Skip to main content
Log in

Bargained haircuts and debt policy implications

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We extend the Cole and Kehoe model (J Int Econ 41:309–330, 1996) by adding a Rubinstein bargaining game between creditors and debtor country to determine the share of debt repayment in a sovereign debt crisis. Ex-post, the possibility of partial repayment avoids the costly case of total default, as seen recently in Greece. Ex-ante, the effects are to increase the sovereign debt cap and delay the fiscal adjustment. In other words, expectations of a haircut in times of crisis relax leverage restrictions implied by financial markets and make government more lenient, suggesting caution with haircut adoption, especially when risk-free interest rates are low.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Sudden changes in outcomes, such as market prices of public bonds, without obvious comparable changes in the set of fundamentals, including public debt level, tax revenues and public expenditures.

  2. For an applied example of multiplicity under non-common knowledge, see Araujo et al. (2016).

  3. Here, the central planner is a player in a bargaining game, though in fact its importance to solve sovereign crises involves other aspects. Arellano and Bai (2014) discuss some of them.

  4. For further discussions on debt recovery rates and equilibrium implications, see Mora (2012) and Yue (2010). In the last, the debt recovery rate is determined in a Nash bargaining game, which also affects the country’s ex-ante incentives to default.

  5. Conesa and Kehoe (2014) also consider bailout of government debt by official lenders in a debt crisis and highlight that the bailout cost is smaller than the cost of a total default.

  6. In each period, the crisis probability is defined exogenously, but the more periods the economy remains in the crisis zone, the higher is the cumulative chance of a crisis occurrence. One may argue that crisis probability per period itself should increase with partial default, a case to be considered in further extensions.

  7. In order to avoid excessive wordiness, henceforth we omit the word partial.

  8. \(f(0)=0;\ f^\prime (0)=\infty ;\) \(f^\prime (\infty )=0\).

  9. See Kaminsky and Vega-Garcia (2014) for another discussion of investors asking higher discount rates to reflect a crisis rate.

  10. Arellano (2008) describes an income shock and assumes it as i.i.d. In our paper, the income is also affected, but via productivity, \(a_{t}\).

  11. The international credit restriction resulted from speculative attack on sovereign debt may be a response to a change in economic fundamentals not explicitly described in the model, such as a persistent change in prices of a key commodity exported by the country, fear of change in the government preferences after national elections, or a sudden reduction of international liquidity.

  12. Sunspot \(\pi \) is considered independent from \(\phi \).

  13. For new issuance during the crisis we consider \(E(z^{\prime })=0\), to reflect the debt market closure.

  14. We could represent governments more concerned about private goods by replacing \(\ln (g)\) with \(\frac{\ln (g)}{2},\) for example.

  15. See Greece government debt to GDP at http://www.tradingeconomics.com/greece/government-debt-to-gdp.

  16. Under low probability of crisis, the first effect (lower interest rates due to the expected haircut instead of no payment) is more than sufficient to decelerate the fiscal adjustment to exit the crisis zone.

  17. Presented at 13th SAET conference from July 22 through July 27 in Paris, France, at MINES ParisTech.

  18. Redundant given condition (iii) - to be derived.

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcia Leon.

Additional information

We would like to thank the participants at the 13th SAET meeting, the editor, and two anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments.

Appendix

Appendix

First, we highlight that, as already extensively discussed in the original Cole and Kehoe model (1996), a government that cares sufficiently more about private than public consumption or is sufficiently farsighted is guaranteed to have a non-empty crisis zone (i.e., \(\overline{B}>\underline{B}\)). Second, we assume the existence of a non-empty crisis zone for \(\phi =0\), and we show, in the end of this appendix, that the condition \(\overline{B}>\underline{B}\) remains as long as \(\phi \) has an upper limit.Next, we are going to detail the three conditions—(i), (ii) and (iii)—that ensure the result of our proposition, taking as given the existence of the crisis zone for \(\phi =0\). To derive such conditions, note that the floor of the crisis zone, \(\underline{B},\) is defined as the highest stationary debt level under which not defaulting \((z=1)\) is better than defaulting \((z=\phi <1),\) even when there is a speculative attack, i.e., \(q=0\) and new debt is not available. Then, to compute the floor of the crisis zone, we need to compare \(V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)\) with \(V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )\). Formally, \(V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)\) is given by : 

$$\begin{aligned} V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)&=\underline{C1}+\underline{G1}\\ \underline{C1}&\equiv \frac{\left( 1-\theta \right) \left( f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) }{1-\beta }\\ \underline{G1}&\equiv \frac{\left( 1-\beta ^{T}\right) v\left( g_{n} -\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) +\beta ^{T}v\left( g_{n}\right) }{1-\beta }\\ g_{n}&\equiv \theta \left[ f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right] \\ K^{n}\text { solves }\frac{1}{\beta }&=(1-\theta )\left[ f^\prime (k^{\prime })-\delta \right] +1\quad \text {and}\\ \frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)}{\partial B}&=\frac{\partial \underline{G1} }{\partial B}=-v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) <0 \end{aligned}$$

where the payment of \(\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\) must be made at maturities \(1,2,\ldots ,T\), and the value function is decreasing in the current debt level as expected. \(V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )\) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned}&V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )=\underline{C0}+\underline{G0}\\&\underline{C0}\equiv \left( 1-\theta \right) \left[ \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right] +K^{n}-K^{d}+\frac{\beta \left( 1-\theta \right) \left[ \alpha f\left( K^{d}\right) -\delta K^{d}\right] }{1-\beta }\\&\underline{G0}\equiv v\left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\frac{\phi B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T} }\right) \\&\quad \qquad +\,\beta \frac{\left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) v\left( g_{d}-\frac{\phi B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) +\beta ^{T-1}v\left( g_{d}\right) }{1-\beta }\\&g_{d}\equiv \theta \left[ \alpha f\left( K^{d}\right) -\delta K^{d}\right] \\&K^{d}\text { solves }\frac{1}{\beta }=(1-\theta )\left[ f^\prime (k^{\prime })\alpha -\delta \right] +1\\&\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )}{\partial B}=\frac{\partial \underline{G0}}{\partial B}\text { which is given by:}\\&\left( \frac{-\phi }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) \left\{ \left( 1-\beta \right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi B_{T}\right) +\left( \beta -\beta ^{T}\right) v^\prime \left[ g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right] \right\} \\&\text {where, } B_{T}\equiv \frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}} \end{aligned}$$

and again, the debt payment of \(\frac{\phi B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\) must be made during T periods, and the value function is decreasing in the current debt level as expected. For B sufficiently close to zero, it is trivial to conclude that \(V(s\left( B\rightarrow 0\right) , B^\prime ,0,\phi )<V(s\left( B\rightarrow 0\right) , B^\prime ,0,1),\) since after the default, the productivity becomes lower without significantly improving the public expenditure. Moreover, if B is high enough, higher than \(g_{n}\frac{1-\beta ^{T}}{\left( 1-\beta \right) },\) then \(z_{t}=1\) is not an option as g cannot be negative. To ensure \(z_{t}=\phi \) as the unique feasible option for this high debt level, \(\phi \) must be lower than \(\frac{g_{d}}{g_{n}}\).Footnote 18 Then, to assure the existence of the floor of the crisis zone, \(\underline{B},\) it is sufficient to have \(\phi <\frac{g_{d}}{g_{n}}\) and \(\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)}{\partial B}<\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )}{\partial B},\) or, more than sufficient to have : 

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{v^\prime \left( \theta \left( f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) }{v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi \frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T} }\right) }>1>\phi \end{aligned}$$

assured by

$$\begin{aligned}&\theta \left[ f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right] -\theta \left[ \alpha f\left( K^{d}\right) -\delta K^{d}\right]<\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\left( 1-\phi \right) \\&\phi <1-\frac{\theta \left( f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{d}\right) -\delta K^{d}\right) }{\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}} \end{aligned}$$

i.e., funds raised by the government due to the partial default must be higher than the reduction of the government revenue from tax collection.

The cap of the crisis zone, \(\overline{B},\) is defined as the highest stationary debt level under which not defaulting \((z=1)\) is better than defaulting \((z=\phi <1)\) when there is no speculative attack, i.e., \(q=\beta \) and new lending is available. Then, to compute the cap of the crisis zone, we need to compare \(V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,1)\) with \(V(s,B^\prime , \beta ,\phi ).\) Formally, \(V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,1)\) is given by : 

$$\begin{aligned}&V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,1)=\overline{C1}+\overline{G1}\\&\overline{C1}\equiv \frac{\left( 1-\theta \right) \left( f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) }{1-\beta }\\&\overline{G1}\equiv \frac{v\left( g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) }{1-\beta }\\&\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,1)}{\partial B}=\frac{\partial \overline{G1}}{\partial B}=-v^\prime \left( g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) \end{aligned}$$

where \(B\left( 1-\beta \right) \) is the interest payment on total debt. The value function is decreasing in the current debt level as expected. \(V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )\) is given by : 

$$\begin{aligned}&V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )=\overline{C0}+\overline{G0}\\&\overline{C0}\equiv \left( 1-\theta \right) \left[ \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right] +K^{n}-K^{d}+\frac{\beta }{1-\beta }\left[ \left( 1-\theta \right) \left( \alpha f\left( K^{d}\right) -\delta K^{d}\right) \right] \\&\overline{G0}\equiv v\left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) \\&\quad \qquad +\,\frac{\beta \left[ \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) v\left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) +\beta ^{T-1}v\left( g_{d}\right) \right] }{1-\beta }\\&B_{T}\equiv \frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\quad \text {and}\quad q_{_{T} }=\beta ^{T}\\&\qquad \,\, \left( -\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )}{\partial B}\right) \text { is given by:}\\&\frac{\left( 1-\beta \right) \left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) }{1-\beta ^{T} }v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) \\&\qquad +\,\phi \frac{\beta \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\left[ v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$

For B sufficiently close to zero, it is trivial to conclude that \(V(s\left( B\rightarrow 0\right) , B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )<V(s\left( B\rightarrow 0\right) , B^\prime ,\beta ,1),\) since after the default, the productivity becomes lower without significantly improving the public expenditure. Moreover, if B is high enough, higher than \(\frac{g_{n} }{\left( 1-\beta \right) },\) then \(z_{t}=1\) is not an option as g cannot be negative. To ensure \(z_{t}=\phi \) as the unique feasible option for this high debt level, \(\phi \) must be lower than \(\left( 1-\beta ^{T}\right) \frac{g_{d}}{g_{n}}\). Given this condition, to ensure the existence of the cap of the crisis zone, \(\overline{B},\) it is sufficient to have \(\frac{dV(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,1)}{dB}<\frac{dV(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )}{dB},\) or, by considering \(\left( \phi \le \beta ^{T}\right) \), it is sufficient to have:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{v^\prime \left( g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) }{v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) }>\phi \beta \\&\text {assured by}\\&g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right)<g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\\&\phi B_{T}+\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right)<B\left( 1-\beta \right) \\ \quad&\text {or}\\&\phi <\left( 1-\beta ^{T}\right) \frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) -\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right) }{B\left( 1-\beta \right) } \end{aligned}$$

Then, we have two conditions for the existence of \(\overline{B}\). First, partial default must occur on the principal amount of the debt, i.e., partial default must imply negative return on bonds \(\left( \phi <\beta ^{T}\right) \). Note that, after the payment of \(\phi \), the rate of return is equal to \(\left( \frac{\phi }{\beta ^{T}}-1\right) \). Second, the flow reduction of the government revenue from both tax collection \(\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right) \) and partial repayment of maturing debt \(\left( \phi B_{T}\right) \) must be lower than the total interest payment on the total debt \(B\left( 1-\beta \right) \). Therefore, the conditions for \(\underline{B} \) and \(\overline{B}\) to be well defined are the following:

$$\begin{aligned}&\phi B_{T}+\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right)<\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\\&\phi B_{T}+\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right)<B\left( 1-\beta \right) \\&\phi B_{T}+\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right)<\beta ^{T}B_{T}+\left( g_{n} -g_{d}\right) \\&\phi <\left( 1-\beta ^{T}\right) \frac{g_{d}}{g_{n}} \end{aligned}$$

and noting that the first condition is redundant, we can focus only in the following three conditions:

$$\begin{aligned}&(\hbox {i})\quad \phi B_{T}+\left( g_{n}-g_{d}\right)<B\left( 1-\beta \right) \\&(\hbox {ii})\quad \phi<\beta ^{T}\\&(\hbox {iii})\quad \phi <\left( 1-\beta ^{T}\right) \frac{g_{d}}{g_{n}} \end{aligned}$$

Again, as already discussed in the original CK96 paper, a government that cares sufficiently more about private than government consumption or is sufficiently farsighted is guaranteed to have a crisis zone \((\overline{B}>\underline{B})\). For a non-empty crisis zone, conditions (i), (ii) and (iii) are sufficient to ensure the result of proposition, i.e., the higher the \(\phi ,\) the higher are the limits \(\overline{B}\) and \(\underline{B}\). Note that since \(\underline{B}\) is increasing in \(\phi \) and \(V(s,B^\prime ,0,1)\) does not depend on \(\phi \), it is sufficient to show that \(\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )}{\partial \phi }<0,\) which is true, since : 

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \left( 1-\beta \right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\frac{\phi B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) \right. \\ \left. +\,\beta \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\frac{\phi B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) \right] >0 \end{aligned}$$

and to have \(\overline{B}\) increasing in \(\phi ,\) it is sufficient to show that \(\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )}{\partial \phi }<0,\) which is true:

$$\begin{aligned}&-\,B_{T}\ \left\{ v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) \right. \\&\qquad \left. +\,\frac{\beta \left[ \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \right] }{1-\beta }\right\} <0 \end{aligned}$$

Finally, in order to assure that the crisis zone characterized under total default; \(\left[ \underline{B}_{\phi =0},\overline{B}_{\phi =0}\right] \) remains non-empty under partial default (\(\phi >0\)), i.e., to assure that \(\underline{B}_{\phi >0}\) remains smaller than \(\overline{B}_{\phi >0}\) when partial repayment is allowed, it is sufficient to show that the resulted reduction in the crisis zone is limited:

or it is sufficient to have

where,

$$\begin{aligned}&\hbox {LHS}=-v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) \\&\qquad \times \left( \begin{array}[c]{c} \frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )}{\partial \phi }-\frac{\left( 1-\beta \right) \left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) }{1-\beta ^{T}}\\ -\frac{\phi \beta \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) }{1-\beta ^{T}} \end{array}\right) \\&\hbox {RHS}=-v^\prime \left( g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) \\&\qquad \times \left( \frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )}{\partial \phi }-\left( \frac{\phi }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) \left\{ \begin{array}[c]{l} \left( 1-\beta \right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi B_{T}\right) \\ +\left( \beta -\beta ^{T}\right) v^\prime \left[ g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right] \end{array}\right\} \right) \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,\beta ,\phi )}{\partial \phi }=-B_{T}v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) \\&\quad -B_{T}\frac{\beta \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) }{1-\beta }v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \\&\frac{\partial V(s,B^\prime ,0,\phi )}{\partial \phi }=-B_{T}v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi B_{T}\right) \\&\quad -B_{T}\frac{\beta \left( 1-\beta ^{T-1}\right) }{1-\beta }v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \\&\hbox {so}\\&\hbox {LHS}=v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\frac{B\left( 1-\beta \right) }{1-\beta ^{T} }\right) \\&\quad \times \left( \begin{array} [c]{c} \left( \phi +B-\beta ^{T}\right) \left( \frac{1-\beta }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -B_{T}\left( \phi -\beta ^{T}\right) \right) \\ +\left( \phi +B\right) \left( \frac{\beta -\beta ^{T}}{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \end{array} \right) \\&\hbox {RHS}=v^\prime \left( g_{n}-B\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) \\&\quad \times \left( \begin{array} [c]{c} \left( \phi +B\right) \left( \frac{1-\beta }{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi B_{T}\right) \\ +\left( \phi +B\right) \left( \frac{\beta -\beta ^{T}}{1-\beta ^{T}}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{d}-\phi B_{T}\right) \end{array} \right) \end{aligned}$$

and to have non-empty crisis zone at least for \(T=1\) and a positive \(\phi \), after replacing the debt level where derivative is evaluated, it is sufficient to have:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( \phi +\underline{B}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\overline{B}\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) \left( v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi \underline{B}\right) \right) \\&\qquad -\left( \phi +\overline{B}-\beta \right) v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\underline{B} \right) \left( v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi \overline{B}+\beta \overline{B}\right) \right) \le 0 \end{aligned}$$

And it is sufficient

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi \underline{B}\right) \right) }{v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\underline{B}\right) }\le \frac{\left( \phi +\overline{B}-\beta \right) \left( v^\prime \left( \theta \left( \alpha f\left( K^{n}\right) -\delta K^{n}\right) -\phi \overline{B}+\beta \overline{B}\right) \right) }{\left( \phi +\underline{B}\right) v^\prime \left( g_{n}-\overline{B}\left( 1-\beta \right) \right) } \end{aligned}$$

As in the original Cole and Kehoe model, depending on the set of parameters, the crisis zone is non-empty. For a particular example, and remembering that a government that cares sufficiently more about private than public consumption or that is sufficiently farsighted assures a non-empty crisis zone (i.e., \(\Delta >0\)), suppose \(v^\prime (.)\) tends to a constant \(\kappa \). Then, the previous condition becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \beta \le \overline{B}_{\phi =0}-\underline{B}_{\phi =0}\equiv \Delta \end{aligned}$$

and \(\beta <\Delta \) makes the incentive to smooth the private consumption important enough to assure a non-empty crisis zone for, at least, \(T=1\), and small positive \(\phi \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Araujo, A., Leon, M. & Santos, R. Bargained haircuts and debt policy implications. Econ Theory 64, 635–656 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-0981-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-0981-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation