Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The effect of nonreciprocal preferential trade agreements on benefactors’ exports

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Over the last decades, developed countries have provided developing countries with preferential market access via trade policies in the form of nonreciprocal preferential trade agreements (NRPTAs). Despite the lack of reciprocity of this kind of agreements, certain criteria for designating eligible countries refer to the commercial interests of benefactor countries. This paper examines for the first time the effect of NRPTAs on benefactors’ exports to beneficiary countries. Using recent developments in the econometric analysis of the gravity equation, we find robust evidence that nonreciprocal agreements have had an economically significant effect on exports not only for beneficiary countries but also for benefactor countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the list of NRPTAs and when they entered into force, see Gil-Pareja et al. (2014).

  2. In a recent survey on panel econometric methods to gravity modeling, Baltagi et al. (2015, p. 610) note that “even an analysis of a cross-section of county pairs (based on a single year s or an average across several years) in essence involves panel data, ...”. As these authors point out, Pöyhönen (1963) is probably the first to control for country-specific fixed effects in cross-sectional data.

  3. The exporter and importer effects capture all time-invariant observable and unobservable country characteristics. These effects could either be treated as fixed (Mátyás 1997) or as random (Mátyás 1998) and being part of the error term. Egger (2000) shows that the fixed-effects model is the right choice on conceptual and econometric grounds. Time effects control for common shocks and trend shared by all countries. They are treated as fixed.

  4. The bilateral effects control for the impact of any time-invariant determinant of trade (observed or not).

  5. Baltagi et al. (2003) propose for the first time the inclusion of fixed exporter-time and importer-time effects. As they point out, these effects are included to capture country-specific time-varying effects like the exporter (importer) country’s business cycle, its cultural, political or institutional characteristics and unobserved factor endowment variables.

  6. Baldwin and Taglioni (2006) generalize Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) framework (which is limited to cross-section data), to allow for panel data and then show that multilateral resistance terms can be dealt with using country-and-time dummies (it, jt) with omitted determinants of bilateral trade being dealt with by time-invariant bilateral dummies.

  7. In this paper we estimate partial (or direct) effects, not general equilibrium effects as in Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), Baier and Bergstrand (2009), Egger and Larch (2011), and Bergstrand et al. (2013).

  8. We use data at four-year intervals as Bergstrand et al. (2013) and Gil-Pareja et al. (2014) do and akin to Chen and Wall (2005), Baier and Bergstrand (2007), Subramanian and Wei (2007), Eicher and Henn (2011a, b), Beahr and Cirera-i-Crivillé (2013) and Kohl (2014) use of data for every five years. The use of this kind of data addresses the concern raised by Chen and Wall (2005, p. 52): “Fixed-effects estimation is sometimes criticized when applied to data pooled over consecutive years on the grounds that dependent and independent variables cannot fully adjust in a single year’s time.”

  9. The sample considered by Bergstrand et al. (2013) only includes 41 trading partners and four years (1990, 1994, 1998 and 2002), which allow them to use the first approach. The large datasets considered by Baier et al. (2014) and Gil-Pareja et al. (2014) preclude to estimate that specification since the huge number of fixed effects required is beyond the capability of commonly used statistical software. The same applies for this paper.

  10. In this study we use the expression “preferential trade agreement” to also refer to other agreements involving a higher degree of economic integration. In fact, most economic integration agreements considered in the sample are free trade agreements.

  11. See, http://www.agoa.gov/eligibility/country_eligibility.html for membership in AGOA and http://ec.europa.eu/trade/wider-agenda/development/generalised-system-of-preferences/everything-but-arms for EBA.

  12. http://ec.europa.eu/trade/wider-agenda/development/economic-partnerships.

  13. The index is defined as: (% Protestants in country i * % Protestants in country j) + (% Catholics in country i * % Catholics in country j) + (% Muslims in Country i * % Muslims in country j).

  14. The Wald test rejects, at the 10 % level of significance, the null hypothesis of equality between the estimated coefficients for XNRPTA and MNRPTA.

  15. These authors argue that countries likely select endogenously into free trade agreements (FTA) and that the most plausible estimates for the effect of an FTA on trade are obtained using panel data with bilateral fixed effects (or differenced panel data) and country-and-time fixed effects.

  16. This result is consistent with that provided by Eicher and Henn (2011a, b) who find smaller estimated coefficients when they add unobserved bilateral heterogeneity controls. In contrast, Baier and Bergstrand (2007) find a larger estimated coefficient for free trade agreements accounting for both country-and-time fixed effects and country-pair fixed effects (0.48) than using OLS with time dummies (0.27).

  17. In the random effects specification the country-pair effects are considered as part of the error term. The main drawback of this specification lies in its restrictive exogeneity assumption because, if there is correlation between the covariates and the country-pair effects, parameter estimates with the random effects model are biased and inconsistent, while the fixed country-pair effects estimator is immune to the potential problem of correlation.

  18. In the specifications with lags we report the sum of the estimated coefficients from current and lagged values.

  19. The first difference approach clearly reveals the importance of incorporating lagged effects. The results with first-differenced data without accounting for lagged effects (not reported) show that only the variable of interest presents a coefficient estimate that is positive (0.091) and statistically significant at least at the 5 per cent level of significance. Moreover, the coefficient of the variable PTA is 0.062 (statistically significant at the 10 per cent level), whereas neither CU, GATT/WTO nor XNRPTA dummies have positive significant effects at conventional levels. This result is in line with Kohl (2014, p. 453) who finds, using first differences with data at five-year intervals over the period 1950–2010, that the impact of economic integration agreements on trade is only statistically significant when allowing for phase-in periods with lags. In particular, he finds a positive (0.058) but statistically insignificant coefficient estimate without lags and a cumulative treatment effect equal to 0.39 with two lags.

  20. Baier et al. (2014) do not consider currency unions or membership in GATT/WTO in their analysis of the effects of various types of economic integration agreements on trade flows and trade margins.

  21. Monte Carlo simulations lead Head and Mayer (2013, p. 50) to conclude that “While Poisson PML has many virtues... it should not replace OLS as the new workhorse estimator of gravity equations. Rather, Poisson PML should be used as part of a robustness-exploring ensemble...”

  22. Since the Poisson estimator did not achieve convergence including time-varying fixed effects in addition to country-pair fixed effects, in the regressions with pair effects we include instead GDPs.

References

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier SL, Bergstrand JH (2007) Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? J Int Econ 71(1):72–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier SL, Bergstrand JH (2009) Bonus vetus OLS: a simple method for approximating international trade-costs effects using the gravity equation. J Int Econ 77(1):77–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier L, Bergstrand JH, Egger P, McLaughlin P (2008) Do economic integration agreements actually work? Issues in understanding the causes and consequences of growth of regionalism. World Econ 31(4):461–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier L, Bergstrand JH, Feng M (2014) Economic integration agreements and the margins of international trade. J Int Econ 93(2):339–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Taglioni D (2006) Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity equations. NBER WP No 12516

  • Baltagi BH, Egger P, Pfaffermayr M (2003) A generalized design for bilateral trade flows models. Econ Lett 80(3):391–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH, Egger P, Pfaffermayr M (2015) Panel data models of international trade. In: Baltagi BH (ed) The oxford handbook of panel data. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 608–641

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Beahr A, Cirera-i-Crivillé L (2013) Does it matter who you sign with? Comparing the impacts of north–south and south–south trade agreements on bilateral trade. Rev Int Econ 21(4):765–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand JH, Egger P, Larch M (2013) Gravity redux: estimation of gravity-equation coefficients, elasticities of substitution and general equilibrium comparative statics under asymmetric bilateral trade costs. J Int Econ 89(1):110–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand JH, Larch M, Yotov YV (2013) Economic integration agreements, border effects, and distance elasticities in the gravity equation. CESIfo Working Paper No 4502

  • Chen IH, Wall JW (2005) Controlling for heterogeneity in gravity models of trade and integration. Fed Reserve Bank St. Louis Rev 87(1):49–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt P, Mihov I, Van Zandt T (2013) The effect of WTO on the extensive and the intensive margins of trade. J Int Econ 91(2):204–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P (2000) A note on the proper econometric specification of the gravity equation. Econ Lett 66(1):25–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P (2001) European exports and outward foreign direct investment: a dynamic panel data approach. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 137(3):427–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P (2004) Estimating regional trading bloc effects with panel data. Rev World Econ 140(1):151–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P, Pfaffermayr M (2003) The proper panel econometric specification of the gravity equation: a three way model with bilateral interactions effects. Empir Econ 28(3):571–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger P, Larch M (2011) An assessment of the Europe agreements’ effects on bilateral trade, GDP, and welfare. Eur Econ Rev 55(2):263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eicher TS, Henn C (2011a) In search of WTO trade effects: preferential trade agreements promote trade strongly, but unevenly. J Int Econ 83(2):137–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eicher TS, Henn C (2011b) One money, one market—a revisited benchmark. Rev Int Econ 19(3):419–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr G, Kohler W (2010) Modelling the extensive margin of world trade: new evidence on GATT and WTO membership. World Econ 33(11):1430–1469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fugazza M, Nicita A (2013) The direct and relative effects of preferential market access. J Int Econ 89(2):357–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Pareja S, Llorca-Vivero R, Martínez-Serrano JA (2008a) Assessing the enlargement and deepening of the European Union. World Econ 31(9):1253–1272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Pareja S, Llorca-Vivero R, Martínez-Serrano JA (2008b) Trade effects of monetary unions: evidence from OECD countries. Eur Econ Rev 52(4):733–755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Pareja S, Llorca-Vivero R, Martínez-Serrano JA (2014) Do nonreciprocal preferential trade agreements increase beneficiaries’ exports. J Dev Econ 107(March):291–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glick R, Rose AK (2002) Does a currency union affect trade? The time series evidence. Eur Econ Rev 46(6):1125–1151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2013) Gravity equations: workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. CEPII Working Paper No 27

  • Head K, Mayer T, Ries J (2010) The erosion of colonial trade linkages after independence. J Int Econ 81(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herz B, Wagner M (2011) The real impact of GATT/WTO—a generalised approach. World Econ 34(6):1014–1041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohl T (2014) Do we really know that trade agreements increase trade? Rev World Econ 150(3):443–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu X (2009) GATT/WTO promotes trade strongly. Sample selection and model specification. Rev Int Econ 17(3):428–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mátyás L (1997) Proper econometric specification of the gravity model. World Econ 20(3):363–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mátyás L (1998) The gravity model. Some econometric considerations. World Econ 21(3):397–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pöyhönen P (1963) A tentative model for the volume of trade between countries. Weltwirtschaftliches Arhiv 90(1):92–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva JMC, Tenreyro S (2006) The log of gravity. Rev Econ Stat 88(4):641–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian A, Wei SW (2007) The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly. J Int Econ 72(1):151–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1962) Shaping the world economy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge J (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This study is part of a research project financed by Ministerio de Economía y Competitividad (project ECO2012-38040, in part-founded by the European Regional Development Fund) and Generalitat Valenciana (PROMETEOII/2014-053). The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Salvador Gil-Pareja.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gil-Pareja, S., Llorca-Vivero, R. & Martínez-Serrano, J.A. The effect of nonreciprocal preferential trade agreements on benefactors’ exports. Empir Econ 52, 143–154 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1071-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1071-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation