Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does oil rents dependency reduce the quality of education?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The resource curse hypothesis suggests that resource-rich countries (especially oil-dependent economies) show lower economic growth rate as compared to resource-poor countries. We contribute to this literature by providing empirical evidence on a new transmission channel of the resource curse, namely the negative long-run effect of oil rents on the quality of education. Our empirical analysis for more than 70 countries from the period of 1995–2015 shows a significantly positive effect of oil rents on the quantity of education measured by government spending on primary and secondary education. However, we find a robust and negative long-run effect of oil rents dependency on the objective and subjective indicators of quality of education. Further, panel regressions with country and year fixed effects support our cross-country findings on the negative effect of oil rents dependency on the quality of education.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Resource rents refer to difference between international market price and average unit production costs multiplied by production volume of specific kind of natural resource. Our main analysis is focusing on point resources, e.g., crude oil.

  2. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2016/03/10/education-quality-measuring-learning-outcomes-in-francophone-africas-primary-schools.

  3. We see the same impressive funding of education, when we consider its share of government total spending (16.3% in the MENA vs. 13.9% world average). In addition, educational spending per student at the secondary level (in relation to GDP per capita) is higher in the resource-rich MENA region (19.5%) than in East Asia (14.7%) or Latin America (13.9%).

  4. The literature shows that the curse is in point resources such as oil and gas, which offer significant economic rents (Ross 2012). In this paper, we focus on oil rents dependency.

  5. Davis (1995) sees positive effects of resource rents on schooling, as literacy rates and enrollment are higher in resource-rich countries than in other (developing) countries.

  6. We have also investigated the effect of education spending and the quality of education on the long-run economic growth rates in our sample controlling for other possible drivers of growth. The results are shown in Appendix B Tables 14 and 15. Our cross-country results support the argument of scholars who are questioning the effectiveness of education spending per se on long-term growth. However, we find that there is a robust positive effect of education quality on long-term growth, which is also in line with the findings of Hanushek and Woessmann (2013).

  7. We also re-examine the resource curse hypothesis by regressing the degree of oil dependency in 1990 on the GDP per capita growth rates from 1990 to 2015, controlling for a couple of other growth drivers and regional dummies. The initial dependency on oil rents has a negative and significant effect on the long-term growth rates in our sample, which is in line with resource curse hypothesis (see Table 13 in Appendix B). There is also a line of literature, which argues for positive long-run growth effect of natural resource wealth (see Alexeev and Conrad 2009). Alexeev and Conrad (2011) also find little evidence for the resource curse in a sample of transition countries.

  8. We are not considering the tertiary level of education in our analysis because our main focus is only on the quality of the educational system, which is measured by the secondary level of schooling.

  9. As the World Bank (2017) data on education expenditures is expressed in relation to GDP per capita of a country, we first multiply the government expenditure per student (percentage of GDP per capita) by GDP per capita in the local currency of each country. The outcome is then divided by the PPP conversion factor.

  10. We also control for different indicators of trade and investment openness (trade and net inflow of FDI as a share of GDP and KOF economic globalization index) in both quantity and quality of education regressions. Due to their mostly insignificant effects, we have dropped them from the analysis. Our main results on the education–oil nexus are not sensible to inclusion or exclusion of the trade and FDI indicators. (Results are available upon request.)

  11. Kaarsen (2014) uses data from various TIMSS rounds from 1995, 1999, 2003, 2007, and 2011. Some countries such as the USA have participated in all rounds and some others only in few of them. The downside of using these data is that we cannot conduct a panel data analysis, as the Kaarsen index is available only as a cross section.

  12. http://reports.weforum.org/global-competitiveness-report-2015-2016/.

  13. The report is available at: http://unesdoc.unesco.org/images/0017/001776/177683e.pdf.

  14. The mean VIF for Model 3.7 is under the critical level of 10 (9.31). However, the VIF for the logarithm of government spending—per student at the secondary and primary levels—and the logarithm of GDP per capita show VIF of above 10.

  15. The role of some dimensions of governance such as corruption and rent seeking for the effectiveness of education spending is examined by Rogers (2008).

  16. We have also used the average test score in math and science (primary through the end of secondary school, all years, 1964–2003), which is used in Hanushek and Woessmann (2013), as our index of education quality. The negative effect of oil rents remains robust in most specifications.

  17. For more details on robust regressions, see http://stats.idre.ucla.edu/stata/dae/robust-regression/.

  18. The result is obtained by first multiplying the absolute value of the coefficient 0.010 associated with the individual effect of oil rents dependency by the within-country standard deviation of oil rents 2.7 and then by dividing the product by the within-country standard deviation of WEF quality of education 0.26 (− 0.01 * 2.7/0.26 = −0.10).

  19. World Values Survey (Wave 6 2010–2014) Official aggregate v.20150418. World Values Survey Association (www.worldvaluessurvey.org).

  20. Because of this effect, the literature suggests that higher resource rents can reduce the income gap between the rich and the poor in the short term (Goderis and Malone 2011).

  21. The direct relevance of institutions for the allocation of talent is examined empirically by Natkhov and Polishchuk (2012).

  22. Farzanegan (2014b) also shows that rent dependency leads to a low prevalence of entrepreneurship.

  23. Other regional dummies turn out to be insignificant when included.

References

  • Al Riyami A, Al Hammadi N, Al Marzouqi O, Al Neyadi N, Jamil S, Al Mansoori S, Hodgson S (2015) Ghost employees: the impact of emiratization quotas. Middle East J Bus 10:65–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Easterly W (1998) Redistributive public employment. J Urban Econ 48:219–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alexeev M, Conrad R (2009) The elusive curse of oil. Rev Econ Stat 91:586–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alexeev M, Conrad R (2011) The natural resource curse and economic transition. Econ Syst 35:445–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altinok N, Kingdon G (2012) New evidence on class size effects: a pupil fixed effects approach. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 74:203–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altinok N, Murseli H (2007) International database on human capital quality. Econ Lett 96:237–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arezki R, Gylfason T (2013) Resource rents, democracy and corruption: evidence from sub-Saharan Africa. J Afr Econ 22:552–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auty RM (2001) Resource abundance and economic development. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin-Edwards M (2011) Labour immigration and labour markets in the GCC countries: national patterns and trends. Research paper no. 15, Kuwait Programme on Development, Governance and Globalisation in the Gulf States

  • Barro RJ (1991) Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Q J Econ 106:407–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Spiegel MM (1994) The role of human capital in economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J Monetary Econ 34:143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benos N, Zotou S (2014) Education and economic growth: a meta-regression analysis. World Dev 64:669–689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birdsall N, Pinckney T, Sabot R (2001) Natural resources, human capital, and growth. In: Auty RM (ed) Resource abundance and economic growth. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 57–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjorvatn K, Farzanegan MR (2013) Demographic transition in resource rich countries: a blessing or a curse? World Dev 45:337–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjorvatn K, Farzanegan MR (2015) Resource rents, balance of power, and political stability. J Peace Res 52:758–773

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjorvatn K, Farzanegan MR, Schneider F (2012) Resource curse and power balance: evidence from oil rich countries. World Dev 40:1308–1316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colclough C (1982) The impact of primary schooling on economic development: a review of the evidence. World Dev 10:167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis GA (1995) Learning to love the Dutch disease: evidence from the mineral economies. World Dev 23:1765–1779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhuey E, Smith J (2018) How school principals influence student learning. Empir Econ 54:851–882

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dizaji SF, Farzanegan MR, Naghavi A (2016) Political institutions and government spending behavior: theory and evidence from Iran. Int Tax Public Finance 23:522–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyer P, Kherfi A (2016) Gulf youth and the labor market. In: Sayre EA, Yousef TM (eds) Young generation awakening—economics, society, and policy on the eve of the Arab Spring. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 88–109

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ebeke C, Omgba LD, Laajaj R (2015) Oil governance and the (mis)allocation of talent in developing countries. J Dev Econ 114:126–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farzanegan MR (2011) Oil revenues shocks and government spending behavior in Iran. Energy Econ 33:1055–1069

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farzanegan MR (2014a) Military spending and economic growth: the case of Iran. Def Peace Econ 25:247–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farzanegan MR (2014b) Can oil-rich countries encourage entrepreneurship? Entrep Reg Dev 26:706–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glewwe P, Maïga E, Zheng H (2014) The contribution of education to economic growth: a review of the evidence, with special attention and an application to Sub-Saharan Africa. World Dev 59:379–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goderis B, Malone SW (2011) Natural resource booms and inequality: theory and evidence. Scand J Econ 113:388–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta S, Davoodi H, Tiongson E (2001) Corruption and the provision of health care and education services. In: Jain AK (ed) The political economy of corruption. Routledge, London, pp 111–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Gylfason T (2001) Natural resources, education, and economic development. Eur Econ Rev 45:847–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (1997) Assessing the effects of school resources on student performance: an update. Educ Eval Policy Anal 19:141–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (2005) The economics of school quality. German Econ Rev 6:269–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (2013) Economic growth in developing countries: the role of human capital. Econ Educ Rev 37:204–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Kimko DD (2000) Schooling, labor-force quality, and the growth of nations. Am Econ Rev 90:1184–1208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Woessmann L (2008) The role of cognitive skills in economic development. J Econ Lit 46:607–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Woessmann L (2013) Do better schools lead to more growth? Cognitive skills, economic outcomes, and causation. J Econ Growth 17:267–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Woessmann L (2015) The economic impact of educational quality. In: Dixon P, Humble S, Counihan C (eds) Handbook of international development and education. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp 6–19

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hodler R (2006) The curse of natural resources in fractionalized countries. Eur Econ Rev 50:1367–1386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • James A (2017) Natural resources and education outcomes in the United States. Resour Energy Econ 49:150–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamison EA, Jamison DT, Hanushek EA (2007) The effects of education quality on income growth and mortality decline. Econ Educ Rev 26:771–788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaarsen N (2014) Cross-country differences in the quality of schooling. J Dev Econ 107:215–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koyame-Marsh RO (2016) Saudization and the Nitaqat programs: overview and performance. J Account Finance Econ 6:36–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Le TM, Devarajan S, Raballand G (2010) Increasing public expenditure efficiency in oil-rich economies: a proposal. The World Bank policy research working paper no. 5287, Washington DC

  • Lee JW, Barro RJ (2001) Schooling quality in a cross section of countries. Economica 38:465–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessmann C, Steinkraus A (2017) The geography of natural resources, ethnic inequality and development. CESifo working paper no. 6299

  • Levin H (1983) Youth unemployment and its educational consequences. Educ Eval Policy Anal 5:231–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehlum H, Moene K, Torvik R (2006) Institutions and the resource course. Econ J 116:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Natkhov T, Polishchuk L (2012) Institutions and the allocation of talent. HSE working papers WP BRP 15/EC/2012, National Research University Higher School of Economics, Moscow

  • Pritchett L (2001) Where has all the education gone? World Bank Econ Rev 15:367–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridge N (2010) Teacher quality, gender and nationality in the United Arab Emirates; a crisis for boys. Working paper no. 10-06, Dubai School of Government

  • Ridge N, Shami S, Kippels S (2015) Arab migrant teachers in the United Arab Emirates and Qatar: challenges and opportunities. In: Arab migrant communities in the GCC, summary report no. 12, Center for International and Regional Studies, Georgetown University School of Foreign Service in Qatar

  • Robinson JA, Torvik R, Verdier T (2006) Political foundations of the resource curse. J Dev Econ 79:447–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers ML (2008) Directly unproductive schooling: how country characteristics affect the impact of schooling on growth. Eur Econ Rev 52:356–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross M (2012) The oil curse: how petroleum wealth shapes the development of nations. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs J, Warner A (2001) Natural resources and economic development—the curse of natural resources. Eur Econ Rev 45:827–838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayre EA, Hendy R (2016) The effects of education and marriage on young women’s labor force participation in the Middle East and North Africa. In: Sayre EA, Yousef TM (eds) Young generation awakening—economics, society, and policy on the eve of the Arab Spring. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 72–87

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Stijns J (2006) Natural resource abundance and human capital accumulation. World Dev 34:1060–1083

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sylwester K (2002) Can education expenditures reduce income inequality? Econ Educ Rev 21:43–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi V, Chu K (1998) Income distribution and high quality growth. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • UNESCO (2009) EFA global monitoring report—overcoming inequality: why governance matters. http://unesdoc.unesco.org/images/0017/001776/177683e.pdf. Accessed 28 Aug 2018

  • van Wijnbergen S (1984) Inflation, employment, and the Dutch disease in oil exporting countries: a short-run disequilibrium analysis. Q J Econ 99:233–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woessmann L, West M (2006) Class-size effects in school systems around the world: evidence from between-grade variation in TIMSS. Eur Econ Rev 50:695–736

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2015) The World Bank annual report 2015. Washington D.C. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/22550/WBAnnualReport2015EN.pdf. Accessed 28 Aug 2018

  • World Bank (2016) Education quality: measuring learning outcomes in Francophone Africa’s primary schools, Washington, D.C. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2016/03/10/education-quality-measuring-learning-outcomes-in-francophone-africas-primary-schools. Accessed 28 Aug 2018

  • World Bank (2017) World development indicators. Washington, D.C. http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators. Accessed 28 Aug 2018

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the anonymous referees, participants and discussants at the 23rd International Congress of the German Middle East Studies Association (2016, Tübingen); Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society (2016, Freiburg); International Iran Forum (2017, Marburg); 11th Workshop on Political Economy (2017, Dresden); and 3rd Turkish-German Frontiers of Social Science Symposium (2017, Berlin) for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this study.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mohammad Reza Farzanegan.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Appendices

Appendix A

See Tables 9, 10, 11, and 12.

Table 9 List of 94 countries included in Table 1 (Model 1.3) example of education spending for secondary school
Table 10 List of 72 countries included in Table 3 (Model 3.8)—quality of education (Kaarsen index)
Table 11 List of 123 countries included in Table 4 (Model 4.8)—quality of education (WEF index)
Table 12 Data description and sources

Appendix B

2.1 Resource curse in our sample of analysis

The resource curse hypothesis states that countries that are more dependent on resource rents (in most cases, this is oil) experience lower economic growth rates in the long term compared to countries with lower initial dependency on rents. To (re-)test this hypothesis, we consider the effects of oil rents dependency in 1990 on GDP per capita growth rates from 1990 to 2015, controlling for other possible drivers of growth in 1990. These control variables are trade openness ([import + exports]/GDP); foreign aid (percentage of GNI); domestic capital formation (percentage of GDP) as a proxy for the domestic investment rate; foreign direct investment (FDI, percentage of GDP); the fertility rate and a dummy for the East Asian and Pacific region.Footnote 23 All variables are from the World Bank (2017).

We follow a specific to general approach in our specification, starting in Model 1 with oil rents only. There is a negative and significant effect of oil rents in 1990 on the long-run growth rates, supporting the resource curse hypothesis. Only in Model 7, when also controlling for fertility, the negative significance of oil rents vanishes. However, the statistical significance of oil rents in growth returns in Model 8 where we exclude the insignificant variables of Model 7 (see Table 13).

Table 13 Resource curse: oil rents and long-run growth rates across countries

2.2 Long-run growth, education spending and education quality

We investigate the effects of government spending on education and of education quality [using the measure by Kaarsen (2014)] on long-run growth (Table 14). There is a positive effect of education quality and a negative effect of education spending on growth.

Table 14 Education spending, education quality, and long-run growth rates

In the following table (Table 15), we use the logarithm of government spending per student at the secondary level schooling (PPP adjusted) instead of government spending on education (percentage of GDP). The overall results do not change.

Table 15 Education spending per student (secondary level), education quality, and long-run growth rates

2.3 Using International database on human capital quality (Altinok and Murseli 2007)

See Table 16.

Table 16 Education quality and oil rents

2.4 Robust regression: examining the effect of outliers or influential observations

See Tables 17 and 18.

Table 17 Robust regression: re-examining Model 3.8 from Table 3
Table 18 Robust regression: re-examining Model 4.9 from Table 4

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Farzanegan, M.R., Thum, M. Does oil rents dependency reduce the quality of education?. Empir Econ 58, 1863–1911 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1548-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1548-y

Keywords

Navigation