Skip to main content
Log in

Asylum seekers in Europe: the warm glow of a hot potato

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Common European Asylum System calls for increased coordination of the European Union (EU) countries’ policies towards asylum seekers and refugees. In this paper, we provide a formal analysis of the effects of coordination, explicitly modelling the democratic process through which policy is determined. In a symmetric, two-country citizen-candidate setup, in which accepting asylum seekers in one country generates a cross-border externality in the other, we show that coordination is desirable. Internalizing the externality leads to a welfare improvement over the non-cooperative outcome. However, contrary to suggestions by many observers, we show that allowing for cross-country transfers in the cooperative outcome leads to a welfare inferior outcome because the possibility of compensation exacerbates strategic delegation effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. General Declaration on Articles 13 to 19.

  2. See Luedtke (2005).

  3. “Switzerland and Austria have accused Italy of turning a blind eye to would-be refugees heading north.” The Economist, September 6, 2001.

  4. See for instance Boeri et al. 2002, and Hatton (2004).

  5. Emphasis added by the authors.

  6. The citizen-candidate framework we are using has been introduced by Besley and Coate (1997) and Osborne and Slivinski (1996). The concept of strategic delegation has been applied in different contexts: Besley and Coate (2003) use it to analyze the provision of local public goods, Willmann (2004) employs it to endogenize trade policy, Lorz and Willmann (2005) explain the degree of regionalism in this way, etc.

  7. For more details on the construction of the figures, we refer the reader to the Appendix of Hatton (2004).

  8. It is worth emphasizing that the specific functional forms are chosen solely to guarantee a closed-form solution. The crucial features of this setup are the convex cost that gives rise to a concave objective function and the positive net spill-over from admitting asylum seekers. A similar functional form is used by Segendorff (1998).

  9. Conceptionally, we can distinguish up-front processing costs and the ongoing cost burden. While our model allows for both, the inclusion of spill-overs is relevant mainly for the latter.

  10. Notice that in our model, we do not explicitly consider the dynamic adjustments involved in the ‘relocation’ of migrants across countries. This is realistic as long as the relocation takes place quickly. Alternatively, as suggested by one referee, we could think of \(m_i\) as representing the stock of refugees, and the costs and utilities should then be interpreted as present values.

  11. Note that the welfare of immigrants enters aggregate welfare in each country only indirectly through the warm glow effect.

  12. Recall that we assume \(1/2<\lambda<1\).

  13. Note that in the absence of cost spill-overs (\(\lambda=1\)) strategic delegation would disappear in the noncooperative game. This is not true in the coordination case because their strategic delegation is undertaken for different reasons, as will become clear in the next section.

  14. The outside utility, thus, takes the form \(U_i(\hat{\alpha}_i,m^N)=2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]m_i^{N}(\hat{\alpha}^N)+\ln(1- m_i^{N}(\hat{\alpha}^N))\), where \(m_i^N(\hat{\alpha}^N)\) is determined by the equilibrium without coordination derived in the previous section. Note that this implies that the representatives who bargain are not necessarily the same as those who set the immigration level noncooperatively. We make this assumption to keep the model tractable.

  15. Note that this argument would hold even if \(\lambda=1\), and therefore, there were no strategic delegation in the non-cooperative game the of previous section.

  16. This result is reminiscent of Wilson (1990) who shows that the availability of a more efficient policy instrument can lead to a less efficient equilibrium because the efficient instrument is used more extensively.

  17. One may wonder why the two countries would consider side payments at all, as these turn out to lead to a welfare inferior outcome. We are implicitly assuming that politicians cannot commit to not use such payments. This assumption is supported by the fact that the use of side payments is a prominent feature of the current political debate.

  18. This is due to our simplifying assumption of \(\lambda=1\), not to the asymmetry.

References

  • Besley T, Coate S (1997) An economic model of representative democracy. Q J Econ 108(1):85–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Coate S (2003) Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public goods: a political economy approach. J Public Econ 87(4):2611–2637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boeri T, Hanson G, McCormick B (eds) (2002) Immigration policy and the welfare system. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Hatton TJ (2004) Seeking asylum in Europe. Econ Policy 38:5–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatton TJ, Williamson JG (2004) Refugees, asylum seekers and policy in Europe. Mimeo, Harvard University, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorz O, Willmann G (2005) On the endogenous allocation of decision powers in federal structures. J Urban Econ 57:242–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luedtke A (2005) European integration, public opinion and immigration policy: testing the impact of national identity. Eur Union Polit 6:83–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noll G (2000) Negotiating asylum: the EU Acquis, extraterritorial protection and the common market of deflection. Martinus Nijhoff, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne MJ, Slivinski A (1996) A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. Q J Econ 111(1):65–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segendorff B (1998) Delegation and threat in bargaining. Games Econom Behav 23:266–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNHCR (2003) 2003 Global refugees trends. United Nations High Commission on Refugees, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Willmann G (2004) Why legislators are protectionists: the role of majoritarian voting in setting tariffs.http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=564587

  • Wilson JD (1990) Are efficiency improvements in government transfer policies self-defeating in political equilibrium? Econ Polit 2:241–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Gil Epstein who provided the impetus for this research, to two anonymous referees for insightful comments and to conference participants at the Midwest International Economics Spring 2005 meeting for helpful discussions. The usual caveat applies: all errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gerald Willmann.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Symmetric case

This appendix derives \(dm_i^B/d\hat{\alpha}_i\) and \(dm_{-i}^B/d\hat{\alpha}_i\) for the bargaining equilibrium without side payments. The first-order condition for \(m_i^B\) as given by Eq. 14 is \(N_{m_i}=0\). The first-order condition for \(m_{-i}^B\) is \(N_{m_{-i}}=0\). By totally differentiating these equations, we obtain

$$\eqalign{ \frac{dm_i^B}{d\hat{\alpha}_i} = \frac{-N_{m_i\hat{\alpha}_i}N_{m_{-i} m_{-i}}+N_{m_{-i}\hat{\alpha}_i}N_{m_i m_{-i}}}{N_{m_im_i}N_{m_{-i}m_{-i}}-N_{m_i m_{-i}}N_{m_{-i} m_i}}, }$$
(42)
$$\eqalign{ \frac{dm_{-i}^B}{d\hat{\alpha}_i} = \frac{-N_{m_{-i}\hat{\alpha}_i}N_{m_i m_i}+N_{m_i\hat{\alpha}_i}N_{m_{-i} m_i}}{N_{m_im_i}N_{m_{-i}m_{-i}}-N_{m_i m_{-i}}N_{m_{-i} m_i}}. }$$
(43)

Departing from the symmetric equilibrium (\(\hat{\alpha}_i=\hat{\alpha}_{-i}\) and \(s_i=s_{-i}\)), the respective terms in Eqs. 42 and 43 can be derived as

$$ N_{{m_{i} m_{i} }} = - 2{\left[ {1 + \widehat{\alpha }_{i} } \right]}^{2} {\left\{ {2s_{i} {\left[ {1 - 2\lambda + 2\lambda ^{2} } \right]} + {\left[ {1 - 2\lambda } \right]}^{2} } \right\}} = N_{{m_{i} m_{i} }} $$
(44)
$$ N_{{m_{i} m_{{ - i}} }} = - 2{\left[ {1 + \widehat{\alpha }_{i} } \right]}^{2} {\left\{ {4s_{i} \lambda {\left[ {1 - \lambda } \right]} - {\left[ {1 - 2\lambda } \right]}^{2} } \right\}} = N_{{m_{{ - i}} m_{i} }} , $$
(45)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_i \hat{\alpha}_i} = s_i + 2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]\left[2\lambda-1\right]\left[m_i^B(\hat{\alpha})-m_i^N(\hat{\alpha}^N)\right], }$$
(46)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_{-i} \hat{\alpha}_i} = s_i - 2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]\left[2\lambda-1\right]\left[m_i^B(\hat{\alpha})-m_i^N(\hat{\alpha}^N)\right]. }$$
(47)

Inserting these equations into Eqs. 42 and 43 and rearranging yields

$$\eqalign{ \frac{dm_i^B}{d\hat{\alpha}_i} = \frac{\left[1+s_i\right]\left[2\lambda-1\right]+2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]\left[m_i^B(\hat{\alpha})-m_i^N(\hat{\alpha}^N)\right]}{4\left[2\lambda-1\right]\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]^2\left[1+s_i\right]}, }$$
(48)
$$\eqalign{ \frac{dm_{-i}^B}{d\hat{\alpha}_i} = \frac{\left[1+s_i\right]\left[2\lambda-1\right]-2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]\left[m_i^B(\hat{\alpha})-m_i^N(\hat{\alpha}^N)\right]}{4\left[2\lambda-1\right]\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]^2\left[1+s_i\right]}. }$$
(49)

1.2 Asymmetric case

As in the symmetric case, the equations determining the marginal influence of \(\hat{\alpha}_i\) on the immigration levels can be derived from the first-order conditions and are identical to Eqs. 42 and 43 above,with \(N_{m_i}=0\) given by Eq. 34. From Eq. 34 the following equations can be derived:

$$\eqalign{ N_{m_i m_i} = -\frac{s_{-i}}{\left[1-m_i\right]^2}-2 \left[1+\hat{\alpha}_{-i}\right]^2 s_i/s_{-i}, }$$
(50)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_i m_{-i}} = 2\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]\left[1+\hat{\alpha}_{-i}\right], }$$
(51)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_{-i} m_{-i}} = -\frac{s_{i}}{\left[1-m_{-i}\right]^2}-2 \left[1+\hat{\alpha}_{i}\right]^2s_{-i}/s_{i}, }$$
(52)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_i \hat{\alpha}_i} = s_{-i} + \left[ 1+\hat{\alpha}_{-i}\right] Δ m^B, }$$
(53)
$$\eqalign{ N_{m_{-i} \hat{\alpha}_i} = s_{-i} - \left[1+\hat{\alpha}_i\right]Δ m^B s_{-i}/s_i . }$$
(54)

Inserting these equations, employing Eq. 34, and rearranging yields Eqs. 35 and 36, with \(\mid H\mid \equiv N_{m_im_i}N_{m_{-i}m_{-i}}-N_{m_i m_{-i}}N_{m_{-i} m_i}>0\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Facchini, G., Lorz, O. & Willmann, G. Asylum seekers in Europe: the warm glow of a hot potato. J Popul Econ 19, 411–430 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0059-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0059-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation