Skip to main content
Log in

Determinants of risk-taking: Behavioral and economic views

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The concept of risk-taking is examined from various perspectives: economic, decision theoretic, and psychological. Multiple factors are discussed as complicating the extraction of any presumed risk-taking propensity from a person's real-world behavior.Problem structuring, beliefs, andvalues (defined here as riskless as opposed to risky utility) may of course underlie differences in risk behavior. In addition,context andprocess factors can induce variance in risk-bearing. Also,portfolio effects (including cross-sectional, multiattribute, and longitudinal) may greatly complicate the measurement of risk-taking propensity. Lastly, the presence of incompletemarkets (via which risks can be partially diversified and traded) may further mask the link between intrinsic and observed risk-taking. This article examines each of these measurement obstacles and sources of variance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abelson, R. P. (1985). “A Variance Explanation Paradox: When a Little is a Lot,”Psychological Bulletin 97, 129–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allais, M. (1953). “Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulates et axioms de l'ecole Americaine,”Econometrica 21, 503–546.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1971).Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing. Chicago: Markham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashby, W. R. (1956).Introduction to Cybernetics. New York: John Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, J. W. (1957). “Motivational Determinants of Risk-Taking Behavior,”Psychological Review 64, 359–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Battalio, R. C., J. H. Kagel, and D. N. MacDonald (1985). “Animals' Choices over Uncertain Outcomes,”American Economic Review 75, 597–613.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1976).The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, D. E. (1982). “Regret in Decision Making Under Uncertainty,”Operations Research 30, 961–981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, D. E. and H. Raiffa (1982). “Marginal Value and Intrinsic Risk Aversion.” In H. Kunreuther (ed.),Risk: A Seminar Series. Laxenburg, Austria: International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, pp. 325–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentham, J. (1789).Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation, Anchor Press, Doubleday: NY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blume, M. E. and I. Friend. (1978)The Changing Role of the Individual Investor. New York: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordley, R. and G. Hazen. (1991). “SSB and Weighted Linear Utility as Expected Utility with Suspicion,”Management Science 37(4), 396–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowman, E. H. (1982). “Risk Seeking by Troubled Firms,”Sloan Management Review 23, 33–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunswik, E. (1952). “The Conceptual Framework of Psychology.” InInternational Encyclopedia of Unified Science, Vol. 1, No. 10. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchsbaum, M. S. (1971). “Neural Events and the Psychophysical Law,”Science 172, 502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cambell, D. T. and D. M. Fisk. “Convergent and Discriminant Validation by the Multitrait-Multimethod Matrix,”Psychological Bulletin 56, 81–105.

  • Camerer, C. (1989). “An Experimental Test of Several Generalized Utility Theories,”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 2, 61–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (1990). “Recent Tests of Generalizations of Expected Utility Theory.” In W. Edwards (ed.),Utility: Theories, Measurement and Applications (in press).

  • Chew, S. H. and L. G. Epstein. (1988). “The Law of Large Numbers and the Attractiveness of Compound Gambles,”Journal of Risk and Uncertainly 1(1), 25–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohn, R. A., W. G. Lewellen, and G. G. Schlarbaum. (1975). “Individual Investor Risk Aversion and Investment Portfolio Composition,”The Journal of Finance 30(2), 605–620.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coombs, C. H. (1975). “Portfolio Theory and the Measurement of Risk.” In M. F. Kaplan and S. Schwartz (eds.).Human Judgment and Decision Processes. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coombs, C. H. and C. S. Avrunin. “Single-Peaked Functions and the Theory of Preference,”Psychological Review 84, 216–230.

  • Cooms, C. H. and D. G. Pruitt. (1960). “Components of Risk in Decision Making: Probability and Variance Preference.,”Journal of Experimental Psychology 60, 256–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, T. E. and F. J. Weston. (1980).Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crandall, R. W. and J. D. Graham. (1984). “Automobile Safety Regulation and Offsetting Behavior: Some New Empirical Estimates,”American Economic Association: Papers and Proceedings 74(2), 328–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawes, R. M., and B. Corrigan. (1974). “Linear Models in Decision Making,”Psychological Bulletin 81, 97–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawes, R. M., D. Faust, and P. Meehl. (1989). “Clinical versus Actuarial Judgment,”Science 243, 1668–73.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Dekel, E. (1986). “An Axiomatic Characterization of Preferences Under Uncertainty: Weakening the Independence Axiom,”Journal of Economic Theory 40, 304–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. S. and R. K. Sarin. (1979). “Measurable Multiattribute Value Functions,”Operations Research 27, 810–822.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. S. and R. K. Sarin. (1982). “Relative Risk Aversion,”Management Science 28(8), 875–886.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, W. (1954). “Variance Preferences in Gambling,”American Journal of Psychology 67, 441–452.

    Google Scholar 

  • Einhorn, H. J. and R. M. Hogarth. (1986). “Decision Making Under Ambiguity,”Journal of Business 59(4) (pt. 2), 5225–5255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg, D. (1961). “Risk, Ambiguity, and the Savage Axioms,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 75, 643–669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, L. (1986). “Risk Homeostasis Theory and Traffic Accident Data,”Risk Analysis 6(1), 81–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1976).Foundations of Finance. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff, B., P. Slovic, and S. Lichtenstein. (1980). “Knowing What You Know: Measuring Labile Value.” In T. Wallsten (ed.),Cognitive Processes in Choice and Decision Behavior. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1983). “Transitive Measurable Utility,”Journal of Economic Theory 31, 31–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1988). “Expected Utility: An Anniversary and a New Era,”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1 (3), 267–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1965).The Theory of Interest. New York: August M. Kelly. (Reprinted from the 1930 edition.)

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. and B. Heggli. (1989). “An Ipsative Theory of Business Behavior,”Journal of Economic Psychology 10, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fulker, D., S. Eysenck, and M. Zuckerman. (1980). “A Genetic and Environmental Analysis of Sensation Seeking,”Journal of Research in Personality 14, 261–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, W. M. and H. Einhorn. (1987). “A Theory of Preference Reversals,”Psychological Review 94(2), 236–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, K. R., C. H. McClelland, and J. Mumpower. (1980).Human Judgment and Decision Making: Theories, Methods and Procedures. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harlow, W. V. (1988). “Economic Preferences and Risk-Aversion: An Alternative Perspective,” working paper, Dept. of Finance and Real Estate, University of Arizona.

  • Hershey, J. C. and P. J. H. Schoemaker. (1980). “Risk Taking and Problem Context in the Domain of Losses: An Expected Utility Analysis,”The Journal of Risk and Insurance 47, 111–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hershey, J. C. and P. J. H. Schoemaker. (1985). “Probability Versus Certainty Equivalence Methods in Utility Measurement: Are They Equivalent?”Management Science 31, 1213–1231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. and R. Allen. (1934). “A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value,”Economica (February), 52–75, 196–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogarth, R. M. (ed.). (1982). “Question Framing and Response Consistency.” InNew Directions for Methodology of Social and Behavioral Science. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

  • Jackson, D. N., L. Hourany, and N. J. Vidmar. (1972). “A Four-Dimensional Interpretation of Risk Taking,”Journal of Personality 40, 483–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J. and J. W. Payne. (1985). “Effort and Accuracy in Choice,”Management Science 31(4), 395–413.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J. and D. Schkade. (1989). “Bias in Utility Assessments: Further Evidence and Explanations,”Management Science 35, 406–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky. (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,”Econometrica 47, 263–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karn, E. (1979). “On Multivariate Risk Aversion,”Econometrica 47(6), 1391–1401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karn, E. (1985).Decision Making Under Uncertainty: The Case of State-Dependent Preferences. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karn, E. and Z. Safra. (1987). “ ‘Preference Reversal’ and the Observability of Preferences by Experimental Methods,”Econometrica 55, 675–685.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeney, R. L. and H. Raiffa. (1976).Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Tradeoffs. New York: John Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, L. R. (1985). “An Empirical Investigation of Relative Risk Aversion,”IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics SMC-15(4), 475–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemper, T. D. (1987). “How Many Emotions Are There? Wedding the Social and the Autonomic Components,”American Journal of Sociology 93(2), 263–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenrick, D. and D. Funder. (1988). “Profiting from Controversy: Lessons from the Person-Situation Debate,”American Psychologist 43(1), 23–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogan, N. and M. A. Wallach. (1967). “Risk Taking as a Function of the Situation, the Person, and the Group.” InNew Directions in Psychology, Vol. 3. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, pp. 111–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogan, N. and M. A. Wallach. (1964).Risk-Taking: A Study in Cognition and Personality. New York: Holt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, T. C. (1972). “Representation of Preference Orderings Over Time.” In C. B. McGuire and T. R. Radner (eds.).Decision and Organization, Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. M. and E. L. Porteus. (1979). “Temporal von Neumann-Morgenstern and Induced Preferences,”Journal of Economic Theory 20, 81–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kroll, Y., H. Levy, and A. Rapoport. (1988). “Experimental Tests of the Mean Variance Model for Portfolio Selection,”Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 42, 388–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., R. Ginsberg, L. Miller, et al. (1978).Disaster Insurance Protection: Public Policy Lessons. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langer, E. J. (1975). “The Illusion of Control,”Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32(2), 311–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, P. N. (1979). “Has the Mortality of Male Doctors Improved with the Reduction in Their Cigarette Smoking?”British Medical Journal 2, 1538–1540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, S. (1965). “Bases for Preferences Among Three-Outcome Bets,”Journal of Experimental Psychology 69, 162–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linville, P. W. (1982). “The Complexity-Extremity Effect and Age-Based Stereotyping,”Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 42(2), 193–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linville, P. W. and E. E. Jones. (1980). “Polarized Appraisals of Outgroup Members,”Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 38, 689–703.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. (1987). “Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption,”The Economic Journal 97, 666–684.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. (1988). “Frames of Mind in Intertemporal Choice,”Management Science 34, 200–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loomes, G. and S. Sugden. (1982). “Regret Theory: An Alternative Approach to Rational Choice under Uncertainty,”Economic Journal 92, 805–824.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopes, L. L. (1981). “Decision Making in the Short Run,”Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory 7(5), 377–385.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopes, L. L. (1987). “Between Hope and Fear: The Psychology of Risk,”Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 20, 255–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lund, A. K. and P. Zador. (1984). “Mandatory Belt Use and Driver Risk-Taking,”Risk Analysis 4(1), 41–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J. (1982). “ ‘Expected Utility’ Analysis Without the Independence Axiom,”Econometrica 50, 277–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J. (1984). “Temporal Risk and the Nature of Induced Preferences,”Journal of Economic Theory 33, 199–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J. (1989). “Dynamic Consistency and Non-Expected Utility Models of Choice Under Certainty,”Journal of Economic Literature (December), 1622–1668.

  • MacCrimmon, K. R. and D. A. Wehrung. (1986).Taking Risks: The Management of Uncertainty. The Free Press MacMillan, Inc. NY.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. (1978). “Bounded Rationality, Ambiguity, and the Engineering of Choice,”Bell Journal of Economics 9, 587–608.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. (1988). “Variable Risk Preferences and Adaptive Aspirations,”Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 9, 5–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. and Z. Shapira. (1987). “Managerial Perspectives on Risk and Risk Taking,”Management Science 33(11), 1404–1418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. M. (1952). “Portfolio Selection,”Journal of Finance 1, 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920).Principles of Economies. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maslow, A. H. (1954).Motivation and Personality. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • McClelland, D. C. (1961).The Achieving Society. Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand.

    Google Scholar 

  • McInish, T. H. (1982). “Individual Investors and Risk-Taking,”Journal of Economic Psychology 2, 125–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1971). “Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules,”Journal of Economic Theory 3, 378–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mischel, W. (1968).Personality and Assessment. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mischel, W. (1983). “Alternatives in the Pursuit of the Predictability and Consistency of Persons,”Journal of Personality 51, 578–604.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordquist, G. L. (1985). “On the Risk-Aversion Comparability of State-Dependent Utility Functions,”Theory and Decision 18, 287–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. W. (1973). “Alternative Approaches to Decision Making Under Risk: Moments vs. Risk Dimensions,”Psychological Bulletin 80(6), 493–553.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. (1982). “Contingent Decision Behavior,”Psychological Bulletin 92, 382–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J., J. Bettman, and E. Johnson. (1992). “Behavioral Decision Theory: A Cognitive Processing Perspective,”Annual Review of Psychology 43, 87–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1975). “The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation,”Journal of Political Economy 83, 677–725.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plax, T. G. and L. B. Rosenfeld (1976). “Correlates of Risky Decision-Making,”Journal of Personality Assessment 40(4).

  • Pratt, J. W. (1964). “Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large,”Econometrica 32, 122–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prelec, D. and G. Loewenstein. (1991). “Decision Making over Time and under Uncertainty: A Common Approach,”Management Science, 37(7), 770–786.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin, J. (1991). “Comparative Statistics for Rank-Dependent Expected Utility Theory,”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 4(4), 339–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raiffa, H. (1968).Decision Analysis. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A., R. Zwick, and S. G. Funk. (1988). “Selection of Portfolios With Risky and Riskless Assets: Experimental Tests of Two Expected Utility Models,”Journal of Economic Psychology 9, 169–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richard, S. F. (1975). “Multivariate Risk Aversion, Utility Independence and Separable Utility Functions,”Management Science 22(1), 12–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, D. S., J. M. Davis, A. Nies, C. L. Ravaris and D. Sylvester. (1971). “Relation of Sex and Aging to Monoamine Oxidase Activity of Human Brain, Plasma and Platelets,”Archives of General Psychiatry 24, 536–539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. (1977). “A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory's Tests,”Journal of Financial Economics (March), 129–176.

  • Rubinstein, M. (1976). “The Strong Case for the Generalized Logarithmic Utility Model as the Premier Model of Financial Markets,”Journal of Finance (May).

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1963). “Risk and Uncertainty: A Fallacy of Large Numbers,”Scientia (April–May), 1–6.

  • Savage, L. J. (1954).The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, S. L. and L. L. Lopes. (1986). “Reflection in Preferences Under Risk: Who and When May Suggest Why,”Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 12(4), 535–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1977). “Experimental Studies on Individual Decision Making Under Risk: An Information Processing Approach,” Ph.D. thesis, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1982). “The Expected Utility Model: Its Variants, Purposes, Evidence and Limitations,”Journal of Economic Literature 20, 529–563.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1990). “Are Risk-Attitudes Related Across Payoff Domains and Response Modes?”Management Science 36, 1451–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segal, U. (1987). “The Ellsberg Paradox and Risk Aversion: An Anticipated Utility Approach,”International Economic Review 28, 175–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selden, L. (1978). “A New Representation of Preferences Over ‘Certain x Uncertain’ Consumption Pairs: The ‘Ordinal Certainty Equivalent’ Hypothesis,”Econometrica 46(5), 1045–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shafer, G. (1986). “Savage Revisited,”Statistical Science 1(4), 463–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, S. (1957). “Level of Aspiration and Decision Making,”Psychological Review 64, 253–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1955). “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice,”Quarterly Journal of Economics 69, 99–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sloan, A. P. (1963).My Years with General Motors. New York: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P. (1972). “Information Processing, Situation Specificity, and the Generality of Risk-Taking Behavior,”Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 22(1), 128–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P. and S. Lichtenstein. (1968). “The Relative Importance of Probabilities and Payoffs in Risk Taking,”Journal of Experimental Psychology 78.

  • Slovic, P., and S. Lichtenstein. (1983). “Preference Reversals: A Broader Perspective,”American Economic Review 73, 596–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1904).The Wealth of Nations. Methuen.

  • Stigler, G. and G. Becker. (1977). “De gustibus non est disputandum,”American Economic Review 67(2), 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1985). “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice,”Marketing Science 4(3), 199–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torrance, P. and R. Ziller. (1957). “Risk and Life Experience: Development of a Scale for Measuring Risktaking Tendencies,” Research Report AFPTRC-TN-75-23, Crew Research Laboratory, Air Force Personnel and Training Research Center, Randolf Air Force Base, Texas, February.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. and M. Bar-Hillel. (1983). “Risk: The Long and the Short,”Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 9, 713–717.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. (1974). “Judgments Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases,”Science 185, 1124–1131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. (1981). “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice,”Science 211, 453–458.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman. (1986). “Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions,”Journal of Business 59(4) (pt. 2), 5251–5284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., S. Sattath, and P. Slovic. (1988). “Contingent Weighting In Judgment and Choice,”Psychological Review 95, 371–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1984). “The Lulling Effect: The Impact of Child-Resistant Packaging on Aspirin and Analgesic Ingestions,”American Economic Association: Papers and Proceedings 74(2), 324–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. and O. Morgenstern. (1947).Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Winterfeldt, D., F. H. Barron, and C. W. Fischer. (1980). “Theoretical and Empirical Relationships Between Risky and Riskless Utility Functions,” Technical report, Social Sciences Research Institute, University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagenaar, W. and G. Keren. (1988). “Chance and Luck Are Not the Same,Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 1(2), 65–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wehrung, D. A., K. R. MacCrimmon, and K. M. Brothers. (1984). “Utility Assessment: Domains, Stability, and Equivalence Procedures,”INFOR 22(2), 98–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, N. D. (1987).Taking Care: Understanding and Encouraging Self-Protective Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilde, G. J. S. (1982a). “The Theory of Risk Homeostatis: Implications for Safety,”Risk Analysis 2(4), 209–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilde, G. J. S. (1982b). “Critical Issues in Risk Homeostatis Theory,”Risk Analysis 2(4), 249–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilde, G. J. S. (1982c). “Incentive Systems for Accident-Free and Violation-Free Driving in the General Population,”Ergonomics 25(10), 879–890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, P. N. and V. R. Eidman. (1983). “An Empirical Test of the Interval Approach for Estimating Risk Preferences,”Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 8(2), 170–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, R. L. (1991). “Ambiguity, Probability, Preference and Decision Analysis,”Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 4(3), 285–298.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolf, C. and L. Pohlman. (1983). “The Recovery of Risk Preferences from Actual Choices,”Econometrica 51 (3), 843–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, M. (1984). “Sensation-Seeking: A Comparative Approach to a Human Trait,”The Behavioral and Brain Sciences 7, 413–471.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, M., J. C. Ballenger, D. C. Jimerson, D. L. Murphy and R. M. Post. (1983). “A Correlational Test in Humans of the Biological Models of Sensation Seeking, Impulsivity, and Anxiety.” In M. Zuckerman (ed.),Biological Bases of Sensation Seeking, Impulsivity, and Anxiety. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, pp. 229–248.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This paper has benefited from presentations at the University of Chicago's Center for Decision Research, the Managerial Economics workshop at the Harvard Business School, and the Annual Judgment and Decision Making Conference in Chicago. Lynd Bacon, Baruch Fischhoff, Robert Gertner, Robin Hogarth, Paul Kleindorfer, Howard Kunreuther, George Loewenstein, Richard Meyer, Ehud Ronn, J. Edward Russo, Peter Salovey and Elke Weber are especially acknowledged for their helpful comments. None bears responsibility for errors or omissions. This research was supported in part from NSF grant SES-8319065.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schoemaker, P.J.H. Determinants of risk-taking: Behavioral and economic views. J Risk Uncertainty 6, 49–73 (1993). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01065350

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01065350

Key words

Navigation