Skip to main content
Log in

When to merge with a lower quality producer?

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the possibility of different types of mergers when firms produce vertically and horizontally differentiated products. Two firms produce a better quality product, while the third firm produces a lower quality product and the firms compete in quantities. The merger of two firms that produce better-quality products is possible if the quality difference (net of cost) or the horizontal product differentiation are high. However, if the quality difference (net of cost) and the horizontal product differentiation are neither too high nor too low, then the firm that produces the better quality product will merge with the firm that produces a lower quality product. Welfare may increase after the merger between the two firms that produce different quality products. However, if the two firms that produce the better quality product merge then welfare always falls.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Ashenfelter et al. (2013) mentions that in U.S. each year thousands of mergers are proposed to the U.S. Federal Trade Commission and U.S. Department of Justice. After filing, the merging firms must wait while the antitrust authority attempts to identify and block mergers that would increase consumer prices and thereby reduce consumer surplus.

  2. Gugler et al. (2003) analyzes the effects of mergers around the world over the past 15 years.

  3. In India around the mid-1990s, soft-drink giant the Coca-Cola company bought out a well known domestic soft drink brand Thums Up and immediately after this takeover, the company cut down on the advertisement of Thums Up, cut down on it’s supplies to markets and tried to promote Coco-Cola brand more aggressively leading to loss of market share of the Thums Up brand quite substantially. The consumers were not happy to see this dilution of the brand and none of the soft drinks variety was close to the taste of Thums Up as perceived by the consumers (Thumps Up “taste the thunder" which was the tag line of the advertisement). After several years the company re position the brand and it is now a flagship brand of the Coco-Cola company at least in the Indian market (see Dutta 2022). Brand rationalization after merger is a common feature whenever the merging firms have competing brand in the same market. In 2005, the merger of Proctor and Gamble, a US consumer goods company and Gillette, the world’s largest manufacturer of shaving products made them one of the largest consumer products company. However, the product portfolio was rationalized over time and some under-performing brands were sold off.

  4. Under the discrete choice approach there exists the “spokes model” of non-localized spatial competition as a tool for oligopoly analysis developed by Chen and Riordan (2007).

  5. Studies of product differentiation that follow the representative consumer model are Spence (1976), Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), Dixit (1979), Singh and Vives (1984), Hackner (2000) etc. For a detailed review of literature following this tradition as well as the linear demand system, one can see Choné and Linnemer (2020) and Martin (2009). Shubik and Levitan (1980) however considers an aggregate linear demand, differentiated product specification in which total demand at identical prices is constant with respect to changes in the number of varieties. Belleflamme and Peitz (2015) mentions that “Also preferences in these representative consumer models can be specified on an underlying characteristics space. The idea here is that a product is a bundle of different characteristics. A consumer has preferences over these bundles.”

  6. There is another demand system developed by Sutton (1997) and later used by Symeonidis (1999) that characterizes horizontally and vertically differentiated product markets simultaneously. However, they follow the representative consumer model and there too the demand is linear. For analytical simplicity (Symeonidis 1999) also considers that the marginal costs are constant in a study on collusion. This approach is quite similar to Hackner (2000) as followed in our paper.

  7. These costs also include the promotional costs of marketing the brand as well as the production cost of the specific quality associated with the brand.

  8. Sen and Narula (2021) assumes that \(\alpha _{1}>\alpha _{2}=\alpha _{3}\) and \(c_{1}>c_{2}=c_{3}\).

  9. It is always better to produce both the goods in comparison to not producing either of the two products.

  10. It is also to be noted in this context that merger between firm 1 and firm 3 and merger of firm 2 and firm 3 are equivalent to each other.

References

  • Ashenfelter OC, Hosken DS, Weinberg MC (2013) The price effects of a large merger of manufacturers: a case study of Maytag–Whirlpool. Am Econ J Econ Pol 4:239–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belleflamme P, Peitz M (2015) Industrial organization: markets and strategies. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bos I, Vermeulen D (2022) On the microfoundation of linear oligopoly demand. B E J Theor Econ 22:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke KR, Siciliani L, Straume OR (2017) Horizontal mergers and product quality. Can J Econ 50:1063–1103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breton M, Sbragia L (2021) Intra-brand competition in a differentiated oligopoly. J Econ 132:1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R (2021) Whom should I merge with? How product substitutability affects merger profitability. J Ind Bus Econ. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-020-00180-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Riordan MH (2007) Price and variety in the spokes model. Econ J 117:897–921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choné P, Linnemer L (2020) Linear demand systems for differentiated goods: overview and user’s guide. Int J Ind Organ 73:1026–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deneckere R, Davidson C (1985) Incentives to form coalitions with Bertrand competition. Rand J Econ 16:473–486

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1979) A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers. Bell J Econ 10:20–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Stiglitz JE (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta A (2022) Tasting the thunder: How thums up rose to become a billion-dollar brand. Business Today. https://www.businesstoday.in/latest/corporate/story/tasting-the-thunder-how-thums-up-rose-to-become-a-billion-dollar-brand-325041-2022-03-07

  • Ebina T, Shimizu D (2009) Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels. Aust Econ Pap 48:237–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J, Shapiro C (1990) Horizontal mergers: an equilibrium analysis. Am Econ Rev 80:107–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Gugler K, Mueller DC, Yurtoglu BB, Zulehner C (2003) The effects of mergers: an international comparison. Int J Ind Organ 21:625–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hackner J (2000) A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies. J Econ Theory 93:233–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu J, Wang XH (2010) Horizontal mergers in a differentiated cournot oligopoly. Bull Econ Res 62:305–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Zang I (1990) The limits of monopolization through acquisition. Quart J Econ 105:465–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kao T, Menezes F (2010) Welfare-enhancing Mergers under product differentiation. Manch Sch 78:290–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (2009) Microfoundations for the linear demand product differentiation model, with applications. Purdue University Economics Working Papers 1221, Purdue University, Department of Economics

  • Mazzeo MJ, Seim K, Varela M (2018) The welfare consequences of mergers with endogenous product choice. J Indus Econ 66:980–1016

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller DC (1985) Mergers and market share. Rev Econ Stat 67:259–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M, Rosen S (1978) Monopoly and product quality. J Econ Theory 18:301–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norman G, Pepall L, Richards D (2005) Product differentiation, cost-reducing mergers, and consumer welfare. Can J Econ 38:1204–1223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry MK, Porter RH (1985) Oligopoly and the incentive for horizontal merger. Am Econ Rev 75:219–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Salant SW, Switzer S, Reynolds RJ (1983) Losses from horizontal merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on cournot-nash equilibrium. Quart J Econ 98:185–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen N, Kaul S, Biswas R (2021) Technology licensing under product differentiation. J Econ 134:219–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen N, Narula D (2021) Merger under horizontal and vertical product differentiation. Int J Econ Theory. https://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaked A, Sutton J (1982) Relaxing price competition through product differentiation. Rev Econ Stud 49:3–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (1996) Mergers with differentiated products. Antitrust, Spring, 23–30

  • Shubik M, Levitan R (1980) Market structure and behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Singh N, Vives X (1984) Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. Rand J Econ 15:546–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (1976) Product selection, fixed costs, and monopolistic competition. Rev Econ Stud 43:217–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutton J (1997) One smart agent. Rand J Econ 28:605–628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Symeonidis G (1999) Cartel stability in advertising-intensive and R &D-intensive industries. Econ Lett 62:121–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toshimitsu T, Nakajima T (2021) On the “merger paradox" in price competition with asymmetric product differentiation. Aust Econ Pap 60:153–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Neelanjan Sen.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The authors thank Rajit Biswas for the valuable suggestions and comments. We are grateful to the two anonymous referees of this journal for providing some insightful comments which helped us to improve our paper significantly. The usual disclaimer applies. The authors declare that there is no conflict of interest.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sen, N., Sinha, U.B. When to merge with a lower quality producer?. J Econ 138, 165–188 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-022-00807-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-022-00807-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation