  • Keeler E, Spence M, Zeckhauser R (1971) The optimal control of pollution. J Econ Theory 4:19–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller W, Levinson A (2002) Pollution abatement costs and foreign direct investment inflows to US states. Rev Econ Stat 84:691–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson A, Taylor MS (2008) Unmasking the pollution haven effect. Int Econ Rev 49:223–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Co CY (2000) The effects of environmental regulations on foreign direct investment. J Environ Econ Manag 40:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet DL, List JA (2004) The case of the missing pollution haven hypothesis. J Regul Econ 26:239–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musu I (1989) Optimal accumulation and control of environmental quality. Nota di Lavoro no. 8903. University of Venice, Venice

  • Selden TM, Song D (1995) Neoclassical growth, the J-curve for abatement, and the inverted U curve for pollution. J Environ Econ Manag 29:162–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey N (1998) Are there limits to growth? Int Econ Rev 39:1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen O, Kuuluvainen J (1993) Economic growth, pollution and renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 24:101–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (1991) Pollution control and the Ramsey problem. Environ Resour Econ 1:215–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldkirch U, Gopinath M (2008) Pollution control and foreign direct investment in Mexico: an industry level analysis. Environ Resour Econ 41:289–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing Y, Kolstad C (2002) Do lax environmental regulations attract foreign investment? Environ Resour Econ 21:1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Dr. Clas Eriksson, Associate Professor of Economics, Malardalen University College, Sweden, Professor Yves Surry, Department of Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, for their insightful comments on the earlier drafts of this paper. I also thank the two anonymous referees for useful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George Adu.

Appendices

Appendix 1: decentralized solution

Then the objective of the household is to maximize

$$ u = \int\limits_{0}^{\infty } {u(C/L,Z){\text{e}}^{ - (\rho - n)t} } {\text{d}}t = \int\limits_{0}^{\infty } {\left[ {\frac{{(C/L)^{1 - \theta } - 1}}{1 - \theta } - \phi \frac{{Z^{1 + \eta } }}{1 + \eta }} \right]} {\text{e}}^{ - (\rho - n)t} {\text{d}}t $$
(48)

with respect to C, subject to

$$ \dot{A} = wL + rA + \varphi - C, $$
(49)

The current value Hamiltonian for the above dynamic optimization problem is

$$ H(C/L,Z,K,\lambda ) = \frac{{(C/L)^{1 - \theta } }}{1 - \theta } - \phi \frac{{Z^{1 + \eta } }}{1 + \eta } + \lambda \left[ {wL + rA + \varphi - C} \right] $$
(50)

Note that the household cannot influence Z. It is therefore not a direct choice variable here. The associated optimality conditions for the representative household are

$$ \frac{\partial H}{\partial C} = 0 \Leftrightarrow C^{ - \theta } L^{\theta - 1} - \lambda = 0 \Leftrightarrow C^{ - \theta } = \lambda L^{1 - \theta } $$
(51)
$$ \frac{\partial H}{\partial A} = - \left[ {\dot{\lambda } - (\rho - n)\lambda } \right] \Leftrightarrow r\lambda = \dot{\lambda } - (\rho - n)\lambda \Rightarrow \dot{\lambda } = (\rho + \delta - n - \alpha /v)\lambda $$
(52)
$$ \lim_{t \to \infty } \left[ {\lambda (t)A(t)} \right]{\text{e}}^{ - (\rho - n)t} = 0 $$
(53)

Note that (6) has been used in Eq. (52). It can conveniently be rewritten as

$$ \frac{{\dot{\lambda }}}{\lambda } = \rho + \delta - n - \alpha /v $$
(54)

Taking logs of Eq. (51), differentiating both sides with respect to time and using condition (54), we obtain the familiar consumption Euler equation.

$$ \frac{{\dot{C}}}{C} = \frac{1}{\theta }\left[ {(\alpha /v) + \theta n - (\rho + \delta )} \right] $$
(55)

Appendix 2: equivalence between command and decentralized solutions

2.1 Optimal tax rule

From the optimality condition in (4), we obtain the following relationship among the growth rates of pollution tax, aggregate production and aggregate emissions as follows.

$$ \frac{{\dot{\tau }}}{\tau } = \frac{{\dot{Y}}}{Y} - \frac{{\dot{Z}}}{Z} $$

Imposing the planners steady state growth rate of aggregate production and pollution into the above condition for the growth rate of the pollution tax, we derived the socially optimal growth rate of the tax as follows.

$$ \frac{{\dot{Y}}}{Y} = \frac{(1 + \eta )(1 - \alpha - \beta )}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))}x + \frac{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta ))}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))}n $$
$$ \frac{{\dot{Z}}}{Z} = - \left( {\frac{(\theta - 1)(1 - \alpha - \beta )x - \beta (\theta - 1)n}{\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta )}} \right) $$
$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{\tau }}}{\tau } &= \frac{(1 + \eta )(1 - \alpha - \beta )}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))}x + \frac{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta ))}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))}n \hfill \\ &\quad+ \left( {\frac{(\theta - 1)(1 - \alpha - \beta )x - \beta (\theta - 1)n}{\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta )}} \right) \hfill \\ \end{aligned} $$
$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{\tau }}}{\tau } &= \left( {\frac{(1 + \eta )(1 - \alpha - \beta )}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))} + \frac{(\theta - 1)(1 - \alpha - \beta )}{\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta )}} \right)x \hfill \\ &\quad+ \left( {\frac{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta ))}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))} - \frac{\beta (\theta - 1)}{\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta )}} \right)n \hfill \\ \end{aligned} $$
$$ \frac{{\dot{\tau }}}{\tau } = \frac{(\theta + \eta )(1 - \alpha - \beta )x + (1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta )n}{{\left( {\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta )} \right)}} $$
(56)

2.2 Steady state growth rates of aggregate variables

Imposing the steady state condition that \( \dot{K}/K = \dot{Y}/Y \) on Eq. (9) we obtain the steady state growth rate of aggregate output as

$$ \frac{{\dot{Y}}}{Y} = n + x - \xi \frac{{\dot{\tau }}}{\tau }. $$

Substituting Eq. (56) into this together with some simplifications, we have

$$ \frac{{\dot{Y}}}{Y} = \frac{(1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta )x + (\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha - \beta )(1 + \eta ))n}{(\beta (\theta - 1) + (1 - \alpha )(1 + \eta ))} $$

Note that we have the same results as the one obtained under command allocation. Thus, we can conclude that with the Pigouvian tax optimally set, the command allocation and decentralized allocation are equivalent.

About this article

Cite this article

Adu, G. Effects on growth of environmental policy in a small open economy. Environ Econ Policy Stud 15, 343–365 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-013-0065-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-013-0065-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation