Skip to main content
Log in

Indirect taxes in a cross-border shopping model: a monopolistic competition approach

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a model of cross-border shopping with monopolistic competition, we examine the relative merits of an ad valorem (ADV) tax and a unit (specific) tax. Our focus is on the effects of the opening of borders that enables consumption outside the country of the residence. The result shows that the increased cross-border shopping may strengthen or weaken the superiority of either of the two tax methods, depending on the relative weight that the government places on tax revenue and welfare. Specifically, while cross-border shopping always increases the welfare of all countries in ADV tax competition, welfare increases only when the governments place a large weight on tax revenue in unit tax competition. Cross-border shopping lowers welfare when governments with high weight on welfare compete in unit tax.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Keen (1998) for a general review of these studies. Recently, the application of tax analysis to the newly emerging market structure has also been implemented. For instance, Kind et al. (2009) analyzed a two-sided market, while Hamilton (2009) and Lapan and Hennessy (2011) both analyzed a multiproduct market.

  2. Since Schröder (2004), several papers have used monopolistic competitive models to compare unit tax and ADV tax. Dröge and Schröder (2009) compare the two tax methods in the presence of environmental externalities and show that unit tax leads to more firms in the industry, less tax revenue, but higher welfare compared with ad valorem taxes. Vetter (2013) points out the possibility that the result of Schröder (2004) depends on the functional form.

  3. Leal et al. (2010) states that the importance of cross-border shopping increases as two trends in the world economy intensify. The first is the globalization of the economy, which substantially reduces the transaction costs associated with trade relations between territories. The second is the decentralization of tax-raising powers towards jurisdictional government even within the same country, which significantly increases the number of jurisdictions with different taxation on the same goods or services.

  4. Fitzgerald et al. (1988) have found that, in the Republic of Ireland, the main perceived advantage for crossing the border to shop is the variety of items, following the price difference. Mittelstaedt and Stassen (1990) show that product variety, both within an individual store and across competing stores, is likely to attract consumers to shop for specific product purchases across stores in different locations. Timothy and Butler (1995) and Tömöri (2010) have shown that cheaper price and variety of goods are factors that led shoppers to choose to shop across the border in Canada and Hungary, respectively. Wakefield and Baker (1998) found that the variety in the shopping mall has the strongest effect on the desire to stay when competing for mobile customers. Bygvra (2011) shows that the cross-border shopping done by Germans is not caused by price differences to the same extent, but is mainly the result of differences in the range of products available on the other side of the border.

  5. In a line economy in which possible market place locations are restricted to the end of the line, Henkel et al. (2000) study the conditions under which producers of substitutes cluster in market places in order to attract consumers dispersed along the line. Spatial externalities in their model lead the equilibrium to be sub-optimal, and they then analyze the role of coalitions of firms to improve the sub-optimal spatial allocation.

  6. As with many studies, this formulation does not include income effects, but this makes it possible to obtain analytical solutions.

  7. For example, consider a consumer in country 1 who lives at point \(x=-0.5\). If he or she goes to the market in country 1, (2) becomes \(I = H + \int ^{n_1}_{0} p_1(i) m_1(i) di + \tau (1-0.5)\), while if he or she goes to the market in country 2, it becomes \(I = H + \int ^{n_2}_{0} p_2(i) m_2(i) di + \tau (1+0.5)\).

  8. Because the two reaction curves derived from the first-order condition for \(i=1,2\) are continual under \(0\le l_j \le 1\) and symmetric with respect to a 45\(^{\circ }\) (\(t_1=t_2\)) line, there is a unique symmetric equilibrium. The same applies for other cases to be analyzed.

  9. The same notation applies in the following analysis: \(U^{yz}\equiv \int _{x \in L_j}U^{yz}(x)dx\), where \(y=U,A\) and \(z=O,C\).

  10. As \(l_j + l_k = 2\), \(d l_j/d t_j<0\) for \(t_j>0\) and \(d l_j/d r_j<0\) for \(0<r_j<1\) if \(\tau (\sigma - 1)>\mu \).

  11. It shows that when \(\theta =0\), the border opening reduces the equilibrium tax rate in unit tax competition, but not in ADV tax competition. As shown in Lemma 2, the quantity and number of differentiated products satisfy the optimal levels, when the government uses the ADV tax in the closed economy. Hence, the government has no incentive to change its ADV tax rate when the consumers cross the border for their shopping. When the government uses unit tax, however, the number of firms in the equilibrium is insufficient compared with the optimal level. In this case, the government has incentive to reduce its unit tax rate to make the product variety closer to the optimum level.

  12. This can be confirmed, from (17), that \(U_j\) increases as \(t_j\) and \(r_j\) decrease.

References

  • Aiura H, Ogawa H (2013) Unit tax versus ad valorem tax: a tax competition model with cross-border shopping. J Public Econ 105:30–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akai N, Ogawa H, Ogawa Y (2011) Endogenous choice on tax instruments in a tax competition model: unit tax versus ad valorem tax. Int Tax Public Finance 18:495–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akai N, Ogawa H, Ogawa Y (2014) Endogenous choice of subsidy instruments in imperfectly competitive markets: a unit subsidy versus an ad valorem subsidy. Ann Econ Stat/Ann ’Écon Stat 113(114):81–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, Kreider B (2001) Tax incidence in differentiated product oligopoly. J Public Econ 81:173–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bygvra S (2011) The road to the single European market as seen through the Danish retail trade: cross-border shopping between Denmark and Germany. Int Rev Retail Distrib Consum Res 8:147–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Stiglitz J (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Dröge S, Schröder P (2009) The welfare comparison of corrective ad valorem and unit taxes under monopolistic competition. Int Tax Public Finance 16:164–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards J, Keen M (1996) Tax competition and Leviathan. Eur Econ Rev 40:113–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fitzgerald J, Quinn T, Whelan R, Williams J (1988) An analysis of cross-border shopping. Economic & Social Research Institute, Dublin

  • Hamilton SF (2009) Excise taxes with multiproduct transactions. Am Econ Rev 99:458–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henkel J, Konrad S, Walz U (2000) Coalition building in a spatial economy. J Urban Econ 47:136–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgensen J, Schröder P (2005) Welfare-ranking ad valorem and specific tariffs under monopolistic competition. Can J Econ 38:228–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kawachi K, Ogawa H, Susa T (2018) Endogenizing government’s objectives in tax competition with capital ownership. Int Tax Public Finance. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9516-1

  • Keen M (1998) The balance between specific and ad valorem taxation. Fisc Stud 19:1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kind HJ, Koethenbuerger M, Schjelderup G (2009) On revenue and welfare dominance of ad valorem taxes in two-sided markets. Econ Lett 104:86–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lapan HE, Hennessy DA (2011) Unit versus ad valorem taxes in multiproduct Cournot oligopoly. J Public Econ Theory 13:125–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leal A, Lopez-Laborda J, Rodrigo F (2010) Cross-border shopping: a survey. Int Adv Econ Res 16:135–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang W-J, Cheng K, Wang A (2018) The superiority among specific, demand ad valorem and cost ad valorem subsidy regimes. J Econ 123:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B (2004) Competition in unit vs. ad valorem taxes. Int Tax Public Finance 11:763–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B, Wong K (2000) Specific and ad valorem tariffs are not equivalent in trade wars. J Int Econ 52:183–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manuszak M, Moul C (2009) How far for a buck? Tax differences and the location of retail gasoline activity in southeast Chicagoland. Rev Econ Stat 91:744–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mittelstaedt R, Stassen R (1990) Shopping behavior and retail merchandising strategies. J Bus Res 21:243–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal R, Sharma A (2013) Endogenizing government’s objectives in tax competition. Region Sci Urban Econ 43:570–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schröder PJH (2004) The comparison between ad valorem and unit taxes under monopolistic competition. J Econ 83:281–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schröder PJH, Sørensen A (2010) Ad valorem versus unit taxes: monopolistic competition, heterogeneous firms, and intra-industry reallocations. J Econ 101:247–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suits D, Musgrave R (1953) Ad valorem and unit taxes compared. Q J Econ 67:598–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takatsuka H (2014) Tax effects in a two-region model of monopolistic competition. Pap Region Sci 93:595–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timothy D, Butler R (1995) Cross-border shopping: a North American perspective. Ann Tour Res 22:16–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tömöri M (2010) Investing shopping tourism along the borders of Hungary: a theoretical perspective. Geo J Tour Geosites 6:202–210

    Google Scholar 

  • Vetter H (2013) Consumption taxes in monopolistic competition: a comment. J Econ 110:287–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakefield, Baker (1998) Excitement at the mall: determinants and effects on shopping response. J Retail 74:515–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrede M (1998) Household mobility and the moderate leviathan: efficiency and decentralization. Region Sci Urban Econ 28:315–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of this paper was presented at ARSC2013 and NARSC2013. We would like to thank Takanori Ago and Johan Lundberg for their helpful comments. In addition, the comments of anonymous referees and the editor Giacomo Corneo have substantially improved this paper. Any mistakes herein are, of course, our own. The research has been supported by JSPS KAKENHI (Grant Numbers JP25245042, JP16K12374, JP17H02533, JP18H00865, JP18K01632), and the Nitto Foundation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiroshi Aiura.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

From (28) and (29), \(R^{AC}-R^{UC}=0\) and \(U^{AC}-U^{UC}=0\) when \(\theta =1/\sigma \). In addition, \(R^{AC}-R^{UC}\) is an increasing function of \(\theta \) and \(U^{AC}-U^{UC}\) is a decreasing function of \(\theta \). Therefore, \(R^{AC}>(<)R^{UC}\) and \(U^{AC}<(>)R^{UC}\) for \(\theta >(<)1/\sigma \). Furthermore,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d({W^{+}}^{AC}-{W^{+}}^{UC})}{d \theta }&= \frac{d(R^{AC}-R^{UC})}{d \theta } + \frac{d(U^{AC}-U^{UC})}{d \theta } \\&= \frac{\mu }{\sigma -1} -\frac{\mu }{(1-\theta )(\sigma -1)} \le 0, \end{aligned}$$

suggesting that \({W^{+}}^{AC}-{W^{+}}^{UC}\) is a decreasing function of \(\theta \). Notice that \(W^{AC}-W^{UC}=0\) at \(\theta =1/\sigma \). Then we have \({W^{+}}^{AC}<(>){W^{+}}^{UC}\) for \(\theta >(<) 1/\sigma \).

1.2 Proof of Lemma 3

If \(\theta = \hat{\theta }^{O}\), \(t^{UO} = r^{AO} = 0\). Therefore, \(p^{AO}=p^{UO}\), \(R^{AO}=R^{UO}\), and \(U^{AO} = U^{UO}\). Thus, \({W^{+}}^{AO} = {W^{+}}^{UO}\) if \(\theta = \hat{\theta }^{O}\). From (39) and (40), \(p^{AO}-p^{UO}\) and \(R^{AO}-R^{UO}\) are the increasing function of \(\theta \). Thus, \(p^{AO} >(<)p^{UO}\) and \(R^{AO}>(<)R^{UO}\) for \(\theta >(<)\hat{\theta }^{O}\). Since

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{d(U^{AO} - U^{UO})}{d \theta }\\&\quad = -\frac{\sigma \mu }{\sigma -1}\cdot \frac{(1-\theta ) [ 2\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ]^2}{ \{ (\sigma -1)\mu + (1-\theta )[2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \} \{ (\sigma -1)^2 \mu + (1-\theta )\sigma [2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \}} \le 0, \end{aligned}$$

\(U^{AO} - U^{UO}\) is a decreasing function of \(\theta \). Thus, \(U^{AO}<(>)U^{UO}\) for \(\theta >(<)\hat{\theta }^{O}\). Furthermore,

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{d({W^{+}}^{AO}-{W^{+}}^{UO})}{d \theta } = \frac{d(R^{AO}-R^{UO})}{d \theta } + \frac{d(U^{AO}-U^{UO})}{d \theta } \\&\quad = \frac{2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu }{(\sigma -1) \{ 2[\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] +\sigma \mu \} \{ 2[\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] +(\sigma -1)\mu \}}\mu \\&\qquad -\frac{\sigma \mu }{\sigma -1}\cdot \frac{(1-\theta ) [ 2\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ]^2}{ \{ (\sigma -1)\mu + (1-\theta )[2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \} \{ (\sigma -1)^2 \mu + (1-\theta )\sigma [2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \}}, \end{aligned}$$

which is positive at \(\theta =1\) and negative at \(\theta =0\) and \(\theta =\hat{\theta }^{O}\). Furthermore, the second-order derivative shows

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{d^2({W^{+}}^{AO}-{W^{+}}^{UO})}{d \theta ^2}\\&\quad =\frac{\sigma \mu }{\sigma -1}\cdot \frac{[2\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ]^2 \{ (\sigma -1)^3 \mu ^2 -(1-\theta )^2 \sigma [2\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ]^2 \} }{ \{ (\sigma -1)\mu + (1-\theta )[2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \}^2 \{ (\sigma -1)^2 \mu + (1-\theta )\sigma [2 \tau (\sigma -1)-\mu ] \}^2}, \end{aligned}$$

which implies that \({W^{+}}^{AC}-{W^{+}}^{UC}\) has at most one extremum for \(0 \le \theta \le 1\). Therefore, \({W^{+}}^{AC}-{W^{+}}^{UC}\) is a decreasing function of \(\theta \) for \(0 \le \theta < \hat{\theta }^{O}\). Hence, \({W^{+}}^{AO}>{W^{+}}^{UO}\) for \(\theta <\hat{\theta }^{O}\).

1.3 Proof of Lemma 4

We have

$$\begin{aligned} t^{UC}-t^{UO}&=\frac{(\sigma -1)[\theta (\sigma -1)^2 + (1-\theta )]}{(1-\theta ) \sigma \{ (\sigma -1)^2 \mu + (1-\theta )\sigma [2\tau (\sigma -1)-\mu \} ]} \mu c > 0, \\ r^{AC}-r^{AO}&=\frac{\theta \sigma \mu }{[2 \tau (\sigma -1) -\mu ]+(\sigma -1)\mu } \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

which derives Lemma 4.

1.4 Proof of Proposition 2

$$\begin{aligned}&(R^{AC} - R^{AO})-(R^{UC} - R^{UO} ) \nonumber \\&\quad = \frac{\{ 2(2\sigma -1)[(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu ] +\sigma (\sigma -1)\mu \} -(1-\theta )\sigma \{ 4[(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu ] +\sigma \mu \} }{\sigma \{ 2[(\sigma -1) -\mu ]+(\sigma -1)\mu \} \{ 2[(\sigma -1) -\mu ]+\sigma \mu \} }\mu ^2.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Thus, \((R^{AC} - R^{AO})-( R^{UC} - R^{UO} )\) increases with an increase in \(\theta \). Furthermore, \((R^{AC} - R^{AO})-( R^{UC} - R^{UO} )=R^{UO}-R^{AO}>0\) if \(\theta =1/\sigma \) and \((R^{AC} - R^{AO})-( R^{UC} - R^{UO} )<0\) if \(\theta =0\). Therefore, Proposition 2 is proved.

1.5 Proof of Proposition 4

$$\begin{aligned} (U^{AO} - U^{AC}) -( U^{UO} - U^{UC}) = -\mu \ln \alpha g(\theta ) h(\theta ) \end{aligned}$$
(43)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha&= \frac{[2(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu + (\sigma -1)\mu ]^{\sigma /(\sigma -1)}}{2[(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu ] + (\sigma -1)\mu }, \\ g(\theta )&= \frac{(1-\theta )\sigma [2(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu ]+\mu (\sigma -1)^2}{(1-\theta )\sigma [2(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu ]+\mu \sigma (\sigma -1)}, \\ h(\theta )&= \left[ 2(\sigma -1)\tau -\mu + \frac{\sigma -1}{1-\theta }\mu \right] ^{-1/(\sigma -1)}. \end{aligned}$$

As \(g(\theta )\) and \(h(\theta )\) are the decreasing function of \(\theta \), the RHS of (43), that is, \(-\mu \ln \alpha g(\theta ) h(\theta )\), is an increasing function of \(\theta \). Moreover, we have \(-\mu \ln \alpha g(1/\sigma ) h(1/\sigma ) = U^{AO}-U^{UO}>0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} -\mu \ln \alpha g(0) h(0)= - \mu \ln \frac{2\sigma (\sigma -1)\tau +(\sigma ^2 -3\sigma + 1)\mu }{2\sigma (\sigma -1)\tau +(\sigma ^2 -3\sigma )\mu } < 0. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \((U^{AO} - U^{AC}) -( U^{UO} - U^{UC}) > 0\) if \(0\le \theta <\tilde{\theta }\) and \((U^{AO} - U^{AC}) -( U^{UO} - U^{UC}) < 0\) if \(\tilde{\theta } < \theta \le 1\). Accordingly, Proposition 4 is proved.

1.6 Proof of Proposition 5

We have

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{d W^+_j}{d t_j}\right| _{l_j=1}&=\left. \frac{d R_j}{d t_j}\right| _{l_j=1} + \left. \frac{d U_j}{d t_j}\right| _{l_j=1} \\&=-\frac{\mu }{(c+t_j)^2}\left( \frac{c}{\sigma } + t_j \right) , \\ \left. \frac{d W^+_j}{d r_j}\right| _{l_j=1}&=\left. \frac{d R_j}{d r_j}\right| _{l_j=1} + \left. \frac{d U_j}{d r_j}\right| _{l_j=1} \\&=-\frac{\mu }{1-r_j}\left( \frac{1}{\sigma -1} + r_j \right) . \end{aligned}$$

These show that domestic welfare is maximized at \(t^{UC}|_{\theta =0}\) and \(r^{UC}|_{\theta =0}\). Furthermore, they show that domestic welfare decreases as the tax rate moves away from \(t^{UC}|_{\theta =0}\) and \(r^{UC}|_{\theta =0}\).

Domestic welfare is maximized at \(\theta =0\) in the equilibrium of the closed-border economy and in the equilibrium of the open-border economy with ADV tax competition. In the equilibrium of the open-border economy with unit tax competition, domestic welfare is maximized at \(\theta =\mu /[2\tau \sigma (\sigma -1)-\sigma \mu ]\) because of \(t^{UC}=t^{UO}\). These derive Proposition 5.

1.7 Proof of Proposition 6

$$\begin{aligned}&\lim _{\theta \rightarrow 1} [({W^+}^{AO}-{W^+}^{AC})-({W^+}^{UO}-{W^+}^{UC})]\nonumber \\&\quad = \lim _{\theta \rightarrow 1}[(U^{AO} - U^{AC}) -( U^{UO} - U^{UC})] \nonumber \\&\qquad -\lim _{\theta \rightarrow 1}[(R^{AC} - R^{AO})-( R^{UC} - R^{UO} )] \end{aligned}$$
(44)

Substituting (42) and (43) into (44), we obtain \(\lim _{\theta \rightarrow 1} [({W^+}^{AO}-{W^+}^{AC})-({W^+}^{UO}-{W^+}^{UC})] = \infty \), that is \({W^+}^{AO}-{W^+}^{AC}>{W^+}^{UO}-{W^+}^{UC}\) if \(\theta \) is sufficiently close to 1. Further, it is obvious, by Proposition 5, that if \(\theta \) is sufficiently close to 0, \(W^{AO}-W^{AC}\ge 0>W^{UO}-U^{UC}\) and \(|W^{AO}-W^{AC}|<|W^{UO}-U^{UC}|\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aiura, H., Ogawa, H. Indirect taxes in a cross-border shopping model: a monopolistic competition approach. J Econ 128, 147–175 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-019-00659-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-019-00659-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation