Skip to main content
Log in

Reciprocal altruism and food sharing decisions among Hiwi and Ache hunter–gatherers

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The common occurrence of food transfers within human hunter–gatherer and forager–horticulturalist groups presents exciting test cases for evolutionary models of altruism. While kin biases in sharing are consistent with nepotism based on kin selection, there is much debate over the extent to which reciprocal altruism and tolerated scrounging provide useful explanations of observed behavior. This paper presents a model of optimal sharing breadth and depth, based on a general non-tit-for-tat form of risk-reduction based reciprocal altruism, and tests a series of predictions using data from Hiwi and Ache foragers. I show that large, high variance food items are shared more widely than small, easily acquired food items. Giving is conditional upon receiving in pairwise interactions and this correlation is usually stronger when the exchange of value rather than quantities is considered. Larger families and low producing families receive more and give less, consistent with the notion that marginal value may be a more salient currency than quantity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Individual differences in marginal value due to resource holding potential or acquisition ability are not included in this model.

  2. Although larger families should display higher marginal value for food because of having more mouths to feed, larger families could have smaller marginal value if additional family members are net producers. Instead, we might focus on number of dependent children, or the ratio of consumers to adult producers, as an overall indicator of marginal value.

  3. These values of q are conditional upon a foraging event. The probability that individuals go foraging on a given day at the Ache reservation and the Hiwi settlement varies from 0.1 to 0.4.

  4. For each pair of correlated data points, I randomly chose one to use in the analysis and discarded the other.

  5. The amount one can expect to receive from an individual is a function of both her willingness to share and the amount of food she produces. Individuals less willing to share may still receive food from others if their production is above average. Likewise, those who produce less, but give proportionally more, may also receive food.

References

  • Alexander RD (1987) The biology of moral systems. Aldine de Gruyter, Hawthorne, N.Y.

  • Altman JC (1987) Hunter–gatherers today: an aboriginal economy of North Australia. Australian Institute of Aboriginal Studies, Canberra

  • Aspelin P (1979) Food distribution and social bonding among the Mamainde of Mato Grosso, Brazil. J Anthropol Res 35:309–327

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Dion D (1988) The further evolution of cooperation. Science 242:1385–1390

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Hamilton WD (1981) The evolution of cooperation. Science 211:1390–1396

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bliege Bird RL, Bird DW (1997) Delayed reciprocity and tolerated theft: the behavioral ecology of food-sharing strategies. Curr Anthropol 38:49–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliege Bird RL (1999) Cooperation and conflict: the behavioral ecology of the sexual division of labor. Evol Anthropol 8:65–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blurton Jones N (1987) Tolerated theft, and the evolution of sharing, hoarding, and scrounging. Soc Sci Inf 26:31–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Boesch C. (1994) Cooperative hunting in wild chimpanzees. Anim Behav 47:1135–1148

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone JL (1992) Competition, conflict, and the development of social hierarchies. In: Smith EA, Winterhalder B (eds) Evolutionary ecology and human behavior. Aldine de Gruyter, New York, pp 301–337

  • Dugatkin LA, Mesterton-Gibbons M (1996) Cooperation among unrelated individuals: reciprocal altruism, by-product mutualism and group selection in fishes. BioSystems 37:19–30

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Frean M (1996) The evolution of degrees of cooperation. J Theor Biol 182:549–559

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M (2000) To give and give not: the evolutionary ecology of hunter–gatherer food transfers. Ph.D. dissertation. University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, N.M.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M (2004) To give or not to give: an evolutionary ecology of human food transfers. Behav Brain Sci 27 (in press) http://www.bbsonline.org/documents/a/00/0012/57/bbs00001257-00/gurvbbs.htm

  • Gurven M, Hill K, Kaplan H, Hurtado AM, Lyles B (2000a) Food sharing among Hiwi foragers of Venezuela: tests and implications for reciprocity. Hum Ecol 28:171–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M, Allen-Arave W, Hill K, Hurtado AM (2000b) ‘It’s a Wonderful Life’: signaling generosity among the Ache of Paraguay. Evol Hum Behav 21:263–82

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M, Allen-Arave W, Hill K, Hurtado AM (2001) Reservation sharing among the Ache of Paraguay. Hum Nat 12:273–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurven M, Hill K, Kaplan H (2002) From forest to reservation: transitions in food sharing behavior among the Ache of Paraguay. J Anthropol Res 58:91–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Hames R (2000) Reciprocal altruism in Yanomamo food exchange. In: Chagnon N, Cronk L, Irons W (eds) Human behavior and adaptation: an anthropological perspective. Aldine de Gruyter, New York, pp 397–416

  • Hart BL, Hart LA (1992) Reciprocal allogrooming in impala, aepyceromelampus. Anim Behav 44:1073–1083

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkes K (1990) Why do men hunt? Benefits for risky choices. In: Cashdan E (ed) Risk and uncertainty in tribal and peasant economies. Westview, Boulder, Colo., pp 145–166

  • Hawkes K (1992) Sharing and collective action. In: Smith EA, Winterhalder B (eds) Evolutionary ecology and human behavior. Aldine de Gruyter, New York, pp 269–300

  • Hawkes K (1993) Why hunter–gatherers work: an ancient version of the problem of public goods. Curr Anthropol 34:341–361

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkes K, O’Connell JF, Blurton Jones NG (2001) Hadza meat sharing. Evol Hum Behav 22:113–142

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Henry J (1951) The economics of Pilagá food distribution. Am Anthropol 53:187–219

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill K, Hurtado AM (1996) Ache life history: the ecology and demography of a foraging people. Aldine de Gruyter, Hawthorne, N.Y.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill K, Kaplan H (1993) On why male foragers hunt and share food. Curr Anthropol 34:701–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmberg AR (1969) [1941] Nomads of the Long Bow: the Sirionó of Eastern Bolivia. Natural HistoryPress, New York

  • Hurtado AM, Hill K (1990) Seasonality in a foraging society: variation in diet, work effort, fertility, and sexual division of labor among the Hiwi of Venezuela. J Anthropol Res 46:293–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurtado AM, Hill K, Kaplan H, Hurtado I (1992) Trade-offs between female food acquisition and child care among Hiwi and Ache foragers. Hum Nat 3:185–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan H, Hill K (1985) Food sharing among Ache foragers: tests of explanatory hypotheses. Curr Anthropol 26:223–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski M (1987) Tit-for-tat in sticklebacks and the evolution of cooperation. Nature 325:434–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitani JC, Watts DP (2001) Why do chimpanzees hunt and share meat? Anim Behav 61:915–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noe R (1990) A veto game played by baboons: a challenge to the use of the prisoner’s dilemma as paradigm for reciprocity and cooperation. Anim Behav 39:78–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Noe R, Van Schaik CP, Van Hooff AM (1991) The market effect: an explanation for pay-off asymmetries among collaborating animals. Ethology 87:97–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak M, Sigmund K (1994) The alternating prisoner’s dilemma. J Theor Biol 168:219–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein SI, Pierroti R (1988) Distinctions among reciprocal altruism, kin selection, and cooperation and a model for the initial evolution of beneficient behavior. Ethol Sociobiol 9:189–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahlins M (1972) Stone age economics. Tavistock, London

  • Seyfarth RM, Cheney DL (1984) Grooming, alliances and reciprocal altruism in vervet monkeys. Nature 308:541–543

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Sigmund K (1993) Games of life: explorations in ecology, evolution, and behaviour. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Silberbauer G (1981) Hunter/gatherers of the Central Kalahari. In: Harding R, Teleki G (eds) Omnivorous primates. Columbia University Press, New York, pp 454–498

  • Skyrms B, Pemantle R (2000). A dynamic model of social network formation. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 97:9340–9346

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Smith EA (1988) Risk and uncertainty in the ‘original affluent society’: evolutionary ecology of resource-sharing and land tenure. In: Ingold T, Riches D, Woodburn J (eds) Hunter–gatherers, volume 1: history, evolution and social change. Berg, New York, pp 222–251

  • Smith EA, Bliege Bird RL (2000) Turtle hunting and tombstone opening: public generosity as costly signaling. Evol Hum Behav 21:245–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith EA, Boyd R (1990) Risk and reciprocity: hunter–gatherer socioecology and the problem of collective action. In: Cashdan E (ed) Risk and uncertainty in tribal and peasant economies. Westview, Boulder, Colo., pp 167–191

  • Sosis R (2000) Costly signaling and torch fishing on Ifaluk Atoll. Evol Hum Behav 21:223–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers RL (1971) The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol 46:35–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vickery WL, Giraldeau L, Templeton JJ, Kramer DL, Chapman CA (1991) Producers, scroungers, and group foraging. Am Nat 137:847–863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waal FBM de (1997) Food transfers through mesh in brown capuchins. J Comp Psychol 111:370–378

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson GS (1988) Reciprocal altruism in bats and other mammals. Ethol Sociobiol 9:85–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson DS (1997) Hunting, sharing, and multilevel selection: the tolerated theft model revisited. Curr Anthropol 39:73–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winterhalder B (1986) Diet choice, risk, and food sharing in a stochastic environment. J Anthropol Archaeol 5:369–392

    Google Scholar 

  • Winterhalder B (1997) Social foraging and the behavioral ecology of intragroup resource transfers. Evol Anthropol 5:46–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank the Hiwi of Mahenemuthu and the Ache of Arroyo Bandera for their generous support and tolerance. Hiwi research was funded by NSF (BNS-8613215), two grants from the L.S.B. Leakey Foundation, and an NSF Graduate Fellowship to K. Hill and A.M. Hurtado. Ache research was supported by a Leakey grant to Gurven, an NSF Graduate Fellowship, and by the Latin American Institute at the University of New Mexico. Kim Hill, Monique Borgerhoff Mulder, Eric Smith, Troy Tucker, and three anonymous reviewers offered helpful comments that significantly improved earlier versions of this manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Gurven.

Additional information

Communicated by M. Borgerhoff-Mulder

Appendices

Appendix 1a

For a fixed producer priority level at FA, it will be more beneficial to share to an additional individual when V(n)>V(n1).

$${\left( {F - A} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} + n{\left( {\frac{{PA}}{n}} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} > {\left( {F - A} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} + {\left( {n - 1} \right)}{\left( {\frac{{PA}}{{n - 1}}} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} $$
(4)
$${\left( {\frac{n}{{n - 1}}} \right)}^{{1 - {\text{c}}}} > 1$$
(5)

The inequality (Eq. 5) is true when c<1. Therefore it will always be better to increase sharing breadth when the value function is characterized by a diminishing returns curve.

Appendix 1b

It will be advantageous for an acquirer to share with n individuals, and not hoard, when V(n)>V(0). We can calculate the minimal probability that makes sharing a better option than hoarding:

$${\left( {F - A} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} + n{\left( {\frac{{PA}}{n}} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} > F^{{\text{c}}} $$
(6)
$$ \Rightarrow p_{{\min }} > \frac{n}{A}{\left( {\frac{{F^{{\text{c}}} - {\left( {F - A} \right)}^{{\text{c}}} }}{n}} \right)}^{{\raise0.5ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle 1$}\kern-0.1em/\kern-0.15em\lower0.25ex\hbox{$\scriptstyle {\text{c}}$}}} $$
(7)

Appendix 2

For all simulations, F=100, N=20, and r=10. Figures 3a–c allow for half the individuals to reciprocate with p 1=0.8, while the other half reciprocate with p 2=0.2. In Fig. 4, p 1=0.5 and p 2=0.3. In each graph, I consider the acquirer giving 25%, 50%, 75%, and 100% of their acquisition to anywhere from 1 to 20 recipients. Several diminishing value functions, including the natural logarithmic function and power functions of degree between 0.3 and 0.6 were evaluated. The value function used for presentation is a square root function (c=0.5), although other value functions give similar qualitative results. In terms of identifying an intermediate optimal breadth and depth, the square root function will be more conservative than the logarithmic function because the former is less steeply declining than the latter. The dashed horizontal line in each figure gives the baseline benefit (FA)c from hoarding. Return values V(n) are calculated according to Eqs. 4 and 5. See also Fig. 5. Details about the figures are given in the text.

Fig. 3a–c
figure 3

Simulations of the sharing breadth–depth model. Resource package size F=100. Horizontal line represents the expected value if none is given away. V(n) refers to the expected value an acquirer will receive over a relevant time period from sharing 25%, 50%, 75%, and 100% of a resource. Ten individuals return food with a probability p 1=0.8, and ten with probability p 2=0.2. The variable q describes the probability that two foragers return food to an acquirer on the same day, and varies in a q=0.1, b q=0.5, and c q=0.9

Fig. 4a–b
figure 4

Simulations of the sharing breadth-depth model. Similar to Fig. 3b, c, except resource package size is reduced, F=10, and p 1=0.5, and p 2=0.3 in (b). Horizontal line represents the expected value if none is given away

Fig. 5a–c
figure 5

Graphs of V(n) with linear cost function (n × cost). Similar to Fig. 4b, with a cost a c=0.03, b c=0.05. In part c the cost c=0.1 and probability of simultaneous returns q=0.5

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gurven, M. Reciprocal altruism and food sharing decisions among Hiwi and Ache hunter–gatherers. Behav Ecol Sociobiol 56, 366–380 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-004-0793-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00265-004-0793-6

Keywords

Navigation