Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Going clubbing in the eighties: convergence in manufacturing sectors at a glance

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper employs the distribution dynamics framework for assessing labour productivity convergence, in the period 1980–1995, among 28 developed and developing countries, in different manufacturing compartments, identified as according to their research and development intensity. Three competing hypotheses are considered: absolute, conditional and club convergence. The key result of the analysis is twofold. First, consistently with very recent evidence, absolute convergence is found in manufacturing as a whole. Second, convergence tendencies are sector specific. In particular, club convergence characterizes traditional and medium- technology compartments, while the absolute one qualifies high-tech productions. Overall, these findings support the view that cross-country labour productivity convergence might be hindered by the sub-optimal structural reallocation from nonconvergence to convergence activities. Moreover, as the clustering dynamics in traditional and medium-tech sectors is related either to physical capital stock or technological development, laggard economies should purse ad hoc catching-up strategies. Finally, the result of high tech provides supportive evidence for the theory of dynamic comparative advantages. Thus, it seems desirable that emerging countries enter into technology-intense markets and that they develop the necessary capabilities for exploiting such endogenous advantages.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Islam (2003) and Durlauf et al. (2005) for authoritative reviews on convergence.

  2. For an exhaustive review on the different convergence hypotheses and the so-called controversy on convergence, in its theoretical foundations and empirical assessments, see the articles of Durlauf (1996), Bernard and Jones (1996b), Galor (1996), Quah (1996b) and Sala-i Martin (1996), all collected in The Economic Journal Vol. 106, No. 437.

  3. See again Islam (2003) and Durlauf et al. (2005) for review.

  4. It might be useful to know that the larger time-series and cross-sectional dimensions which characterize Dal Bianco (2010b) is due to the choice of relying on investment rates in physical capital (i.e. gross fixed capital formation to manufacturing value-added ratio) rather than on the estimation of physical capital stock, which is a data-thirsty process. See Data Appendix and next paragraph’s discussion for further details.

  5. The inclusion of the development stage dummy is inspired by Quah (1996a), which includes a dummy for Africa in its cross-sectional analysis. The underlying idea being the attempt of purging out some common but time-invariant factors that characterize laggard countries.

  6. See Rogers (2003) for a detailed review on technological diffusion models, Nelson and Winter (1982) and Cohen and Levinthal (1989, 1990) for seminal contributions on absorption capabilities.

  7. Gemmell (1996) shows that economic growth in middle-income countries, which are well represented in the sample here considered, is strongly related to secondary rather than to primary and tertiary education.

  8. In particular, Lall (2000) technological taxonomy was originally developed employing the Standard International Trade Classification (i.e. SITC) (Revision 2). Thanks to Eurostat tables, which put in correspondence ISIC Revision 2 with ISIC Revision 3, SITC Revision 2 with SITC Revision 3 and, finally, SITC Revision 3 with ISIC Revision 3, is then possible to obtain a 1-to-1 relation between UNIDO data and Lall’s manufacturing sectors.

  9. See Rodrik (2013, p. 184) for details.

  10. See the Data Appendix for further details on the variables employed.

  11. Stochastic kernels were estimated through STATA and MATLAB. All programs are available from the author upon request.

  12. See Stockey et al. (1989), Luenberger (1979).

  13. Following Desmet and Fafchamps (2006), the support of \(Y\) has been made discrete only for calculating the ergodic distribution and not for computing the joint and marginal distributions as in Quah (1996a). This is for better exploiting the smoothing properties of the kernel estimators.

  14. To save some space, the corresponding figures have not been reported but they are available upon request.

  15. Due to space reasons, sector-specific conditional density functions estimated through stochastic kernels are not reported. They are all available in the working paper version of the present work: Dal Bianco (2010a), Figures 3–16.

  16. As tests’ results reported in Table 4 are clear cut, they will not be commented further. The interested reader can refer for more details to the section on Statistical inference of the Appendix on distribution dynamics.

  17. The coefficient of variation (i.e. standard deviation divided by the mean) is the preferred measure of cross-sectional dispersion because this indicator overcomes the problems related to a changing mean.

  18. Author’s calculations based on INDSTAT3, UNIDO Industrial Statistics Database 2004.

  19. More formally, technological (capital) club convergence result refers to the stochastic kernel conditioned to steady state variables and initial technology (physical capital).

  20. UNCTAD (2005, 2001) show that top 50 world MNCs have been investing in High-Technology industries, while top 50 developing countries’ MNCs, 33 of which are from South Asia, operate in Low-Technology and service sectors. United Nations Food and Agricultural Organization (i.e. FAO) documents, instead, the mechanization of farm product processing, FAO (2006).

  21. Author’s calculations based on UNIDO Industrial Statistics Database 2004.

  22. More precisely Dollar and Wolff (1988) study 13 industrialized countries from 1963 to 1982, distinguishing manufacturing industries into “heavy, medium and light”, while Carree et al. (2000) analyse manufacturing sectors in 28 OECD economies, in the period 1972–1992, employing the ISIC 3-digits classification.

  23. To confirm the robustness of absolute convergence prediction, HT labour productivity distributions conditioned to steady state proxies alone and together with capital or technological initial conditions have been used as counterfactuals. As these ergodics are multipeaked, the absolute convergence prediction is validated. For space reasons, these results are not reported, but they are available upon request.

  24. Author’s calculations based on World Bank, World Development Indicators 2010.

  25. More precisely, Brasili et al. (1999) investigate the dynamics of trade patterns of the six largest industrialized countries (i.e. France, Germany, Italy, Japan, UK and USA) and of the old and new Asian Tigers (i.e. Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan; Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines and Thailand).

  26. Although new versions of the PWT have been released, the current exercise relies on PWT 6.1, in order to employ the most robust real GDP estimates in the present context. As recently demonstrated by Johnson et al. (2013), different PWT releases provide different real GDP estimates, despite being derived from very similar underlying data and methodologies. In particular, such a variability is greater the farther the estimate from the benchmark year, at higher data frequencies and for smaller countries. Following this argument, as the data availability is very limited in terms of frequency and country coverage, the robustness of the present exercise can be improved only selecting the closest benchmark year, which is 1996 and it corresponds to PWT 6.1.

  27. Exact literally means that the resulting index is not an approximation. For details, see Diewert (1976) and its result on the use of Tornqvist-Theil approximation to the Divisia index. Flexible is an aggregator function that can provide a second-order approximation to an arbitrary twice differentiable linearly homogeneous function.

  28. This notation implies that only one homogeneous output is produced using only one homogeneous input. For further details on productivity measurement in this simple and more complex environments (i.e. multiple output-multiple input technologies), see Diewert (1992).

  29. This reduced form directly comes from the translog production function with constant returns to scale hypothesis.

  30. The results of the aforementioned tests are not reported but they are available upon request.

  31. Please note that in what follows ‘relative labour productivity’ and ‘labour productivity’ are used interchangeably.

  32. Bivariate stochastic kernel estimation is performed using the command kdens2 in STATA 12. Marginal, conditional and ergodic distributions are calculated in MATLAB. All programs are available from the author upon request.

  33. See Stockey et al. (1989); Luenberger (1979).

  34. To avoid crude ergodic calculations, it is necessary to work with a sufficiently high \(N\). The present calculations have been done for \(\hbox {N}=50\). Using \(\hbox {N}=200\) does not alter any conclusions, but it has the disadvantage of slowing down computer’s routines.

  35. This constraint must hold for the definition of probability

  36. Quoting Quah (1996a), Chamberlain (1984) finds that:

    the projection of growth on investment, not allowing for individual effects, is precisely the best linear predictor and thus correctly gives residuals that are the components unexplained by (or, more correctly, orthogonal to) investment.

  37. As Quah (1996a) explains, this technique exploits the cross-sectional variation of conditioning variables to compute the initial value of productivity explained steady state proxies.

  38. All the mentioned test have been carried using the statistical software STATA.12

  39. In this case, the STATA command “bandw” has been employed.

  40. The STATA routine employed is called “asciker”.

  41. The STATA routine here employed is called “warpdenm”. It is worth recalling that, following Haerdle (1991), the number of averaged shifted histograms used to calculate the required density estimations has been set to 10 and that the Gaussian kernel has been chosen as weight function, i.e. mval(10) and k(6).

  42. The bootstrapped samples have been generated using the STATA command “boot bootsam”, where the routine has been iterated for 50 times and the Silverman optimal bandwith has been used; the Silverman test has been carried employing “silvtest” for an increasing number of modes, and it has stopped following the previously mentioned rule of thumb.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth. J Econ Growth 3(2):111–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsden AH (1989) Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Arslanalp S, Bornhorst F, Gupta S, Sze E (2010) Public capital and growth. IMF Working Paper, WP/10/175

  • Azariadis C, Drazen A (1990) Threshold externalities in economic development. Q J Econ 105(2):501–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis C, Stachurski J (2005) Poverty Traps. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, 1st edn, vol 1, chap 5. Elsevier

  • Bandyopadhyay S (2006) Rich states, poor states: convergence and polarisation in India. Oxford discussion papers, 266

  • Barro RJ (1991) Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Q J Econ 106(2):407–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 19502010. J Dev Econ 104:184–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basile R (2009) Productivity polarization across regions in Europe: the role of nonlinearities and spatial dependence. Int Reg Sci Rev 31:92–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol W (1986) Productivity growth, convergence and welfare: what the long run data show. Am Econ Rev 76(5):1072–1085

    Google Scholar 

  • Benetrix AS, O’Rourke KH, Williamson JG (2012) The spread of manufacturing to the periphery 1870–2007: eight stylized facts. NBER working paper no 18221

  • Bennell P (1996) Rates of return to education: Does the conventional pattern prevail in sub-Saharan Africa? World Dev 24(1):183–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard A, Jones C (1996a) Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement across indutries and countries. Am Econ Rev 86(5):1216–1238

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernard A, Jones C (1996b) Technology and convergence. Econ J 106:1037–1044

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom D, Canning D, Sevilla J (2003) Geography and poverty traps. J Econ Growth 8(4):355–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boheim M, Pfaffermayr M, Gugler K (2000) Do growth rates differ in European manufacturing industries. Austrain Econ Q 2:93–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Brasili A, Epifani P, Helg R (1999) On the dynamics of trade patterns. Liuc papers n. 61, Serie Economia e Impresa, 18

  • Broadberry S (1993) Manufacturing and the convergence hypothesis: what the long-run data show. J Econ History 53(4):772–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno RL, Campos Ferreira N (2011) A systematic review of the effects of foreign direct investment on economic growth in low income countries. Mimeo, DFID

  • Carree MA, Klomp L, Thurik AL (2000) Productivity convergence in OECD manufacturing industries. Econ Lett 66:337–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli F (2005) Accounting for cross-country income differences. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth 1st edn, vol 1, chap 5. Elsevier

  • Caselli F, Esquivel G, Fernando L (1996) Reopening the convergence debate: a new look at cross-country growth empirics. J Econ Growth 1:363–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli F, Wilson DJ (2004) Importing technology. J Monet Econ 51(1):1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves D (1982) Multilateral comparisons of output, input and productivity using superlative index numbers. Econ J 99:73–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves D, Christensen L, Diewert E (1982) The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output and productivity. Econometrica 50(6):1393–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain G (1984) Panel data. In: Hanbook of econometrics, vol 2, pp 1247–1318

  • Chandra V, Kolavalli S (2006) Chandra V (ed) Technology, adaptation, and exports: How some countries got it right, chapter 1 in technology, adaptation and exports. World Bank Publications, Washington

  • Cohen D (1996) Tests of the “convergence hypothesis”: some further results. J Econ Growth 1(3):351–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1989) Innovation and Learning: the two faces of R&D. Econ J 99(397):569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35(1):128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comin D, Hobijn B, Rovito E (2008) Technology usage lags. J Econ Growth 13(4):237–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bianco S (2010a) Going clubbing in the eighties: convergence in manufacturing sectors at a glance. Quaderno di Dipartimento N.258, University of Pavia

  • Dal Bianco S (2010b) New evidence on classical and technological convergence in manufacturing. Rivista Italiana degli Economisti XV(2):305–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Desdoigts A (1999) Patterns of economic development and the formation of clubs. J Econ Growth 4(3):305–330

  • Desmet K, Fafchamps M (2006) Employment concentration across US counties. Regional Science and Urban Economics 36:482–509

  • Diewert E (1976) Exact and superlative index numbers. J Econom 4(2):115–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert E (1992) Fisher ideal output, input, and productivity indexes revisited. J Product Anal 3:211–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Wolff EN (1988) Convergence of industrial labour productivity among advanced economies, 1963–82. Rev Econ Stat 70:549–558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Wolff EN (1993) Competitiveness, convergence and international specialization. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Doucouliagos H, Iamsiraroj S, Ulubasoglu MA (2010) Foreign direct investment and economic growth: a real relationship or wishful thinking? Economics Series 2010 N.14, Deakin University

  • Durlauf SN (1993) Nonergodic economic growth. Rev Econ Stud 60(2):349–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN (1996) On the convergence and divergence of growth rates. Econ J 106(437):1016–1018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA (1995) Multiple regimes and cross-country growth behaviour. J Appl Econom 10:365–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JR (2005) Growth econometrics. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1A. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 555–677

    Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Quah D (1999) The new empirics of economic growth. In: Taylor JB, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol (1.A). North Holland Elsevier Science, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt M, Teal F (2007) Extent and causes of global shifts in manufacturing. Background paper, Centre for the Study of African Economies, Oxford University

  • Eicher TS, Turnovsky SJ (1999) Convergence in a two-sector nonscale growth model. J Econ Growth 4(4):413–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein P, Howlett P, Schulze M-S (2003) Trade, convergence and globalisation: the dynamics of the international income distribution, 1950–1998. Explor Econ Hist 44(1):100–113

  • FAO (2006) Addressing the challenges facing agricultural mechanization input supply and farm product processing. Discussion paper

  • Feyer J (2008) Convergence by parts. BE J Macroecon 8(1):1935–1960. doi:10.2202/1935-1690.1646

  • Fiaschi D, Gianmoena L, Parenti A (2009) The dynamic of productivity across Italian Provinces from 1995 to 2006: convergence and polarization. University of Pisa, Mimeo

  • Fiaschi D, Lavezzi AM (2003) Distribution dynamics and nonlinear growth. J Econ Growth 8(4):379–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorio CV (2004) Confidence intervals for kernel density estimation. Stata J 4(2):168–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (1996) Convergence? Inferences from theoretical models. Econ J 106:1056–1069

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gemmell N (1996) Evaluating the impacts of human capital stocks and accumulation on economic growth: some new evidence. Oxford B Econ Stat 58(1):9–28

  • Graham BS, Temple JRW (2006) Rich nations, poor nations: how much can multiple equilibria explain? J Econ Growth 11(1):5–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffith R, Redding S, Van Reenen J (2004) Mapping the two faces of R&D: productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries. Rev Econ Stat 87:475–494

    Google Scholar 

  • Haerdle W (1991) Smoothing techniques with implementationchap, vol 1-2. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hall P (1992) Effect of bias estimation on convergence accuracy of bootstrap confidence intervals for a probability density. Ann Stat 20:675–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrigan J (1997) Technology, factor supplies and international specialisation. Am Econ Rev 87:475–494

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison A, Rodrguez-Clare A (2009) Trade, foreign investment, and industrial policy for developing countries. NBER working paper no 15261

  • Hausmann R, Hwang J, Rodrik D (2006) What you export matters. CEPR discussion papers 5444

  • Islam N (2003) What have we learned from the convergence debate? J Econ Surv 17:309–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson PA (2005) A continuous state space approach to “Convergence by parts”. Econ Lett 86:317– 321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson S, Larson W, Papageorgioud C, Subramaniane A (2013) Is newer better? Penn world table revisions and their impact on growth estimates. J Monet Econ 60(2):255–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (1995) R&D based models of economic growth. J Political Econ 103:759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (1997) Convergence revisited. J Econ Growth 2(2):131–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1987) The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease and the competitive consequences of Mrs Thatcher: notes on trade in presence of scale economies. J Dev Econ 27:41–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall S (1997) Learning from the Asian tigers: studies in technology and industrial policy. Palgrave MacMillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall S (2000) The technological structure and performance of developing country manufactured exports, 1985–1998. Oxf Dev Stud 28(3):337–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall S (2001) Competitiveness, technology and skills. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RJ (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luenberger DG (1979) Introduction to dynamic systems. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Maffezzoli M (2006) Convergence across Italian regions and the role of technological catch-up. BE J Macroecon 1(1):1–15

  • Magrini S (2007) Analysing convergence through the distribution dynamics approach: Why and how? DSE working paper 13

  • McMillian M, Rodrik D (2011) Globalization, structural change and productivity grow. NBER working paper no 17143

  • Nehru V, Dhareshwar A (1993) A new database on physical capital stock: sources, methodology and results. Revista de Analisis Economico 8(1):37–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen AL, Videras J, Davis L (2009) Do all countries follow the same growth process? J Econ Growth 14:265–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt K (1984) Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory. Res Policy 13:343–373

  • Quah D (1993) Galton’s fallacy and tests of the convergence hypothesis. Scand J Econ 95(4):427–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah D (1996a) Convergence empirics across economies with (some) capital mobility. J Econ Growth 1:95–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah D (1997) Empirics for growth and distribution: stratification, polarisation and convergence clubs. J Econ Growth 2(1):27–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah DT (1996b) Twin peaks: growth and convergence in models of distribution dynamics. Econ J 106(437):1045–1055

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RR, Zingales L (1998) Financial dependence and growth. Am Econ Rev 88(3):559–586

    Google Scholar 

  • Redding S (1999) Dynamic comparative advantage and the welfare effects of trade. Oxf Econ Pap 51:15–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redding S (2002) Specialization dynamics. J Int Econ 58(2):299–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (2013) Unconditional convergence in manufacturing. Q J Econ 128(1):165–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers M (2003) Knowledge, technological catch-up and economic growth. Edgward Elgar, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i Martin X (1996) The classical approach to convergence analysis. Econ J 106:1019–1036

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-I-Martin X, Doppelhofer G, Miller R (2004) Determinants of long-term growth: a Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. Am Econ Rev 94(4):813–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salgado-Ugarte IH, Makoto S, Toru T (1995) Practical rules for bandwidth selection in univariate density estimation. Stata Tech Bull 27:5–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Salgado-Ugarte IH, Shimizu M, Taniuchi T (1997) Nonparametric assessment of multimodality for univariate data. Stata Tech Bull 38:27–35

  • Scott DW (1992) Multivariate density estimation: theory, practice and visualization. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Silverman BW (1981) Using kernel density estimates to investigate multimodality. J R Stat Soc Ser B 43(1):97–99

  • Silverman BW (1986) Density estimation for statistics and data analysis. Chapman & Hall, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sims CA (1972) Money, income, and causality. Am Econ Rev 62(4):540–552

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh L (2006) Innovations, high-tech trade and industrial development. Theory, evidence and policy. UNU-wider research papers

  • Stockey NL, Lucas RE, Prescott EC (1989) Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (2001) Promoting linkages. Discussion paper

  • UNCTAD (2005) World investment report: TNCs and the internationalization of R&D. Discussion paper

  • UNIDO (1995) Industry and development. Global report. Discussion paper

  • UNIDO (2009) Industrial development report: breaking in and moving up: new industrial challenges for the bottom billion and the middle-income countries. Discussion paper

  • Vandenbussche J, Aghion P, Meghir C (2006) Growth, distance to frontier and composition of human capital. J Econ Growth 11:97–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wade R (1990) Governing the market: economic theory and the role of government in East Asian industrialization. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1991) Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of international trade. Q J Econ 106:396–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1995) The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical realties of East Asian growth experience. Q J Econ 110(3):641–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Carluccio Bianchi for invaluable guidance, Daniele Condorelli for helping all throughout the project, Danny Quah for helpful technical insights, Randolph Luca Bruno, Guido Ascari and all the participants to the 6th Conference on Growth and Development at ISI-Delhi for useful comments. Special thanks go to late Sanjaya Lall and Mark Rogers for encouragement and guidance. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Silvia Dal Bianco.

Appendices

Data appendix

1.1 Labour productivity

This is the natural logarithm of relative labour productivity. Labour productivity is measured as manufacturing value added per worker in 1996 PPP dollars. Relative labour productivity consists in the natural logarithm of labour productivity in country i, sector j, at time t relative to the one of the USA (i.e. the leader) in the same sector and period, which is formally written as \(y_{ijt}=\hbox {log}(Y_{ijt}/Y_{USjt})\). Normalizing the data is important for removing some of the trend from the cross section and thus for avoiding degenerate long-run distributions. The choice of the normalizing variable was made following Quah (1996a) and Desmet and Fafchamps (2006), although other indicators could have been used (e.g. cross-country average, range, etc).

Sectoral relative labour productivity data were retrieved combining UNIDO Industrial Statistics Database 2004, at 3-digits of ISIC Code (Revision 2) (i.e. INDSTAT3), World Bank, World Development Indicators 2006 (i.e. WDI) and the Penn World Tables 2002 (i.e. PWT 6.1).Footnote 26

1.2 Steady state proxies

1.2.1 Log-relative sectoral investment rates in physical capital

They refer to the natural logarithm of gross fixed capital formation (i.e. GFCF) share to manufacturing value added in country i, sector j, at time t relative to the one of the USA. Relevant series come from the aforementioned UNIDO dataset.

1.2.2 Log-relative investment rates in human capital

They consist in the natural logarithm of the average years of schooling in the population over age 15 in country i at time t relative to the one of the USA. Data come from Barro and Lee (2013), which is the most up-to-date version of the well- acknowledged dataset. In particular, as original series are recorded at 5-year intervals, they were interpolated assuming a linear pattern. Moreover, population over 15 years was preferred to the one over 25 years because working age in developing countries can be quite low, Bennell (1996).

1.2.3 Development dummy

This is a dichotomous variable having as reference group the high-income economies, as defined in WDI.

1.3 Relevant initial conditions

1.3.1 Log-relative physical capital stock per worker

This is the natural logarithm of physical capital stock in country i, sector j, at time t relative to the one of the USA in the same sector and period, which is formally written as \(k_{ijt}=\hbox {log}(K_{ijt}/K_{USjt})\).

Since sectoral physical capital stock series are not available from international data sources, they were estimated applying to the UNIDO GFCF series the perpetual inventory method assuming an exponential depreciation rate of 6 %. This is a quite standard hypothesis, see, for example, Vandenbussche et al. (2006) and Jones (1997).

As customary in the literature (Vandenbussche et al. 2006; Caselli 2005 and Young 1995), initial capital stock was calculated employing the formula of steady state capital stock in the neoclassical growth model. Thus, initial capital stock is written as \(K_{t-1}=\frac{I_t}{g+0.06}\).

As UNIDO GFCF data start in 1960, \(g\) is the output growth rate in the first 5 years available (i.e. 1960–1965), \(K_{t-1}\) is the estimated capital stock in 1959 and \(I_t\) is the actual investment in 1960. Since the present econometric exercise begins in 1980, the measurement error on this initial value should have disappeared (Vandenbussche et al. 2006; Nehru and Dhareshwar 1993).

The estimated sectoral capital stock is denominated in 1996 PPP Dollars.

To conclude, it is important to make a note of caution on the use of the same depreciation rate of capital for different sectors and for different countries. That different levels of technological progress should imply also different levels of depreciation rates is well documented in the literature, see Arslanalp et al. (2010). Thus, as robustness checks, capital stock series were calculated employing a 4 % and a 15 % depreciation rate, respectively, used by Nehru and Dhareshwar (1993) and Caselli and Wilson (2004). The findings of the distribution dynamics exercise are qualitatively unaltered. The robustness checks are available upon request.

1.3.2 Interacted TFPgap

Following Griffith et al. (2004), sector- and year-specific TFPgap is calculated as the difference between leader’s TFP and the one of any other country, where TFP levels are obtained through the superlative index approach of Caves (1982) and Caves et al. (1982), see the Appendix on TFP estimation for full details. The natural logarithm of secondary schooling attainment rate in any country i normalized with respect to the one of United States serves, instead, as absorption capacity proxy.

Appendix on TFP estimation

Total factor productivity (TFP) or Solow residual is the part of output growth not accounted for market transactions. It originates from growth accounting exercise, and it is conventionally employed to measure technological progress. Following Diewert (1976), Caves et al. (1982) derive an index number that allows TFP comparisons among countries. This index is superlative, meaning that is exact for the flexible aggregator function chosen (i.e. translog production function), and transitive, so that the choice of base country and year is inconsequential.Footnote 27

Formally, it is assumed that value added of a generic country i is a function of capital stock and employment, that is translog with identical second-order term, that constant returns to scale apply and that inputs are measured perfectly and in the same units for each observation. In symbols:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{i}=\alpha _{0i}+\alpha _{1i}lnl_{i}+\alpha _{2i}lnk_{i}+\alpha _{3}(lnl_{i})^{2}+ \alpha _{4}(lnk_{i})^{2}+\alpha _{5}(lnl_{i}*lnk_{i}) \end{aligned}$$

where constant returns to scale hypothesis requires \(\alpha _{1i}+\alpha _{2i}=1\) and \(2\alpha _{3}+\alpha _{5}=2\alpha _{4}+\alpha _{5}=0\).

In this Appendix, Caves et al. (1982) contribution is reviewed beginning with TFP index number for bilateral comparisons.

There are two countries, b and c, country b is the basis of comparison and the distance function \(D_{c}(y_{b},l_{b},k_{b})\) represents the minimum proportional decrease in \(y_{b}\) such that the resulting output is producible with the inputs and productivity levels of c. Or \(D_{c}(y_{b},l_{b},k_{b})\) is the smallest input bundle capable of producing \(y_{b}\) using the technology in country c. In symbols:

$$\begin{aligned} D_c(y_{b},x_{b})=\min \left\{ \delta \in \mathfrak {R}_{+} : f_c (\delta x_{b})\ge y_{b} \right\} \end{aligned}$$

where \(x_{b}=\left( k_{b},l_{b}\right) \).Footnote 28 Assuming that producers are cost minimizers and price takers in input markets, it can be shown that the Malmquist index (i.e. the geometric mean) of two distance functions for any two countries c and b gives the following TFP index:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {TFP}_{cb}=\frac{y_{c}}{y_{b}}\left( \frac{\bar{l}}{l_{c}}\right) ^{\sigma _{c}} \left( \frac{\bar{k}}{k_{c}}\right) ^{1-\sigma _{c}}\left( \frac{l_{b}}{\bar{l}} \right) ^{\sigma _{b}}\left( \frac{k_{b}}{\bar{k}}\right) ^{1-\sigma _{b}} \end{aligned}$$

where a bar denotes an average over countries and \(\sigma _i=\left( \alpha _{i}+\overline{\alpha }\right) /2\), where \((\alpha _{i})\) stands for labour’s share in total costs for country \(i\).

Similar reasoning can be applied to derive the multilateral version of TFP index, which allows for TFP comparisons among more than two countries. Taking sectoral heterogeneity explicitly into account, TFP level in country \(i\), sector \(j\) at time \(t\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {TFP}_{ijt}=\frac{Y_{ijt}}{\overline{Y_{jt}}}\left( \frac{\overline{L_{jt}}}{L_{ijt}} \right) ^{\tilde{\sigma }_{ijt}}\left( \frac{\overline{K_{jt}}}{K_{ijt}} \right) ^{{1-\tilde{\sigma }}_{ijt}} \end{aligned}$$

where a bar denotes the geometric average over all countries for a given sector \(j\) and a year t and \({\tilde{\sigma }_{i j t}}=(\alpha _{ijt}+\overline{\alpha _{j}})/2\), where \({\alpha _{ijt}}\) is labour share in country i and industry j and \(\overline{\alpha _{j}}\) is the cross-country average for industry j.

Then, taking natural logarithms, the previous expression becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {TFP}_{ijt}=\ln \left( \frac{Y_{ijt}}{\overline{Y_{jt}}}\right) -\tilde{\sigma }_{ijt} \ln \left( \frac{L_{ijt}}{\overline{L_{it}}}\right) -(1-\tilde{\sigma }_{ijt}) \ln \left( \frac{K_{ijt}}{\overline{K_{jt}}}\right) \end{aligned}$$

As originally noticed by Harrigan (1997), the variability in actual labour shares over value added makes difficult the empirical implementation of the equation above. To solve this problem, smoothed and not actual labour shares are usually employed.

Smoothed labour shares are simply obtained running a regression of actual labour shares on a constant and the capital to labour ratio:Footnote 29

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{ijt}=\xi _{i}+\xi _{j}+\chi _{ij}\ln \left( K_{ijt}/L_{ijt}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Previous studies on developed countries, such as Harrigan (1997) and Griffith et al. (2004), consider only sectoral heterogeneity in slopes (i.e. \(\chi _{j}\)). As the sample of countries employed in the current contribution comprises developing countries, the original specification has been improved allowing for country and sector heterogeneity in both intercepts and slopes (i.e. \(\xi _{i}\), \(\xi _{j}\) and \(\chi _{ij}\)). In particular, to avoid a major loss in data variability, due to many dummies, manufacturing sectors have been grouped as according to Lall’s taxonomy and the sampled economies have been divided into developed and developing ones, using World Bank definitions. The diagnostics employed strongly reject the null hypothesis of nonheterogeneity in both intercepts and slopes among different sectors and countries. More precisely, using panel data F tests, intercept heterogeneity due to country and sector-fixed effects has been detected. Sector and country heterogeneity, in both slope and intercepts, has been confirmed through Chow type F statistics.Footnote 30

Appendix on distribution dynamics

1.1 Distribution dynamics and conditioning: a brief nontechnical summary

When distribution dynamics is employed, convergence tendencies among countries can be retrieved analysing the evolution along time of cross-country labour productivity distribution. In particular, the main question to be answered is whether all economies considered converge to same level of labour productivity, such that the cross-country distribution is single-peaked, or whether the economies converge only within small clubs, such that the distribution exhibits more than one peak.

Operatively, the changes along time of cross-country labour productivity distribution are retrieved using the stochastic kernel density estimator. In fact, this estimator allows to measure the probabilities of dynamic transitions from one labour productivity class to another, for each economy.

Intuitively, the stochastic kernel can be thought as a refinement of the histogram. In particular, while in histogram the frequency distribution is calculated for disjoint states, with kernel density estimator, the frequency distribution is estimated for a large number of overlapping class intervals, which gives a much smoother appearance, resembling a probability density function.

Two are the types of kernels employed in this paper:

  1. 1.

    unconditioned kernels

  2. 2.

    conditioned kernels

The unconditioned kernels give information on the likelihood that an economy, starting from a given relative position in the initial period \(t\), will end up improving or worsening its relative position in the final period \(t+s\). In other words, it can be said that unconditioned kernels measure the transition probabilities from \(t\) to \(t+s\).

Unconditioned kernels are used here to test the absolute convergence hypothesis.

Conditioned kernels are an extension of unconditioned ones. In particular, they allow to identify the factors that eventually lead club convergence dynamics. The effects of conditioning are identified by changes in shape and location of the kernel, with respect to the unconditioned case.

Conditioned kernels are here employed for testing both conditional convergence hypothesis and club convergence determinants.

In the case of conditional convergence, for example, if the unconditioned kernel shows twin-peaks feature and, after conditioning with respect to steady state proxies, it is found that the conditioned kernel is single-peaked, then it can be said that club dynamics is lead by structural differences and that conditional converge hypothesis is not rejected.

1.2 Unconditioned transition probability estimates

This section provides a technical illustration of the methodology employed to estimate unconditioned transition probabilities, which are used to test the absolute convergence hypothesis.

Sectoral convergence tendencies are inferred analysing the dynamic behaviour of cross-country distribution of log-relative labour productivity.Footnote 31

Individual country \(i\) labour productivity, in sector \(j\), at time \(t\) is called \(y_{it}\), where the sector index has been omitted for notational convenience (i.e. \(y_{it}=log(Y_{ijt}/Y_{USjt})\)). Cross- country, sector-specific, labour productivity distribution, at time \(t\), is denoted as \(f_{Y_t}(y_t)\), where \(Y_t\) indicates the corresponding random variable.

It is assumed that year-to-year changes in the distribution of labour productivity can be represented by an homogeneous Markow process, in such a way that, \(\forall t\):

  1. 1.

    \(f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}|y_t)=f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}| y_t,y_{t-1},y_{t-2},...)\)

  2. 2.

    \(f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}|y_t)=f_{Y_t|Y_{t-1}}(y_{t}|y_{t-1})\)

The first property guarantees that only previous period income distribution impacts on next period one (i.e. history does not matter). The homogeneity assumption in 2 ensures that the transition probabilities do not vary with time. Although quite restrictive, both hypotheses are necessary for estimating long-run transition probabilities given the available data.

Conditional density functions, \(f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}|y_{t})\), represent the cornerstone of distribution dynamics convergence analysis. This kind of distribution, in fact, encodes information about individual economies’ passages over time. Thus, it sheds light on both intra-distribution dynamics and external shapes, making inference about convergence tendencies possible. For example, observing conditional density mappings, is it possible to know whether poor countries are catching up with their richer counterparts, whether rich countries are still enriching, whether countries are converging overall or are clustering within clubs.

The empirical estimation of conditional densities is handled by nonparametric techniques. To begin, it is worth to recall the definition of conditional distribution, that is the joint distribution divided by the marginal distribution. In formal terms:

$$\begin{aligned} f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}|y_{t})= \frac{f_{Y_{t+1},Y_t}(y_{t+1}, y_{t})}{f_{Y_t}(y_{t})} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

The joint distribution of \((Y_{t+1}, Y_{t})\) can be estimated nonparametrically using a bivariate stochastic kernel, while the marginal distribution of \(Y_{t}\) is obtained by numerical integration of the joint distribution. Finally, the conditional distribution is simply obtained by dividing one to the other, after appropriate discretization of the joint support.Footnote 32

Long-run tendencies towards convergence are encoded by the ergodic distribution. This is the stationary distribution of labour productivity, which will be approached in the long run should certain technical conditions hold.Footnote 33 In particular, if the ergodic distribution is unimodal and has a low variance, then long-run cross-country convergence can be claimed.

Formally, the ergodic is the distribution \(f\) which solves the following functional equation:

$$\begin{aligned} f(y_{t+1})=\int _{-\infty }^{+\infty }f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t}(y_{t+1}|y_{t})f(y_{t})dy \end{aligned}$$
(2)

In order to compute the ergodic distribution, the support of \(y\) is discretized in a set of \(N\) equally large intervals, where interval \(h\) is denoted as \(\varOmega _{h}\).Footnote 34

Then, the probabilities of transition from one interval to another are calculated. Formally, the probability of transition from the interval \(\varOmega _{h}\) to another, \(\varOmega _{k}\), in one time period, is denoted as

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{hk}=Pr(y_{t+1}\in \varOmega _{k}|y_{t}\in \varOmega _{h}) \end{aligned}$$

At this point of the explanation, it is useful to adopt a compact matrix notation. Hence, the ergodic distribution is the vector \(p\) that solves the following system of equations:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle p=Ap\\&\displaystyle (I-A)p=0 \end{aligned}$$

where each component of the vector \(p\) represents the probability of \(y\) assuming a value comprised in a given \(\varOmega \) and A is the matrix of transition probabilities \(\alpha _{hk}\).

Since each column of matrix A is a marginal density and then its elements sum to 1, A does not have full rank, and by consequence, the system does not have a unique solution. To find a unique solution, it is standard to simply drop one row of A (to make its columns linearly independent) and then add the restriction that the entries of vector \(p\) sum to 1.Footnote 35 Then, matrix A is rewritten as B

The modified system is then

$$\begin{aligned} Bp=b \end{aligned}$$

where the vector \(b\), for the constraint added, has all entries equal to 0 except the last one, which is equal to 1.

At this point, the unique ergodic distribution, \(p\), can be easily found inverting B:

$$\begin{aligned} p=B^{-1}b \end{aligned}$$

1.3 Conditioning techniques

This part outlines the conditioning technique employed to test for conditional convergence and club convergence determinants.

Under the conditional convergence hypothesis, cross-country productivity equalization cannot be found in the original relative labour productivity distribution, \(f_{Y}\), but in the conditioned one, \(f_{Y|X}\), where \(X\) denotes steady state proxies. Then, the object of interest is the transition probabilities of the part of labour productivity not explained by the auxiliary variables (i.e. steady state proxies). Employing the former notation, such transition probabilities are formally written as

$$\begin{aligned} f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t,X_t}(y_{t+1}|y_{t},x_t) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

Exploiting Chamberlain (1984) results, the part of labour productivity orthogonal to auxiliary variables is computed as ordinary least squares (OLS) residuals of the projection of labour productivity growth on each of the steady state proxies.Footnote 36 Such calculation involves three steps:

  1. 1.

    estimating the part of countries’ relative productivity growth rate explained by conditioning steady state variables;

  2. 2.

    finding the initial level of relative labour productivity explained by conditioning steady state variables;

  3. 3.

    combining the previous results to find the level of relative labour productivity unexplained by the auxiliary variables (i.e. orthogonal to steady state proxies).

Call \(g_{it}\) the growth rate of \(y_{it}\) (i.e. log-relative productivity in country \(i\), sector \(j\) at time \(t\)), where again the sector index is omitted for notational convenience. Name \(\widehat{g_{it}}\) the part of \(g_{it}\) explained steady state proxies, which are investment rate in both physical and human capital, indicated as \(r_{it}\) and \(h_{it}\), and the dummy development, \(ddev\). Finally, the part of labour productivity orthogonal to steady state proxies, which is the object of interest, is called \(\widehat{\epsilon }_{it}\).

Step 1 is implemented regressing \(g_{it}\) on a two-sided distributed lag of conditioning variables and saving the fitted values. One of such regressions is run for each steady state proxy. Then, cumulating the fitted values, by country and sector, the part of countries’ relative productivity growth rate explained by conditioning steady state variables, \(\widehat{g_{it}}\), is obtained.

Note that in empirical work, multisided regressions are employed to handle endogeneity issues, which are represented in this specific case by the likely bidirectional causality between labour productivity growth rate and steady state proxies. This technique, introduced by Sims (1972), has been extensively used by Quah, who noticed that just 2 leads and 2 lags are sufficient to clear the estimated growth rate from feedback effects, Quah (1996a).

Step 2 is taken running a pooled OLS regression of \(y_{it}\) on steady state proxies’ time averages (i.e. \(\overline{r_{it}}\) and \(\overline{h_{it}}\)) and the estimated growth rate (i.e.\(\widehat{g_{it}}\)). For each sector, the coefficients that solves the following minimization problem are used to pin down the initial level of labour productivity explained by steady state variables, \(\widehat{y_{i0}}\):Footnote 37

$$\begin{aligned} min_{\beta _{1},\beta _{2},\beta _{3}}\sum _{i}\sum _{t}[y_{it}-(\beta _{1} \overline{r_{it}}+\beta _{2}\overline{h_{it}}+\beta _{3}ddev+ \widehat{g_{it}})]^{2} \end{aligned}$$

In fact, thanks to the estimated coefficients, \(\widehat{\beta }s\), the initial level of log-relative labour productivity explained by conditioning variables can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{y_{i0}}=\widehat{\beta _{1}}\overline{r_{it}}+\widehat{\beta _{2}} \overline{h_{it}}+\widehat{\beta _{3}}ddev \end{aligned}$$

Then, adding the growth rates of step 1, the level of relative labour productivity explained by steady state variable is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{y_{it}}=\widehat{y_{i0}}+\widehat{g_{it}} \end{aligned}$$

Finally, \(\epsilon _{it}\), which represents the productivity level not accounted for (or conditional to) steady state proxies, is simply found subtracting the estimated relative labour productivity from the actual one:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\epsilon }_{it}=y_{it}-\widehat{y_{it}} \end{aligned}$$

Once country- and sector-specific \(\epsilon _{it}\) series have been calculated, the empirical implementation for testing conditional convergence is the same as absolute (or unconditional) convergence.

In particular, bivariate stochastic kernel densities fit the cross-country, sector-specific distribution of relative productivity orthogonal to steady state variables, which is denoted as \(f_{\widehat{E_{t+1}},\widehat{E_{t}}}(\widehat{\epsilon _{t+1}},\widehat{\epsilon _{t}})\). By numerical integration of the joint distribution, the marginal density \(f_{\widehat{E_{t}}}(\widehat{\epsilon _{t}})\) is obtained. Finally, the transition probabilities of Equation (3) are found dividing the joint distribution, \(f_{\widehat{E_{t+1}},\widehat{E_{t}}}(\widehat{\epsilon _{t+1}},\widehat{\epsilon _{t}})\), by the marginal distribution, \(f_{\widehat{E_{t}}}(\widehat{\epsilon _{t}})\).

Long-run distribution of relative labour productivity conditioned to steady state variables is retrieved from the ergodic distribution of random variable \(\widehat{\epsilon _{t}}\). Such a distribution is calculated as for the unconditional case (previous section).

Turning now to club convergence analysis, it should be intuitive that the conditioning scheme described so far can be easily extended to determine the relative strength of club convergence inner drivers.

In particular, when club convergence hypothesis holds, the object of interest becomes the dynamics of labour productivity distribution conditioned to both steady state proxies and club convergence driving forces, namely capital and technological initial conditions. Formally, the following transition probabilities has to be computed:

$$\begin{aligned} f_{Y_{t+1}|Y_t,X_t,Z_t}(y_{t+1}|y_{t},x_t,z_t) \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where the variable \(Z\) represents either initial capital stock or initial technological level.

To retrieve the relative strength of capital stock (or technology) as club convergence determinant, relative labour productivity orthogonal to both steady state proxies and capital stock (or technology) initial level must be calculated. This is done implementing the three steps previously described, taking into consideration capital stock (or technology) as extra conditioning variable.

By the same tokens as before, the density in Equation (4) and the ergodic distributions are computed.

To conclude, it is worth noticing that the conditioning scheme here employed allows not only to work out alternative convergence hypotheses within a unified framework but also to calculate the ergodic of distributions that have been conditioned to time varying (and likely endogenous) variables. This latter aspect is particularly worth because it represents a step forward with respect to long-run convergence analysis based on both discrete transition probability matrices, such as in Quah (1996a, 1997), Epstein et al. (2007) and Maffezzoli (2006), and time-invariant conditioning factors such as in Desmet and Fafchamps (2006).

1.4 Statistical inference

The reliability of the kernel density estimations presented in this paper has been checked through a number of statistical inference routines.Footnote 38

First, following Salgado-Ugarte et al. (1995) and their survey on different methods for selecting the bandwidth for univariate density estimation, Silverman (1986) Gaussian kernel optimal bandwidth has been calculated for each assessed convergence hypothesis, for all manufacturing sectors under consideration.Footnote 39

Second, drawing from the work of Fiorio (2004), the asymptotic \(95\%\) confidence intervals for kernel density estimation, based on the theory of kernel density confidence intervals estimation developed in Hall (1992), have been calculated employing Silverman’s Gaussian kernel optimal bandwidth.Footnote 40

Third, the number of modes of the estimated kernel densities as well as their values has been assessed following the ASH-WARPing procedure, Scott (1992) and Haerdle (1991), employing as optimal bandwith the one of Silverman.Footnote 41

Finally, the nonparametric assessment of multimodality has been done following the work of Silverman (1981) as described in Salgado-Ugarte et al. (1997). In particular, the test proposed by Silverman uses nonparametric kernel density estimation techniques to determine the most probable number of modes in the underlying density univariate data, employing bootstrapped samples. Silverman’s test reports the \(p\) value associated with each number of modes for each bootstrapped sample. As such, a testing procedure should be repeated for a successively larger number of modes until a sufficiently large \(p\) value is obtained, one common rule of thumb is stopping the test once a nominal \(p\) value of 0.40 has been found, Salgado-Ugarte et al. (1997).Footnote 42

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dal Bianco, S. Going clubbing in the eighties: convergence in manufacturing sectors at a glance. Empir Econ 50, 623–659 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0940-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0940-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation