Skip to main content
Log in

Government popularity and the economy: first evidence from German microdata

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This is one of the first studies to estimate a popularity function at the microlevel. Using German microlevel data for the years 1991, 1992, 1998, and 2008, we show that a positive assessment of the economy significantly improves government popularity, while negative evaluations decrease satisfaction with the government. Voters take the (current and expected) national and personal economic situation into account. We find no evidence for a grievance asymmetry, i.e., voters not only punish the government for a bad economy but also reward them in good times. Finally, we show that popularity functions are only very crude proxies for vote functions, with the latter being mostly driven by party identification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Vote and popularity (VP) functions have been estimated for many countries and time periods, and it is virtually impossible to discuss the extensive body of research in an article like this due to space constraints. Excellent overviews are given by Lewis-Beck and Paldam (2000), Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier (2000, 2007), and Paldam (2008). Berlemann and Enkelmann (2012) survey and discuss the large field of popularity functions for the United States.

  2. Hesli and Bashkirova (2001) study public support for Russian presidents between 1991 and 1999. However, there is no such study for any Western country.

  3. In a related study, Norpoth and Gschwend (2010) use government popularity to predict election outcomes in Germany.

  4. According to a survey by Paldam (2008), questions Q2 through Q4 represent unsettled (“controversial”) issues in the field. In the German context, evidence is even less clear.

  5. Among others, Downs’ theory has been further developed by Davis et al. (1970) and Kirchgässner (1986). In these models—and also in Downs (1957, ch. 8)—voters maximize utility by minimizing the distance between their own position and the (estimated) party position in the politico-economic space. From these models, an aggregate popularity function can be derived (see, e.g.,Kirchgässner 1986; Neck and Karbuz 1997). For our purpose, however, this approach is less helpful since we focus on the voter’s evaluation of the economy as such, i.e., our measure of performance is a valence issue and not a position issue (see Stokes 1963). Our argumentation, thus, follows the basic ideas of Downs (1957, ch. 3).

  6. After the German reunification an additional, unscheduled survey was conducted in 1991.

  7. The study employs the cumulative GGSS/ALLBUS dataset “ALLBUS/GGSS 1980–2008, study number 4570” (GESIS 2010), which is also available in English language (study number 4572).

  8. Alternatively, it is possible to create a dummy variable that is one if the respondent falls into the two or four highest answer categories. However, the construction of our dummy variable is (linguistically) intuitive as the three top answer categories include the word “satisfied” while the others include the word “dissatisfied” in their answer. In addition, we have run an ordered logit regression that supports our intuitive division. A good economy increases the likelihood of choosing a positive category, and vice versa. As the results are qualitatively identical, we decided to present the results for the dummy variable.

  9. The questions read as follows:

    Current national economy: “How would you generally rate the current economic situation in Germany?”

    Future national economy: “What do you think will the economic situation in Germany will be like in one year?”

    Current personal economy: “How would you generally rate your own current financial situation?”

    Future personal economy: “What will your own financial situation be like in one year?”

  10. This approach is in line with, e.g., Hesli and Bashkirova (2001). The estimation of OLS or ordered logit models with the categorial popularity variable as the dependent variable as well as linear probability models with the dichotomous variable as a dependent variable leave the qualitative results unaffected.

  11. We also estimated a model in which the categorial economic variables were re-coded to variables with three outcomes (good, neutral, or bad). The results are virtually identical to the ones presented in the text.

  12. Results for all variables including the control variables can be found in Tables 9 and 10 in the Appendix.

  13. Regarding the goodness-of-fit, the model performs quite well. We present the most common McFadden’s \(R^2\) which is, however, severely downward biased. According to McFadden (1979, p. 307), a value above 0.20 already indicates an excellent fit. The share of correct predictions is an alternative and more intuitive measure. Assuming that a respondent is satisfied with the government if the predicted probability is above 50 %, we are able to predict about 70 % of all answers correctly.

  14. The coefficients in Table 5 describe the effect (in percentage points) of a change from neutral to the respective category. For example, changing from a neutral position to very bad regarding the current national economy decreases the probability of expressing approval by 19 % points.

  15. Comparing the effect of a bad/very bad assessment of the present national economy versus a good/very good economy, we find weak statistical evidence for a grievance asymmetry. In a model in which all economic variables are re-coded to three-category variables, we find an asymmetry with respect to the present and future national economies in the entire sample. The effect of a bad assessment is significantly larger than the corresponding effect of a positive assessment.

  16. Paldam (1991, p. 9), for example, states that “[t]he two functions are so alike that I shall speak of VP-functions.”

  17. On the microlevel no popularity function estimates exist. At the macrolevel, results are hardly comparable since elections are comparatively rare events that allow for only simple statistics, while popularity functions are sometimes based on more than 50 years of monthly data.

  18. On the other hand, it should be noted that most vote functions rely on answers regarding vote intention. In this case, the last two points are very weak.

  19. We also estimated vote functions for each single year (see Table 11 in the Appendix). Economic variables are often not statistically significant and the coefficients are small in size. In all cases, vote intention is mainly explained by past voting behavior which is highly significant in all years.

References

  • Alesina A, Fuchs-Schündeln N (2007) Good-bye Lenin (or not?): the effect of communism on people’s preferences. Am Econ Rev 97(4):1507–1528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batool I, Sieg G (2009) Bread and the attrition of power: economic events and German election results. Public Choice 141:151–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellucci P, Lewis-Beck MS (2011) A stable popularity function? Cross-national analysis. Eur J Political Res 50:190–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berlemann M, Enkelmann S (2012) The economic determinants of U.S. Presidential approval: a survey. CESifo Working Paper No 3761

  • Bloom HS, Price HD (1975) Voter response to short-run economic conditions: the asymmetric effect of prosperity and recession. Am Political Sci Rev 69(4):1240–1254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell A, Converse PE, Miller WE, Stokes DE (1960) The American voter. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis OA, Hinich MJ, Ordeshook PC (1970) An expository development of a mathematical model of the electoral process. Am Political Sci Rev 64(2):426–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen G (1990) The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Polity Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld LP, Kirchgässner G (2000) Official and hidden unemployment and the popularity of the government: an econometric analysis for the Kohl government. Elect Stud 19:333–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina MP (1978) Economic retrospective voting in American national elections: a micro-analysis. Am J Political Sci 22(2):426–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Garbers H (1972) Der Einfluss wirtschaftlicher Variablen auf die Popularität von Regierungen: Eine empirische Analyse. J Econ Stat 186:281–295

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Schneider FG (1978a) A politico-economic model of the United Kingdom. Econ J 88: 243–253

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Schneider FG (1978b) An empirical study of politico-economic interaction in the United States. Rev Econ Stat 60(2):174–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • GESIS (2010) ALLBUS Kumulation 1980–2008: Study No. 4570, version 2.0.1

  • Hesli VL, Bashkirova E (2001) The impact of time and economic circumstances on popular evaluations of Russia’s President. Int Political Sci Rev 22(4):379–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan N (1965) The asymmetry of liking and disliking: a phenomenon meriting further reflection and research. Public Opin Q 29(2):315–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellermann C, Rattinger H (2006) Economic conditions, unemployment and perceived government accountability. Ger Politics 15(4):460–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key VO (1964) Politics, parties and pressure groups, 5th edn. Crowell, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Key VO (1966) The responsible electorate: rationality in presidential voting, 1936–1960. Belknap Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kinder DR, Kiewiet DR (1979) Economic discontent and political behavior: the role of personal grievances and collective economic judgements in congressional voting. Am J Political Sci 23(3):495–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinder DR, Kiewiet DR (1981) Sociotropic politics: the American case. British J Political Sci 11(2): 129–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G (1974) Ökonometrische Untersuchungen des Einflusses der Wirtschaftslage auf die Popularität der Parteien. Swiss J Econ Stat 110(3):409–445

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G (1985) Causality testing of the popularity function: an empirical investigation for the Federal Republic of Germany, 1971–1982. Public Choice 45(2):155–173

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G (1986) Economic conditions and the popularity of West German parties: a survey. Eur J Political Res 14:421–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G (1991) On the relation between voting intention and the perception of the general economic situation: an empirical analysis for the Federal Republic of Germany, 1972–1986. Eur J Political Econ 7:497–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G (2009) The lost popularity function: are unemployment and inflation no longer relevant for the behaviour of German voters? CESifo Working Paper No 2882

  • Kramer GH (1971) Short-term fluctuations in U.S. voting behavior, 1896–1964. Am Political Sci Rev 65(1):131–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazarsfeld PF, Berelson B, Gaudet H (1944) The people’s choice: How the voter makes up his mind in a presidential campaign. Duelle Sloan and Pearce, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck MS, Paldam M (2000) Economic voting: an introduction. Elect Stud 19:113–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck MS, Stegmaier M (2000) Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annu Rev Political Sci 3(2):183–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck MS, Stegmaier M (2007) Economic models of voting. In: Dalton RJ, Klingemann HD (eds) Oxford handbook of political behavior. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, pp 518–537

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKuen MB, Erikson RS, Stimson JA (1992) Peasants or bankers? The american electorate and the U.S. economy. Am Political Sci Rev 86(3):597–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maier J, Rattinger H (2004) Economic conditions and voting behaviour in German federal elections, 1994–2002. Ger Politics 13(2):201–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden DL (1979) Quantitative methods for analysing travel behaviour of individuals: some recent developments. In: Hensher DA, Stopher PR (eds) Behavioural travel modelling. Croom Helm, London, pp 279–318

    Google Scholar 

  • Meehl PE (1977) The selfish voter paradox and the thrown-away vote argument. Am Political Sci Rev 71(1):11–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller JE (1970) Presidential popularity from Truman to Johnson. Am Political Sci Rev 64(1):18–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad P, Paldam M (1994) The VP-function: a survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice 79:213–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nannestad P, Paldam M (1997) The grievance asymmetry revisited: a micro study of economic voting in Denmark, 1986–92. Eur J Political Econ 13:81–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neck R, Karbuz S (1997) Econometric estimations of popularity functions: a case study for Austria. Public Choice 91:57–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth H, Gschwend T (2010) The chancellor model: forecasting German elections. Int J Forecast 26: 42–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Paldam M (1991) How robust is the vote function? a study of seventeen nations over four decades. In: Norpoth H, Lewis-Beck MS, Lafay JD (eds) Economics and politics. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, pp 9–32

  • Paldam M (2008) Vote and popularity functions. In: Rowley CK, Schneider FG (eds) Readings in public choice and constitutional political economy. Springer, New York, pp 533–550

  • Rattinger H, Steinbrecher M (2011) Economic voting in times of economic crisis. Ger Politics 20(1):128–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozin P, Royzman EB (2001) Negativity bias, negativity dominance, and contagion. Pers Soc Psychol Rev 5(4):296–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigelman L (1979) Presidential popularity and presidential elections. Public Opin Q 43(4):532–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smyth DJ, Taylor SK, Dua P (1991) Structural change in the United States’ social preference function, 1953–88. Appl Econ 23:763–768

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokes DE (1963) Spatial models of party competition. Am Political Sci Rev 57(2):368–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Michael Berlemann, Markus Leibrecht, Christian Pfeifer, participants at the Scottish Economic Society 2012 Annual Conference and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sören Enkelmann.

Appendix: Detailed results

Appendix: Detailed results

See Tables 9, 10 and 11.

Table 9 Popularity function (including control variables)
Table 10 Popularity function with categorial variables
Table 11 Vote function, single years

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Enkelmann, S. Government popularity and the economy: first evidence from German microdata. Empir Econ 46, 999–1017 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0707-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0707-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation