Skip to main content
Log in

The evolution of the world trade web: a weighted-network analysis

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper employs a weighted network approach to study the empirical properties of the web of trade relationships among world countries, and its evolution over time. We show that most countries are characterized by weak trade links; yet, there exists a group of countries featuring a large number of strong relationships, thus hinting to a core-periphery structure. Also, better-connected countries tend to trade with poorly-connected ones, but are also involved in highly-interconnected trade clusters. Furthermore, rich countries display more intense trade links and are more clustered. Finally, all network properties are remarkably stable across the years and do not depend on the weighting procedure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A survey of this enormous literature is beyond the scope of this paper. The interested reader is referred to Scott (2000), Barabási (2003), Watts (2003), Carrington et al. (2005), among others.

  2. Well-known examples of such studies include networks of friendship and social acquaintances (Rapoport and Horvath 1961; Milgram 1967), marriages (Padgett and Ansell 1993), and job-market interactions (Granovetter 1974).

  3. See Jackson (2004) for an introduction.

  4. The analysis of weighted networks was introduced in Barrat et al. (2004, 2005), Barthélemy et al. (2005), and further developed in Dall’Asta et al. (2006), Saramaki et al. (2007), Onnela et al. (2005), DeMontis et al. (2005).

  5. Cf. also Fagiolo et al. (2009), where links are weighted using trade flows only.

  6. We refer the reader to Fagiolo et al. (2007) for more formal definitions and notation.

  7. Self-loops, i.e. links connecting i with itself are not typically considered. This means that a ii  = 0, for all i.

  8. For example in random networks where each link is in place with a certain given probability, independently on all the others (i.e., according the simplest Erdös-Renyi random-graph model: see e.g. Bollobás 1985). In what follows, we employ the term “random network” as a synonym for the Erdös-Renyi random-graph model.

  9. Network clustering is a well-known concept in sociology, where notions such as “cliques” and “transitive triads” have been widely employed (Wasserman and Faust 1994; Scott 2000). For example, friendship networks are typically highly clustered (i.e. they display high cliquishness) because any two friends of a person are very likely to be friends.

  10. See Herfindahl (1959) and Hirschman (1964). For early applications of the disparity index to networks, see Almaas et al. (2004) and Barthélemy et al. (2005).

  11. That is (a ij ,w ij ) are replaced by (max{a ij ,a ji },0.5(w ij  + w ji )), see De Nooy et al. (2005).

  12. Sacks et al. (2001) build a measure of country position in the network based on the concept of “structural autonomy” and show that it has a positive effect on country’s per capita GDP.

  13. Very similar results are obtained by Mahutga (2006), who shows that the globalization process has induced structural heterogeneity and thus inequality.

  14. There is no agreement whatsoever on the way this threshold should be chosen. For example, Kim and Shin (2002) use cutoff values of US$ 1 million and 10 million. Kastelle et al. (2005) endogenously set a cutoff so as to have, in each year, a connected graph. Kali and Reyes (2009) experiment with different lower thresholds defined as shares of country’s total exports. On the contrary, other papers (Serrano and Boguñá 2003; Garlaschelli and Loffredo 2004a, 2005; Kali and Reyes 2007) straightforwardly define a link whenever a non-zero trade flow occurs.

  15. That is, they weight each link by the difference between exports and imports. Notice that, as happens also in Bhattacharya et al. (2007a, b), their across-year comparison may be biased by the fact that trade flows are expressed in current U.S. dollars and do not appear to be properly deflated.

  16. See Fagiolo et al. (2007) for technical details. Note that the corresponding standardized index takes values at least 10 standard deviations below zero.

  17. Due to the extreme symmetry of the network, results do not change if one symmetrizes the export matrix first and then divides by the GDP of the exporting country.

  18. As the right panel of Fig. 5 shows, there seems to be a subset of countries featuring low ND and relatively high strength.

  19. As discussed in Section 5.7, this holds true even if one replaces the baseline weighting procedure with a few, economically meaningful, alternative schemes.

  20. The key assumptions are that the benefits from connections exhibit decreasing returns, and that they depend negatively on distance. Contrary to the predictions of the model, the WTW does not display a single country as its center. This is due to the fact that in the (real) world of international trade, the benefit from connecting to a country is not monotonically increasing in the number of its trading partners. This suffices for a network to display more that one hub.

  21. This interpretation is further corroborated by the fact that geographically-structured networks are typically highly clustered, with short-distance links counting more than long-distance ones.

  22. Indeed, the weighted version of the CC, albeit quite stable over time, is significantly smaller (from a statistical point of view) than its expected value in a random network. Indeed, average clustering ranges from 3.8776×10 − 4 (in 1994) to 5.5106×10 − 4 (in 1982) whereas the expected value of weighted clustering in random networks goes in the same years from 0.2272 to 0.2717—that is, \(\frac{27}{64}\) times network density (see Fagiolo et al. 2007 for details).

  23. To do so, for each year we generated a sample of 10000 random networks whose adjacency matrices have been kept fixed and equal to the observed one, whereas observed link weights have been randomly reshuffled across the links.

  24. Also the shape of the underlying relation is different. While degree seems to be linearly related to pcGDP, a log-log relation holds between strength and pcGDP. This means that pcGDP influences more heavily node strength than node degree.

  25. The correlation between the two indicators is not statistically different from 1.

  26. A very similar result is obtained if one attributes the core status to those countries displaying values of RWBC above the mean plus one standard deviation.

  27. This is expected since one of the interpretations of node strength is related to the degree of influence that a given node has on the network or to what extent other nodes depend on a given node; also, the correlation between RWBC and NS is very high.

  28. As mentioned, we have also experimented with another weighting scheme where we have symmetrized the graph before dividing by exporter (or importer) GDP. All these alternatives did not result in any significant change of our main findings.

  29. This counter-intuitive result depends on the fact that the index computed controls for magnitude effects. Therefore, GDP scaling may enhance differences between imports and exports rather than balancing them.

  30. More detailed results are available from the authors upon request.

  31. In this respect, an interesting exercise would imply to find (if any) a proper rescaling or manipulation of original trade flows that makes weighted and binary undirected network results looking the same.

References

  • Abeysinghe T, Forbes K (2005) Trade linkages and output-multiplier effects: a structural var approach with a focus on Asia. Rev Int Econ 13:356–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albert R, Barabási AL (2002) Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Rev Mod Phys 74:47–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almaas E, Kovács B, Vicsek T, ZN O, Barabási AL (2004) Global organization of metabolic fluxes in the bacterium Escherichia coli. Nature 427:839–843

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora V, Vamvakidis A (2005) How much do trading partners matter for economic growth? IMF Staff Papers 52(1):24–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Baier S, Bergstrand J (2004) Economic determinants of free trade agreements. J Int Econ 64:29–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabási AL (2003) Linked. Plume, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrat A, Barthélemy M, Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2004) The architecture of complex weighted networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci 101:3747–3752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrat A, Barthélemy M, Vespignani A (2005) Weighted evolving networks: coupling topology and weights dynamics. arxiv:cond–mat/0401057v2

  • Barthélemy M, Barrat A, Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2005) Characterization and modeling of complex weighted networks. Physica A 346:34–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya K, Mukherjee G, Manna S (2007a) The international trade network. arxiv:0707.4347v1

  • Bhattacharya K, Mukherjee G, Sarämaki J, Kaski K, Manna S (2007b) The international trade network: weighted network analsys and modeling. arxiv:0707.4343v1

  • Bollobás B (1985) Random graphs. Academic, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Breiger R (1981) Structure of economic interdependence among nations. In: Blau PM, Merton RK (eds) Continuities in structural inquiry. Sage, Newbury Park, pp 353–380

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrington P, Scott J, Wasserman S (eds) (2005) Models and methods in social network analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dall’Asta L, Barrat A, Barthélemy M, Vespignani A (2006) Vulnerability of weighted networks. arxiv:physics/0603163v1

  • De Nooy W, Mrvar A, Batagelj V (2005) Exploratory social network analysis with Pajek. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • DeMontis A, Barthélemy M, Chessa A, Vespignani A (2005) The structure and evolution of inter-urban traffic: a weighted network analysis. arxiv:physics/0507106v2

  • Dorogovtsev S, Mendes J (2003) Evolution of networks: from biological nets to the internet and WWW. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G (2006) Directed or undirected? A new index to check for directionality of relations in socio-economic networks. Econ Bull 3:1–12. http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/2006/volume3/EB–06Z10134A.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G (2007) Clustering in complex directed networks. Phys Rev E 76:026107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G, Reyes J, Schiavo, S (2007), The evolution of the world trade web. LEM working paper, 2007/17, Sant’Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa

  • Fagiolo G, Schiavo S, Reyes J (2008) On the topological properties of the world trade web: a weighted network analysis. Physica A 387:3868–3873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G, Schiavo S, Reyes J (2009) World-trade web: topological properties, dynamics, and evolution. Phys Rev E 79:036115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher E, Vega-Redondo F (2006) The linchpins of a modern economy. Working paper, Cal Poly

  • Forbes K (2002) Are trade linkages important determinants of country vulnerability to crises? In: Sebastian E, Jeffrey F (eds) Preventing currency crises in emerging markets. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman L (1996) Some antecedents of social network analysis. Connections 19:39–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Furusawa T, Konishi H (2007) Free trade networks. J Int Econ 72:310–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garlaschelli D, Loffredo M (2004a) Fitness-dependent topological properties of the world trade web. Phys Rev Lett 93:188701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garlaschelli D, Loffredo M (2004b) Patterns of link reciprocity in directed networks. Phys Rev Lett 93:268701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garlaschelli D, Loffredo M (2005) Structure and evolution of the world trade network. Physica A 355:138–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch K (2002) Expanded trade and gdp data. J Confl Resolut 46:712–724. http://ibs.colorado.edu/~ksg/trade/

    Google Scholar 

  • Goyal S, Joshi S (2006) Bilateralism and free trade. Int Econ Rev 47:749–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Leij M, Goyal S (2006) Strong ties in a small world. Tinbergen Institute discussion papers 06-008/1, Tinbergen Institute

  • Granovetter M (1974) Getting a job: a study of contracts and careers. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Herfindahl O (1959) Copper costs and prices: 1870–1957. John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman A (1964) The paternity of an index. Am Econ Rev 54:761–762

    Google Scholar 

  • Hojman D, Szeidl A (2008) Core and periphery in networks. J Econ Theory 139:295–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson M (2004) A survey of models of network formation: stability and efficiency. In: Demange G, Wooders M (eds) Group formation in economics; networks, clubs and coalitions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kali R, Reyes J (2009) Financial contagion on the international trade network. Econ Inq (in press)

  • Kali R, Reyes J (2007) The architecture of globalization: a network approach to international economic integration. J Int Bus Stud 38:595–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kali R, Méndez F, Reyes J (2007) Trade structure and economic growth. J Int Trade Econ Dev 16:245–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kastelle T, Steen J, Liesch P (2005) Measurig globalisation: an evolutionary economic approach to tracking the evolution of international trade. Paper presented at the DRUID summer conference on knowledge, innovation and competitiveness: dynamycs of firms, networks, regions and institutions, Copenhagen, Denmark

  • Kim S, Shin EH (2002) A longitudinal analysis of globalization and regionalization in international trade: a social network approach. Soc Forces 81:445–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Jin YY, Chen G (2003) Complexity and synchronization of the world trade web. Physica A 328:287–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahutga MC (2006) The persistence of structural inequality?: a network analysis of international trade, 1965–2000. Soc Forces 84(4):1863–1889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgram S (1967) The small world problem. Psychol Today 2:60–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Nemeth R, Smith D (1985) International trade and world-system structure: a multiple network analysis. Rev J Fernand Braudel Center 8(4):517–560

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman M (2003) The structure and function of complex networks. SIAM Rev 45:167–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman M (2005) A measure of betweenness centrality based on random walks. Soc Netw 27:39–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Onnela J, Saramaki J, Kertész J, Kaski K (2005) Intensity and coherence of motifs in weighted complex networks. Phys Rev E 71:065103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano G, Tabuchi T, Thisse JF (2002) Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int Econ Rev 43:409–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padgett J, Ansell C (1993) Robust action and the rise of the Medici, 1400–1434. Am J Sociol 98:1259–1319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastos-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2004) Evolution and structure of the internet. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport A, Horvath W (1961) A study of a large sociogram. Behav Sci 6:279–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch J (2001) Business and social networks in international trade. J Econ Lit 39:1177–1203

    Google Scholar 

  • Rauch J, Casella A (2003) Overcoming informational barriers to international resource allocation: prices and ties. Econ J 113(113):21–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz L, Romer P (1991) Economic integration and endogenous growth. Q J Econ 106:531–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacks M, Ventresca M, Uzzi B (2001) Global institutions and networks: contingent change in the structure of world trade advantage, 1965–1980. Am Behav Sci 44(10):1579–1601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saramaki J, Kivelä M, Onnela J, Kaski K, Kertész J (2007) Generalizations of the clustering coefficient to weighted complex networks. Phys Rev E 75:027105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott J (2000) Social network analysis: a handbook. Sage, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Serrano A, Boguñá M (2003) Topology of the world trade web. Phys Rev E 68:015,101(R)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serrano A, Boguñá M, Vespignani A (2007) Patterns of dominant flows in the world trade web. J Econ Interact Coord 2:111–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith D, White D (1992) Structure and dynamics of the global economy: network analysis of international trade, 1965–1980. Soc Forces 70:857–893

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snyder D, Kick E (1979) Structural position in the world system and economic growth 1955–70: a multiple network analysis of transnational interactions. Am J Sociol 84:1096–1126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szabó G, Alava M, Kertész J (2005) Intensity and coherence of motifs in weighted complex networks. Phys Rev E 71:065103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wasserman S, Faust K (1994) Social network analysis. Methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts D (1999) Small worlds. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts D (2003) Six degrees: the science of a connected age. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts D, Strogatz S (1998) Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393:440–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Marc Barthélemy, Diego Garlaschelli, and to an anonymous referee for their useful and insightful comments. All usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giorgio Fagiolo.

Appendix A: Countries in the balanced panel (1981–2000)

Appendix A: Countries in the balanced panel (1981–2000)

The dataset provided by Gleditsch (2002) includes 196 countries for which there are data on trade flows from 1948 to 2000. However, trade data contain many missing (or badly reported) values before 1970. In addition, there are some countries with zero total exports in some years.

Notice also that our analysis requires to match trade data with real GDP (both in levels and per capita). This is because: (i) weights are defined as exports divided by GDP; (ii) one wants to cross-sectionally correlate network measures with country-specific variables like per-capita GDP.

We have therefore selected countries in such a way to have: (i) a time horizon and a country sample size as long as possible; (ii) no missing values in trade data and GDP (both in levels and per capita); (iii) non-zero total exports.

By applying conditions (i) and (ii) we get only 83 countries from 1960–2000. This number becomes 138 for the period 1970–2000; 152 for the period 1970–2000; 163 for the period 1981–2000; and 168 for the period 1990–2000. We thus decided to select the time interval 1981-2000 using 163 countries. However, 4 of them (San Marino, Andorra, Liechtenstein, Monaco) have total exports equal to zero in some years. This leaves us with N = 159 countries, whose list is in Table 2.

Table 2 List of countries in the balanced panel

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fagiolo, G., Reyes, J. & Schiavo, S. The evolution of the world trade web: a weighted-network analysis. J Evol Econ 20, 479–514 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0160-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0160-x

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation