Skip to main content
Log in

Product variety, competition and economic growth

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we study the relationship between competition and economic growth using a model of economic development through the creation of new sectors. In our model, competition has both an intra- and an inter-sector component. We find that the best conditions for economic development are achieved when a suitable ratio of inter- to intra-sector competition is achieved. This ratio constitutes a compromise between providing a temporary monopoly to the first entrepreneur (low inter-sector competition) and creating enough imitation to expand the sector (intra-sector competition).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Agarwal R, Gort M (2001) First mover advantage and the speed of competitive entry, 1887–1986. J Law Econ 44:161–177 (April)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Griffith R (2005) Competition and growth, reconciling theory and evidence. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2):323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (2005) Appropriate growth policy: a unifying framework, 2005 Schumpeter lecture. In: the XXth Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Amsterdam, August 25 (2005). Available at: http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/aghion/papers.html

  • Allen PM (1988) Evolution, innovation and economics. In: Dosi G, Freeman C, Nelson R, Silverberg G, Soete L (eds) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen P, Strathern M, Baldwin J (2006) Evolution, diversity and organization. In: Garnsey E, Mc Glade J (eds) Complexity and co-evolution. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow JK (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources to invention. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Panzar JC, Willig RD (1982) Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. Harcourt, Brace Jovanovich, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaug M (2001) Is competition such a good thing? Static efficiency versus dynamic efficiency. Rev Ind Organ 19:37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen M, Levinthal D (1989) Innovating and learning: the two faces of R&D. Econ J 99:569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, David PA (1994) Towards a new economics of science. Res Policy 23(5):487–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Stiglitz JE (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 67:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Fabiani S, Aversi R, Meacci M (1994) The dynamics of international differentiation: a multi-country model. Ind Corp Change 3:225–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Llerena P, Sylos Labini M (2005) Science–technology–industry links and the “European paradox”: some notes on the dynamics of scientific and technological Research in Europe. LEM working paper series, no. 2005-2. Available at: http://www.lem.sssup.it/WPLem/files/2005-02.pdf

  • Etkowitz H, Leydesdorff L (eds) (1997) Universities in the global knowledge economy: a co-evolution of university–industry–government relations. Cassel, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J (2000) Technological progress, structural change and productivity growth: a comparative study. Working paper no. 5/2000. Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, Oslo

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J, Verspagen B (1999) Productivity, R&D spillovers and trade. Working paper no. 3/1999. Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, Oslo

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman C, Soete L (1997) The economics of industrial innovation. Pinter, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Funke M, Ruhwedel R (2001a) Product variety and economic growth: empirical evidence for the OECD countries. IMF Staff Pap 48(2):225–242

    Google Scholar 

  • Funke M, Ruhwedel R (2001b) Export variety and export performance: empirical evidence from East Asia. J Asian Econ 12:493–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons M, Limoges C, Nowotny H, Schwartzmann S, Scott P, Trow M (1994) The new production of knowledge—the dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies. Sage, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Quality ladder and product cycles. Q J Econ 106:557–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haken H (1983) Synergetics. Springer, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe AB (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R & D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. Am Econ Rev 76(5):984–1001 (Dec)

    Google Scholar 

  • Klügl F (2008) A validation methodology for agent-based simulations, In: Proceedings of Applied Computing 2008, Fortaleza, Brazil

  • Kwasnicki W (1996) Knowledge, innovation, and economy. An evolutionary exploration. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster KJ (1975) Socially optimal product differentiation. Am Econ Rev 65:567–585

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster KJ (1979) Variety, equity and efficiency. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster KJ (1990) The economics of product variety: a survey. Mark Sci 9:189–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey RG, Carlaw KI, Bekar CT (2005) Economic transformations. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson RR, Orsenigo L, Winter S (1999) History friendly models of industry evolution: the case of computer industry. Ind Corp Change 8:3–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS, Foster J, Ramlogan R (2005) Adaptive economic growth. Camb J Econ 30:7–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. J Polit Econ 67:297–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolis G, Prigogine I (1989) Exploring complexity. Freeman, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti LL (1981) Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti LL (1993) Structural economic dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell W, Koput KW, Smith-Doerr L (1996) Inter-organisational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology. Adm Sci Q 41:116–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pyka A (1997) Informal networking. Technovation 17:207–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pyka A, Fagiolo F (2007) Agent-based modelling: a methodology for neo-Schumpeterian economics. In: Hanusch H, Pyka A (eds) The Elgar companion to neo-Schumpeterian economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp 467–487

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1987) Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. Am Econ Rev 77:565–562

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technical progress. J Polit Econ 98:71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter WEG (1960) Productivity and technical change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti PP (1996) Technological evolution, variety and the economy. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar

  • Saviotti PP, Metcalfe JS (1984) A theoretical approach to the construction of technological output indicators. Res Policy 13:141–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti P-P, Pyka A (2004a) Economic development by the creation of new sectors. J Evol Econ 14(1):1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti P-P, Pyka A (2004b) Economic development, qualitative change and employment creation. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 15(3):265–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti P-P, Pyka A (2004c) Industrial sectors as interacting populations of firms in economic development. Rev Econ 55(6):1023–1049

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti P-P, Pyka A (2005) Micro and macro dynamics: industry life cycles, inter-sector coordination, co-evolution and aggregate growth. In: Proceedings of the Brisbane Club Workshop, University of Queensland, Brisbane, July 2005

  • Saviotti PP, Pyka A (2006) On the co-evolution of technologies and Financial institutions: economic evolution at the edge of chaos. In: Proceedings of the Workshop “complex behavior in economics: modeling, computing, and mastering complexity” Aix en Provence (Marseilles), France, May 17–21, 2006

  • Saviotti PP, Frenken K (2008) Export variety and the economic performance of countries. J Evol Econ. DOI 10.1007/s00191-007-0081-5

  • Saviotti PP, Mani G (1995) Competition, variety and technological evolution: a replicator dynamics model. J Evol Econ 5:369–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA (original edition 1912)

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Verspagen B (1994) Collective learning, innovation and growth in a boundedly rational, evolutionary world. J Evol Econ 4:207–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windrum P, Birchenhall C (1998) Is product life cycle a special case? Dominant designs and the emergence of market niches through co-evolutionary learning. Struct Change Econ Dyn 9:109–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pier Paolo Saviotti.

Additional information

Andreas Pyka currently also is Visiting Professor at the TU Delft, The Netherlands.

Appendix

Appendix

Simulation models usually include a set of parameters, which have to be specified numerically for different experiments. The behavior of a system can be crucially influenced by specific parameter settings and, therefore, sensitivity analyses become necessary in order to test the robustness of the model (Pyka and Fagiolo 2007). As our model does not include any stochastic variables, all results are completely deterministic, which makes Monte Carlo-simulations unnecessary. However, the results may be valid only in certain ranges of parameters and their combinations. In Saviotti and Pyka (2004c) we gave a detailed sensitivity analysis of different parameter combinations and tested the results for qualitative changes. Those tests showed that the corridors in the parameter space of our model where economic development is possible are relatively broad. The choice of the parameter values is based on expert validations (Klügl 2008) derived from the literature on structural change and economic growth. To test the robustness of our results, we performed simulation experiments combining extreme parameter combinations for k sef , R II and k IC, respectively, and investigated their impact on the development of the number of firms in the different industries (Figs. 10, 11, and 12).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Sensitivity for parameter combinations of R II and k ic

Fig. 11
figure 11

Sensitivity for parameter combinations of k sef and k ic

Fig. 12
figure 12

Sensitivity for parameter combinations of R II and k sef

In Fig. 10, the number of firms per industry is growing considerably for higher values of k ic without, however, changing the qualitative structure of economic development with respect to the sectoral composition. With a growing importance of inter-industry competition relative to intra-industry competition, as measured by high values for RII, the number of firms falls and the speed of development is slightly reduced. Nevertheless, the cyclical emergence of industries shows up in the overall range of tested parameter values. The speed of sectoral development is positively affected by higher values of k sef in Fig. 11, both for low and high values of k ic , which, as in the sensitivity analysis above, exerts a strong positive effect on the overall number of firms in an industry. In this vein also, the third sensitivity test, displayed in Fig. 12, shows that the qualitative results remain unaffected by simultaneous variations of k sef and R II. Again, the rate of creation of new sectors rises for higher values of k sef , both for high as well as for low values of RII. The higher importance of inter-industry competition relative to intra-industry competition, following higher parameter values for R II, leads to the effect already observed in Fig. 10: a decreasing number of firms in each industry over time. The three sensitivity tests together show that our model remains robust over a large range of parameter values and combinations, and that the results can be considered as solid stylized facts of our model.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Saviotti, P.P., Pyka, A. Product variety, competition and economic growth. J Evol Econ 18, 323–347 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-008-0097-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-008-0097-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation