Skip to main content
Log in

Evolving social influence in large populations

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Darwinian studies of collective human behaviour, which deal fluently with change and are grounded in the details of social influence among individuals, have much to offer “social” models from the physical sciences which have elegant statistical regularities. Although Darwinian evolution is often associated with selection and adaptation, “neutral” models of drift are equally relevant. Building on established neutral models, we present a general, yet highly parsimonious, stochastic model, which generates an entire family of real-world, right-skew socio-economic distributions, including exponential, winner-take-all, power law tails of varying exponents, and power laws across the whole data. The widely used Barabási and Albert (1999) Science 286: 509-512 “B-A” model of preferential attachment is a special case of this general model. In addition, the model produces the continuous turnover observed empirically within these distributions. Previous preferential attachment models have generated specific distributions with turnover using arbitrary add-on rules, but turnover is an inherent feature of our model. The model also replicates an intriguing new relationship, observed across a range of empirical studies, between the power law exponent and the proportion of data represented in the distribution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Akerlof GA (1970) The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q J Econ 84:488–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson PW (1972) More is different. Science 177:393–396

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Axtell RL (2001) Zipf distribution of U.S. firm sizes. Science 293:1818–1820

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Barabási AL, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286:509–512

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Batty M (2006) Rank clocks. Nature 444:592–596

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Batty M (2008) The size, scale, and shape of cities. Science 319:769–771

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Beinhocker E (2006) The origin of wealth. Harvard Business School, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Ormerod P (2009) Tradition and fashion in consumer choice. Scot J Polit Econ 56:371–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Shennan SJ (2003) Cultural evolution and stochastic network growth. Am Antiquity 68:459–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Shennan SJ (2005) Random copying and cultural evolution. Science 309:877–879

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Hahn MW, Shennan SJ (2004) Random drift and culture change. Proc R Soc B 271:1443–1450

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bentley RA, Lipo CP, Herzog HA, Hahn MW (2007) Regular rates of popular culture change reflect random copying. Evol Hum Behav 28:151–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger J, Le Mens G (2009) How adoption speed affects the abandonment of cultural tastes. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106:8146–8150

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Boone JL, Smith EA (1998) Is it evolution yet? A critique of evolutionary archaeology. Curr Anthropol 39:S141–S173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgatti SP, Mehra A, Brass DJ (2009) Network analysis in the social sciences. Science 323:892–895

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Borgerhoff Mulder M, Bowles S, Hertz T, Bell A, Beise J, Clark G, Fazzio I, Gurven M, Hill K, Hooper PL, Irons W, Kaplan H, Leonetti D, Low B, Marlowe F, McElreath R, Naidu S, Nolin D, Piraino P, Quinlan R, Schniter E, Sear R, Shenk M, Smith EA, von Rueden C, Wiessner P (2009) Intergenerational wealth transmission and the dynamics of inequality in small-scale societies. Science 326:682–688

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (2005) The origin and evolution of culture. Oxford University, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ, Henrich J (2010) Rapid cultural adaptation can facilitate the evolution of large-scale cooperation. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1100-3

  • Byers BE, Belinsky KL, Bentley RA (2010) Independent cultural evolution of two song traditions in the chestnut-sided warbler. Am Nat 176:476–489

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Clauset A, Shalizi CR, Newman MEJ (2009) Power-law distributions in empirical data. SIAM Rev 51:661–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cronk L, Gerkey A (2007) Kinship and descent. In: Dunbar RIM, Barrett L (eds) The Oxford handbook of evolutionary psychology. Oxford University Press, London, pp 463–478

    Google Scholar 

  • Diederen P, van Meijl H, Wolters A, Bijak K (2003) Innovation adoption in agriculture. Cah Économie Sociol Rurales 67:30–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorogovtsev SN, Mendes JFF (2000) Evolution of networks with aging of sites. Phys Rev E 62:1842

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar RIM, Shultz S (2007) Evolution in the social brain. Science 317:1344–1347

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards AWF (2010) Mathematizing Darwin. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1122-x

  • Eerkens JW (2000) Practice makes within 5% of perfect. Curr Anthropol 41:663–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans TS (2007) Exact solutions for network rewiring models. Eur Phys J B 56:65–69

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Galef BG, Laland KN (2005) Social learning in animals: empirical studies and theoretical models. BioScience 55:489–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallegati M, Keen S, Lux T, Ormerod P (2006) Worrying trends in econophysics. Phys A 370:1–6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat R (1931) Les inégalités économiques. Librarie du Recueil Sirey, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn MW (2008) Toward a selection theory of molecular evolution. Evolution 62:255–265

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn MW, Bentley RA (2003) Drift as a mechanism for cultural change: an example from baby names. Proc R Soc B 270:S120–S123

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hajra B, Sen P (2006) Modelling aging characteristics in citation networks. Phys A 368:575–582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasson O, Stone L (2010) Why do females have so few extrapair offspring? Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1104-z

  • Hauser MD, Chomsky N, Fitch WT (2002) The faculty of language: what is it, who has it, and how did it evolve? Science 298:1569–1579

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Gil-White FJ (2001) The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav 22:165–196

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Gintis H, Fehr E, Camerer C, McElreath R, Gurven M, Hill K, Barr A, Ensminger J, Tracer D, Marlowe FW, Patton JQ, Alvard M, Gil-White FJ, Henrich NS (2005) “Economic man” in cross-cultural perspective: ethnography and experiments from 15 small-scale societies. Behav Brain Sci 28:795–855

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Holden CJ, Sear R, Mace R (2003) Matriliny as daughter-biased investment. Evol Hum Behav 24:99–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houston, A (2010) Central-place foraging by humans: transport and processing. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1119-5

  • Huberman BA, Adamic AL (1999) Growth dynamics of the World-Wide Web. Nature 401:131

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Kacelnik A, Vasconcelos M, Monteiro T, Aw J (2010) Darwin’s ‘Tug-of-War’ vs. Starlings’ ‘Horse-Racing’: how adaptations for sequential encounters drive simultaneous choice. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1101-2

  • Kahneman D (2003) Maps of bounded rationality, psychology for behavioral economics. Am Econ Rev 93:1449–1475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koerper HC, Stickel EG (1980) Cultural drift: a primary process of culture change. J Anthropol Res 36:463–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachlan RF, Slater PJB (2003) Song learning by chaffinches: how accurately and from where? A simulation analysis of patterns of geographical variation. Anim Behav 65:957–969

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laherrère J, Sornette D (1998) Stretched exponential distributions in nature and economy, ‘fat tails’ with characteristic scales. Eur Phys J B 2:525–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laland KN (2004) Social learning strategies. Learn Behav 32:4–14

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Larsen ON (1961) Innovators and early adopters of television. Sociol Inq 32:16–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee R, DeVore I (1976) Kalahari hunter-gatherers. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Liljeros F, Edling CR, Amaral LAN, Stanley HE, Aberg Y (2001) The web of human sexual contacts. Nature 411:907–908

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Lipo CP, Madsen ME, Dunnell RC, Hunt T (1997) Population structure, cultural transmission and frequency seriation. J Anthropol Archaeol 16:301–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lynch A, Baker AJ (1994) A population mimetics approach to cultural evolution in chaffinch song: differentiation among populations. Evolution 48:351–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, J (2010) Ultimate causes and the evolution of altruism. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1110-1

  • Marshall J, McNamara J, Houston A (2010). The state of Darwinian theory. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1121-y

  • Mesoudi A, Lycett SJ (2009) Random copying, frequency-dependent copying and culture change. Evol Hum Behav 30:41–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neiman FD (1995) Stylistic variation in evolutionary perspective. Am Antiquity 60:7–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2005) Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf’s law. Contemp Phys 46:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ormerod P (2006) Why most things fail: evolution, extinction and economics. Pantheon Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto V (1907) Manuel d’économie politique. Giard et Briére, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagel M, Atkinson QD, Meade A (2007) Frequency of word-use predicts rates of lexical evolution throughout Indo-European history. Nature 449:717–720

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Perline R (2005) Strong, weak and false inverse power laws. Stat Sci 20:68–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell A, Shennan SJ, Thomas MG (2009) Late Pleistocene demography and the appearance of modern human behavior. Science 324:1298–1301

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Price DJD (1965) Networks of scientific papers. Science 149:510–512

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ratnieks FLW, Foster KR, Wenseleers T (2010) Darwin’s special difficulty: the evolution of “neuter insects” and current theory. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1124-8

  • Redner S (1998) How popular is your paper? An empirical study of the citation distribution. Eur Phys J B 4:131–134

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Renfrew C, Scarre C (eds) (1998) Cognition and material culture. McDonald Institute for Archaeological Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers EM (1962) Diffusion of innovations. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Salganik MJ, Dodds PS, Watts DJ (2006) Experimental study of inequality and unpredictability in an artificial cultural market. Science 311:854–856

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Shennan SJ (2000) Population, culture history, and the dynamics of change. Curr Anthropol 41:811–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shennan SJ, Wilkinson JR (2001) Ceramic style change and neutral evolution: a case study from Neolithic Europe. Am Antiquity 66:577–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1955a) A behavioral model of rational choice. Q J Econ 59:99–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1955b) On a class of skew distribution functions. Biometrica 42:425–440

    Google Scholar 

  • Slater PJB, Ince SA (1979) Cultural evolution in chaffinch song. Behaviour 71:146–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL (2003) Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. Am Econ Rev 93:465–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srinivasan V, Mason CH (1986) Nonlinear least squares estimation of new product diffusion models. Mark Sci 5:169–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steward J (1955) Theory of culture change. University of Illinois Press, Urbana, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1961) The economics of information. J Polit Econ 69:213–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2002) Information and the change in the paradigm in economics. Am Econ Rev 92:460–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weissing FJ, Edelaar P, van Doorn GS (2010) Adaptive speciation theory: A conceptual review. Behav Ecol Sociobiol. doi:10.1007/s00265-010-1125-7

  • Wiessner P, Schiefenhövel W (1997) Food and the status quest. Berghahn, Providence, RI

  • Winterhalder B, Smith EA (2000) Analyzing adaptive strategies: human behavioral ecology at twenty-five. Evol Anthropol 9:51–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu DW, Sheperd GH (1998) Is beauty in the eye of the beholder? Nature 396:321

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Yule GU (1925) A mathematical theory of evolution based on the conclusions of Dr. JC. Willis. Philos Trans R Soc B 213:21–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zipf GK (1949) Human behavior and the principle of least effort. Addison Wesley, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the Leverhulme Trust for the “Tipping points” programmatic bid. Batty was partially supported by the EPSRC Spatially Embedded Complex Systems Engineering Consortium (EP/C513703/1). Amy Heineike, formerly of Volterra and now at George Mason University, provided programming support.

Conflict of Interests

The authors of this manuscript declare no conflict of interests

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to R. Alexander Bentley.

Additional information

Communicated by Guest Editor A. Houston

This contribution is part of the Special Issue “Mathematical Models in Ecology and Evolution: Darwin 200” (see Marshall et al. 2010).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bentley, R.A., Ormerod, P. & Batty, M. Evolving social influence in large populations. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 65, 537–546 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-010-1102-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-010-1102-1

Keywords

Navigation