Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The effect of intermittent renewables on the electricity price variance

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
OR Spectrum Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The dominating view in the literature is that renewable electricity production increases the price variance on spot markets for electricity. In this paper, we critically review this hypothesis. Using a static market model, we identify the variance of the infeed from intermittent electricity sources (IES) and the shape of the industry supply curve as two pivotal factors influencing the electricity price variance. The model predicts that the overall effect of IES infeed depends on the produced amount: while small to moderate quantities of IES tend to decrease the price variance, large quantities have the opposite effect. In the second part of the paper, we test these predictions using data from Germany, where investments in IES have been massive in the recent years. The results of this econometric analysis largely conform to the predictions from the theoretical model. Our findings suggest that subsidy schemes for IES capacities should be complemented by policy measures supporting variance absorbing technologies such as smart-grids, energy storage, or grid interconnections to ensure the build-up of sufficient capacities in time.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that in the long run the price reducing effect could be offset by adjustments in the conventional capacities (see, e.g., Miera et al. 2008).

  2. If there are no feed-in tariffs, the providers of IES would have an incentive to switch off their production in case the price falls below zero. Hence, IES infeed would depend on market prices. For the sake of simplicity and because the current set of assumptions fits market conditions in most markets, we abstain from this complication of the model.

  3. In principle, suppliers of renewables under the market premium regime are free in selecting a marketplace. However, the day-ahead spot market is way bigger than the intra-day market although the latter is growing: the traded volume in 2013 at the day-ahead market was 245.6 TWh (245.3 TWh in 2012) versus 19.7 TWh on the intra-day market (15.8 TWh in 2012), see EPEX (2014). Therefore, we assume that most of the produced quantities are sold on the day-ahead market.

  4. Germany: EnBW Transportnetze, Tennet TSO, Amprion, and 50Hertz Transmission; Austria: Austrian Power Grid.

  5. For 2010, only one of the german grid operators provided PV forecasts (Tennet TSO). Therefore, we extrapolated PV forecasts for the other grid operators by scaling up and down the Tennet forecasts according to the average ratios between the Tennet forecasts and the forecasts of the corresponding operator in 2011.

  6. The MAPE is defined as \(n^{-1} \sum _{i=1}^n \left| \frac{y_i-\hat{y}_i}{y_i} \right| \) where \((\hat{y}_i)_{i=1}^n\) are the forecasts, \((y_i)_{i=1}^n\) are the actual values, and \(n\) is the total numbers of hours in the underlying period.

  7. Prices for primary energy are highly correlated. In particular, in the observation period, gas imported into continental Europe was mainly procured from long-term supply contracts. The price in these contracts is set with formulas which are based on the current oil price as well as the oil prices from three, six, or nine months (see Yegorov and Wirl 2009). Hence, the lagged variable in the regression.

  8. For a few hours, data points are missing in the publicly available data; therefore, the number of observations varies slightly over the years.

  9. Since Germany and Austria are traditionally winter-peaking countries this seems counterintuitive at first glance. An explanation is that high PV production in summer coupled with lower demand pushes the residual demand in the concave area of the merit order resulting in a higher variance.

References

  • Andrews DWK (1991) Heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimation. Econometrica 59:817–858

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arocena P, Saal DS, Coelli T (2012) Vertical and horizontal scope economies in the regulated U.S. electric power industry. J Ind Econ 60(3):434–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barlow M (2002) A diffusion model for electricity prices. Math Fin 12(4):287–298. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9965.2002.tb00125.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bundesnetzagentur (2012) Report on Energy Supplies in Winter 2011/12. Tech. rep

  • Chao H (2011) Efficient pricing and investment in electricity markets with intermittent resources. Energy Policy 39(7):3945–3953. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crampton P, Ockenfels A, Stoft S (2013) Capacity market fundamentals. Econ Energy Enviro Policy 2(2):27–46

    Google Scholar 

  • de Miera GS, del Ro GP, Vizcano I (2008) Analysing the impact of renewable electricity support schemes on power prices: the case of wind electricity in Spain. Energy Policy 36(9):3345–3359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denholm P, Hand M (2011) Grid flexibility and storage required to achieve very high penetration of variable renewable electricity. Energy Policy 39(3):1817–1830

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne T, Mu X (2010) Investment spikes and uncertainty in the petroleum refining industry. J Ind Econ 58(1):190–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EEG (2014) Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG). Online http://www.erneuerbare-energien.de

  • EIA (2014) US Energy Information Administration. Online. http://www.eia.gov

  • ENTSO-E (2014) European network of transmission system operators for electricity. Online. http://www.entsoe.eu, http://www.entsoe.net

  • EPEX (2014) European power exchange. Online. http://www.epexspot.com

  • Fanone E, Gamba A, Prokopczuk M (2013) The case of negative day-ahead electricity prices. Energy Econ 35:22–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gawel E, Purkus A (2013) Promoting the market and system integration of renewable energies through premium schemes: a case study of the German market premium. Energy Policy 61:599–609

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graf C, Wozabal D (2013) Measuring competitiveness of the EPEX spot market for electricity. Energy Policy 62:948–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green R, Vasilakos N (2010) Market behaviour with large amounts of intermittent generation. Energy Policy 38(7):3211–3220. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.07.038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guille C, Gross G (2009) A conceptual framework for the vehicle-to-grid (v2g) implementation. Energy Policy 37:4379–4390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurland J (1967) An inequality satisfied by the expectation of the reciprocal of a random variable. Am Stat 21:24–25

    Google Scholar 

  • He Y, Hildmann M, Herog F, Andersson G (2013) Modeling the merit order curve of the european energy exchange power market in germany. IEEE Trans Power Syst 28(3):3155–3164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirth L (2013) The market value of variable renewables: the effect of solar wind power variability on their relative price. Energy Econ 38:218–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen HK, Zvingilaite E (2010) Reducing the market impact of large shares of intermittent energy in Denmark. Energy Policy 38(7):3403–3413. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.02.014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jónsson T, Pinson P, Madsen H (2010) On the market impact of wind energy forecasts. Energy Econ 32:313–320. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2009.10.018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ketterer JC (2012) The impact of wind power generation on the electricity price in Germany. Ifo working paper series 143, Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich

  • Kim DW, Knittel CR (2006) Biases in static oligopoly models? Evidence from the California electricity market. J Ind Econ 54(4):451–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McSharry P, Taylor J (2007) Short-term load forecasting methods: an evaluation based on European data. IEEE Trans Power Syst 22(4):2213–2219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milstein I, Tishler A (2011) Intermittently renewable energy, optimal capacity mix and prices in a deregulated electricity market. Energy Policy 39(7):3922–3927. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.11.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muche T (2009) A real option-based simulation model to evaluate investments in pump storage plants. Energy Policy 37(11):4851–4862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mugele C, Rachev ST, Trück S (2005) Stable modeling of different european power markets. Invest Manag Financ Innov 3:65–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Paraschiv F, Erni D, Pietsch R (2014) The impact of renewable energies on eex day-ahead electricity prices. Energy Policy (Article in Press)

  • R Core Team (2013) R: a language and environment for statistical computing. R foundation for statistical computing, Vienna, Austria, URL http://www.R-project.org/

  • Redl C, Haas R, Huber C, Böhm B (2009) Price formation in electricity forward markets and the relevance of systematic forecast errors. Energy Econ 31(3):356–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • See CT, Chen J (2008) Inequalities on the variances of convex functions of random variables. J Inequal Pure Appl Math 9: Article 80

  • Strbac G (2008) Demand side management: benefits and challenges. Energy Policy 36:4419–4426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JW (2010) Triple seasonal methods for short-term electricity demand forecasting. Eur J Oper Res 204(1):139–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • TSOs (2014) German TSOs: Amprion, 50 Hertz, TenneT, and TransnetBW; Austrian TSO: APG. Online. http://www.amprion.net, www.50hertz.com, http://www.tennettso.de, www.transnetbw.de, www.apg.at

  • Tveten ÅG, Bolkesjø TF, Martinsen T, Hvarnes H (2013) Solar feed-in tariffs and the merit order effect: a study of the German electricity market. Energy Policy 61:761–770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner A (2014) Residual demand modeling and application to electricity pricing. Energy J 35(2):45–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woo C, Horowitz I, Moore J, Pacheco A (2011) The impact of wind generation on the electricity spot-market price level and variance: the texas experience. Energy Policy 39(7):3939–3944. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.03.084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wozabal D, Graf C, Hirschmann D (2013) Renewable energy and its impact on power markets. In: Pflug V (ed) Kovacevic. Handbook of risk management for energy production and trading. International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, Springer, pp 283–311

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Yegorov Y, Wirl F (2009) Ukrainian gas transit game. Zeitschrift fr Energiewirtschaft 33(2):147–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeileis A (2006) Object-oriented computation of sandwich estimators. J Stat Softw 16(9):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We want to express our thanks to Klaus Gugler, Felix Höffler, Franz Wirl, and the participants of the Mannheim Energy Conference 2013 for stimulating discussions and valuable inputs on a draft version of this paper. Additionally, the paper greatly benefited from the comments and suggestions of two anonymous referees. David Hirschmann was partially supported by the WWTF (Project Number: MA09-019).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David Wozabal.

Appendix

Appendix

The proof of Proposition 1 requires the following proposition:

Proposition 2

Let \(X\) be a positive random variable which takes values on an interval \([a,b]\). Let \(h: \mathbb {R}^+ \times \mathbb {R}\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) be a function such that the following hold:

  1. 1.

    \(h(X,\cdot )\) is twice differentiable

  2. 2.

    \(h(\cdot ,\epsilon )\) is increasing \(\forall \epsilon \in [a,b]\), and

  3. 3.

    \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon }h(\cdot ,\epsilon )\) is decreasing \(\forall \epsilon \in [a,b]\).

Then for \(\epsilon _1,\epsilon _2 \in [a,b]\) with \(\epsilon _1 < \epsilon _2\) it holds true that \(Var[h(X,\epsilon _2)] \le Var[h(X,\epsilon _1)].\)

Proof

The proof is analogue to the proof of (See and Chen 2008, Theorem3.1). It suffices to show that \(Var[h(X,\epsilon )]\) is a decreasing function of \(\epsilon \). We have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } {\text {Var}}(h(X, \epsilon ))= & {} \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } \mathbb {E}(h(X,\epsilon )^2) - \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } (\mathbb {E}(h(X,\epsilon ))^2 \\= & {} \mathbb {E}\left[ \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } h(X,\epsilon )^2\right] - 2\mathbb {E}(h(X,\epsilon )) \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } (\mathbb {E}(h(X,\epsilon )) \\= & {} \mathbb {E}\left[ 2 h(X,\epsilon ) \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } h(X,\epsilon ) \right] - 2\mathbb {E}(h(X,\epsilon )) (\mathbb {E}( \frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon } h(X,\epsilon )) \\\le & {} 0. \end{aligned}$$

The last inequality follows from the fact that for a random variable \(X\), and for continuous functions \(f,g\) on \(\mathbb {R}\), \(\mathbb {E}[f(X)g(X)] \le \mathbb {E}[f(X)] \mathbb {E}[g(X)]\) if \(f\) is monotonically increasing and \(g\) is monotonically decreasing (see, e.g., Gurland 1967). The interchange of the differential operator and the expectation is clearly justified by the assumptions we have made. \(\square \)

Proof

(Proof of Proposition 1) The proof is analogue to (See and Chen 2008, Theorem 3.3). We sketch the important steps.

Define \(h(u,\epsilon ) = g \left( F_X^{-1}(u) + \epsilon [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u) ] \right) \), with \(\epsilon \in [0,1]\). First, note that \(h(\cdot ,\epsilon )\) is an increasing function \(\forall \epsilon \in [0,1]\). Second, note that \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon }h(\cdot ,\epsilon )\) is a decreasing function since

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial }{\partial u}\frac{\partial }{\partial \epsilon }h(\cdot ,\epsilon )&= \frac{\partial }{\partial u} \left\{ [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u)] \ g^{\prime } \left( F_X^{-1}(u) + \epsilon [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u) ] \right) \right\} \\&= [(F_Y^{-1}{})^{\prime } -( F_X^{-1}{})^{\prime } ] \ g^{\prime } \left( F_X^{-1}(u) + \epsilon [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u) ] \right) \\&+ \epsilon (F_X^{-1}{})^{'} \ [F_Y^{-1} - F_X^{-1} ] \ g^{\prime \prime } \left( F_X^{-1}(u) + \epsilon [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u) ] \right) \\&+ (1 \!- \epsilon ) (F_X^{-1}{})^{'} \ [F_Y^{-1} \!- F_X^{-1} ] \ g^{\prime \prime } \left( F_X^{-1}(u) + \epsilon [ F_Y^{-1}(u) - F_X^{-1}(u) ] \right) \\&\le 0 \end{aligned}$$

For the last inequality note that the first term is negative due to condition (2) and \(g\) being increasing (\(g^\prime >0\)), while the second and third terms are negative due to condition (1), convexity of \(g\) (\(g^{\prime \prime }>0\)), and properties of distribution functions, \((F_X^{-1})^{\prime } \ge 0\) and \((F_Y^{-1})^{\prime } \ge 0\).

Now one can apply Proposition 2 and find

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{Var}[g(Y)] = \mathrm{Var}[h(u,1)] \le \mathrm{Var}[h(u,0)] = \mathrm{Var}[g(X)]. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

The following lemma links inequality (1) to the variance of the random variables.

Lemma 1

If for two random variables \(X\) and \(Y\)

$$\begin{aligned}F^{-1}_Y(\alpha ) - F^{-1}_X(\alpha )\end{aligned}$$

is monotonically decreasing, then \({\text {Var}}(Y) \le {\text {Var}}(X)\).

Proof

Notice that for \(\alpha >\alpha '\), we have

$$\begin{aligned}F^{-1}_Y(\alpha ) - F^{-1}_X(\alpha ) \le F^{-1}_Y(\alpha ') - F^{-1}_X(\alpha ')\end{aligned}$$

and, therefore,

$$\begin{aligned}F^{-1}_Y(\alpha ) - F^{-1}_Y(\alpha ') \le F^{-1}_X(\alpha ) - F^{-1}_X(\alpha '),\end{aligned}$$

i.e., the inter-quantile range of \(Y\) is smaller than that of \(X\) for all quantiles \(\alpha \), \(\alpha '\).

Setting \(\alpha _1 = F_X(\mathbb {E}(X))\) and \(\alpha _2 = F_Y(\mathbb {E}(Y))\), yields

$$\begin{aligned} {\text {Var(X)}}= & {} \int _{-\infty }^\infty (x-\mathbb {E}(X))^2 f_X(x) dx = \int _0^1 (F_X^{-1}(\alpha )-F^{-1}_X(\alpha _1))^2 du \\\ge & {} \int _0^1 (F_Y^{-1}(\alpha )-F_Y^{-1}(\alpha _1))^2 du \ge \int _0^1 (F_Y^{-1}(\alpha )-F_Y^{-1}(\alpha _2))^2 du \\= & {} {\text {Var}}(Y), \end{aligned}$$

where the last inequality follows from

$$\begin{aligned}\mathbb {E}(Y) = F^{-1}_Y(\alpha _2) = \arg \min \left\{ a: \mathbb {E}\left[ (Y-a)^2\right] \right\} .\end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wozabal, D., Graf, C. & Hirschmann, D. The effect of intermittent renewables on the electricity price variance. OR Spectrum 38, 687–709 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-015-0395-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-015-0395-x

Keywords

Navigation