Skip to main content

Achieving Carbon Emissions Peak in China by 2030: The Key Options and Economic Impacts

  • Chapter
Post-2020 Climate Action

Abstract

This study investigates the options and sectors that are essential for China to achieve carbon emissions peak by 2030. A dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model is used to generate 14 scenarios from a scenario matrix incorporating three levels of carbon constraints and four options of low-carbon measures. Results suggest that if there is no policy intervention, China’s total CO2 emissions would reach 22.9 Gt in 2030. To cut carbon emissions required by the latest Intended Nationally Determined Contributions (INDC) or the global two-degree target, China should not only rely on optimizing industry structure or restricting its industry output, but more importantly, it should rely on low-carbon technologies in the power and end-use sectors as well as low-carbon style consumption. We also depict how the mitigation costs can be lowered through various low-carbon countermeasures, with which the carbon mitigation cost of achieving China’s INDC target in 2030 could be reduced from 155 USD/ton-CO2 to 35 USD/ton-CO2. The corresponding GDP loss could fall from 6.3% to merely 0.67%, and welfare will not be affected significantly.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Ashina S, Fujino J, Masui T, Ehara T, Hibino G (2012) A roadmap towards a low-carbon society in japan using backcasting methodology: feasible pathways for achieving an 80. Energy Policy 41:584–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bretschger L, Zhang L (2014) Carbon policy in a high-growth economy: the case of china. Available at SSRN 2466370

    Google Scholar 

  • Chai Q-M, Xu H-Q (2014) Modeling an emissions peak in china around 2030: synergies or trade-offs between economy, energy and climate security. Adv Clim Chang Res 5:169–180. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.accre.2015.06.001

  • Cheng B, Dai H, Wang P, Zhao D, Masui T (2015) Impacts of carbon trading scheme on air pollutant emissions in Guangdong province of china. Energy Sustain Dev 27:174–185

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Computer-aided of Engineering (CAE) (2011) China’s mid- and long-term energy development strategy: electricity, oil, gas, nuclear and environment, vol 1. Science Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dagoumas S, Barker TS (2010) Pathways to a low-carbon economy for the UK with the macro-econometric e3MG model. Energy Policy 38:3067–3077

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai H (2012) Integrated assessment of China’s provincial low carbon economy development towards 2030: Jiangxi province as an example. Tokyo, Tokyo Institute of Technology. PhD

    Google Scholar 

  • Dai H, Masui T, Matsuoka Y, Fujimori S (2011) Assessment of china’s climate commitment and non-fossil energy plan towards 2020 using hybrid aIM/CGE model. Energy Policy 39:2875–2887. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.02.062

  • Dai H, Masui T, Matsuoka Y, Fujimori S (2012) The impacts of china’s household consumption expenditure patterns on energy demand and carbon emissions towards 2050. Energy Policy 50:736–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai H, Mischke P, Xie X, Xie Y, Masui T (2016) Closing the gap? Top-down versus bottom-up projections of china’s regional energy use and CO2 emissions. Appl Energy 162:1355–1373

    Google Scholar 

  • Foran B (2011) Low carbon transition options for Australia. Ecol Model 223:72–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomi K, Shimada K, Matsuoka Y (2010) A low-carbon scenario creation method for a local-scale economy and its application in Kyoto city. Energy Policy 38:4783–4796

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertel TW, Tsigas ME (2004) Structure of GTAP. In: Hertel TW (ed) Global trade analysis: modeling and applications. Cambridge University Press, New York, p 48

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2006) IPCC guidelines for national greenhouse gas inventories. IGES, Japan

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2007) Climate change 2007: the physical science basis. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang K, Hu X (2009) China’s low carbon development scenario. In: 2050 China energy ST of, report CE, editors. 2050 china energy and CO2 emissions report. Science Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones R, Yoo B (2010) Korea’s green growth strategy: mitigating climate change and developing new growth engines. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Li W, Li H, Sun S (2015) China’s low-carbon scenario analysis of CO2 mitigation measures towards 2050 using a hybrid aIM/CGE model. Energies 8:3529–3555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masui T, Matsumoto K, Hijioka Y, Kinoshita T, Nozawa T, Ishiwatari S, Kato E, Shukla P, Yamagata Y, Kainuma M (2011) An emission pathway for stabilization at 6 Wm−2 radiative forcing. Clim Chang 109:59–76

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS) (1996–2006) China statistical year book: 1996–2006. China Statistics Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS) (2006) Input-output tables of China 2002. China Statistics Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS) (2008) China energy statistical year book 2008. China Statistics Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS) (2011) Input-output tables of china 2007. China Statistics Press, Beijing. (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  • National Development and Reform Commission of the People’s Republic of China (2012) Letter including autonomous domestic mitigation actions 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Paltsev S, Morris J, Cai Y, Karplus V, Jacoby H (2012) The role of china in mitigating climate change. Energy Econ 34:S444–S450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford TF (1999) Applied general equilibrium modeling with mPSGE as a gAMS subsystem: an overview of the modeling framework and syntax. Comput Econ 14:1–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selvakkumaran S, Limmeechokchai B, Masui T, Hanaoka T, Matsuoka Y (2015) A quantitative analysis of low carbon society (lCS) measures in Thai industrial sector. Renew Sust Energy Rev 43:178–195

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Shukla P, Dhar S, Mahapatra D (2008) Low-carbon society scenarios for India. Clim Pol 8:156–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skea J, Nishioka S (2008) Policies and practices for a low-carbon society. Clim Pol 8:5–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sue Wing I (2006) The synthesis of bottom-up and top-down approaches to climate policy modeling: Electric power technologies and the cost of limiting US CO2 emissions. Energy Policy 34(18):3847–3869

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sue Wing I (2008) The synthesis of bottom-up and top-down approaches to climate policy modeling: electric power technology detail in a social accounting framework. Energy Econ 30(2):547–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun J, Ang B (2000) Some properties of an exact energy decomposition model. Energy 25(12):1177–1188

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Thepkhun P, Limmeechokchai B, Fujimori S, Masui T, Shrestha RM (2013) Thailand’s low-carbon scenario 2050: the aIM/CGE analyses of cO 2 mitigation measures. Energy Policy 62:561–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN (2008) World population prospects: the 2008 revision population database, United Nations

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang T, Watson J (2010) Scenario analysis of china’s emissions pathways in the 21st century for low carbon transition. Energy Policy 38:3537–3546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Zou L-L (2014) The economic impact of emission peaking control policies and china’s sustainable development. Adv Clim Chang Res 5:162–168. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.accre.2015.05.001

  • Wang P, Dai H-C, Ren S-Y, Zhao D-Q, Masui T (2015) Achieving Copenhagen target through carbon emission trading: economic impacts assessment in Guangdong province of China. Energy 79:212–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang D, Rausch S, Karplus VJ, Zhang X (2013) Quantifying regional economic impacts of CO2 intensity targets in China. Energy Econ 40:687–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang S, Bauer N, Luderer G, Kriegler E (2014) Role of technologies in energy-related CO2 mitigation in china within a climate-protection world: a scenarios analysis using rEMIND. Appl Energy 115:445–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou N, Fridley D, Khanna NZ, Ke J, McNeil M, Levine M (2013) China’s energy and emissions outlook to 2050: perspectives from bottom-up energy end-use model. Energy Policy 53:51–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This study was supported by the Environmental Research and Technology Development Fund (S-12-2 and 2-1402) of the Ministry of the Environment, Government of Japan. The authors are grateful for the comments from the anonymous reviewers of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hancheng Dai .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: The CGE Model

The appendix provides a technical description of the CGE model based on Dai (2012).

6.1.1 Production

Each producer maximizes profit subject to the production technology. Activity output of each sector follows a nested constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function. Each sector has two types of production function: one uses the existing capital stock, and another uses new investment (Dai et al. 2011). The difference between these two subsectors is the efficiency and mobility of capital among the sectors. Inputs are categorized into material commodities, energy commodities, land, labor, capital, and resource.

The producer maximizes its profit by choosing its output level and input use, depending on their relative prices subject to its technology. The producer’s problem can be expressed as

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}={p}_{r, j}\bullet {Z}_{r, j}-\left(\sum_{i=1}^N{p}_{r, i}\bullet {X}_{r, i, j}+\sum_{i=1}^N{\omega}_{r, f}\bullet {V}_{r, f, j}\right) $$
(6.5)

subject to

$$ {Z}_{r, j}={\upsilon}_{r, j}\left[{X}_{r,1, j,}{X}_{r,2, j,}\dots, {X}_{r, N, j,};{V}_{r,1, j,}\dots, {V}_{r, F, j\ }\right] $$
(6.6)

where

πr , j::

Profit of j-th producers in region r

Zr , j::

Output of j-th sector in region r

Xr , i , j::

Intermediate inputs of i-th goods in j-th sector in region r

Vr , f , j::

f-th primary factor inputs in j-th sector in region r

pr , j::

Price of the j-th composite commodity

ωr , f::

f-th factor price in region r

υr , j::

Share parameter in the CES production function

Industrial sectors are classified into basic, energy transformation, and power generation sectors.

6.1.1.1 Basic Sectors

For the basic production functions, activity output is determined by a fixed coefficient aggregation of non-energy and energy intermediate commodities and primary factors (Fig. 6.9). The composite of non-energy inputs is in Leontief form. Energy and the value-added bundle are nested by value-added and energy inputs. The value-added bundle is a CES function of primary factors. The composite of energy inputs is a CES aggregation of electricity and fossil fuels. Fossil fuels are further disaggregated into five types:

Fig. 6.9
figure 9figure 9

Production tree of basic sectors

There are four levels in the above production tree. At each level a virtual firm is assumed, each of which aims to maximize the corresponding profit subject to the production technology.

At the top level, output is a Leontief function of the quantities of value-added and aggregate energy input and aggregate intermediate input, associated with process GHG emissions:

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}^z={p}_{r, j}^z\bullet {Z}_{r, j}-\left({p}_{r, j}^{vae}\bullet {QVAE}_{r, j}+{p}_{r, j}^{inta}\bullet {QINTA}_{r, j}+{p}_r^{ghg}\bullet {QGHG}_{r, j, act, ghg}\right) $$
(6.7)

subject to

$$ {Q}_{r, j}=\mathit{\min}\left(\frac{{ Q VAE}_{r, j}}{qvae_{r, j}},\frac{{ Q INTA}_{r, j}}{qinta_{r, j}},\frac{{ Q GHG}_{r, j, act, ghg}}{qghg_{r, j, act, ghg}}\right) $$
(6.8)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^z \)::

Profit of the j-th firm producing gross domestic output zr , j at the top level

Zr , j::

Gross domestic output of the j-th firm

Qr , j::

Output in sector j of region r

QVAEr , j::

Value-added and energy composite input

QINTAr , j::

Composite intermediate input

QGHGr , j , act , ghg::

Process emissions of GHGs per unit of output

\( {p}_{r, j}^z \)::

Price of j-th gross domestic output

\( {p}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

Price of composite goods of factor and energy

\( {p}_{r, j}^{inta} \)::

Price of composite intermediate goods

\( {p}_r^{ghg} \)::

GHG emission price

qvaer , j::

Technical coefficient expressing the composite amounts of value-added and energy inputs required per unit of Qr , j

qintar , j::

Technical coefficient expressing the composite amounts of non-energy intermediate inputs required per unit of Qr , j

qghgr , j , act , ghg::

Technical coefficient expressing the process GHG emissions per unit of Qr , j

At the second level of the production tree, there are two virtual firms with profit-maximization problems. First, composite value-added and energy input is CES aggregation of value-added input and total energy input:

$$ \max {\ \pi}_{r, j}^{va e}={p}_{r, j}^{va e}\bullet {QVA E}_{r, j}-\left({p}_{r, j}^{va}\bullet {QVA}_{r, j}+{p}_{r, j}^{fe}\bullet {QFE}_{r, j}\right) $$
(6.9)

subject to

$$ {QVA E}_{r, j}={\alpha}_{r, j}^{vae}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r, j}^{vae}\bullet {QVA}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{vae}}+\left(1-{\delta}_{r, j}^{vae}\right)\bullet {QFE}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{vae}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r, j}^{vae}}} $$
(6.10)

Second, aggregate non-energy intermediate input is defined as Leontief function of disaggregated intermediate input:

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}^{i nta}={p}_{r, j}^{i nta}\bullet {QINT A}_{r, j}-\left(\sum_i{p}_{r, j}^q\bullet {QINT}_{r, i, j}\right) $$
(6.11)

subject to

$$ { QINT A}_{r, j}=\mathit{\min}\left(\frac{QINT_{r, i, j}}{qint_{r, i, j}}\right) $$
(6.12)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

Profit of j-th firm producing composite input of value added and energy

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^{inta} \)::

Profit of j-th firm producing composite intermediate input

QVAr , j::

Aggregate value-added input

QFEr , j::

Aggregate energy input (electricity and fossil energy)

QINTr , i , j::

i-th non-energy inputs in j-th firm

\( {p}_{r, j}^{va} \)::

Price of composite value-added input

\( {p}_{r, j}^{fe} \)::

Price of the composite energy input (including electricity and fossil fuel)

\( {p}_{r, j}^q \)::

Price of the i-th composite goods

qintr , i , j::

The amounts of each input required per unit of composite intermediate input

\( {\alpha}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the CES function

\( {\delta}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

CES share parameter, \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, j}^{vae}\le 1,\ \sum_i{\delta}_{r, j}^{vae}=1 \)

\( {\rho}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

The CES substitution parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between value added and energy, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{1+\rho} \)

\( {\sigma}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

Elasticity of substitution between value-added bundle and energy

At the third level of the production tree, there are two virtual firms with profit-maximization problems as well. First, composite value-added input is CES aggregation of capital and labor input:

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}^{va}={p}_{r, j}^{va}\bullet {QVA}_{r, j}-\left({ p l}_r\bullet {QLAB}_{r, j}+{ p k}_{r, j}\bullet {QCAP}_{r, j}\right) $$
(6.13)

subject to

$$ {QVA}_{r, j}={\alpha}_{r, j}^{va}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r, j}^{cap}\bullet {QCAP}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{va}}+{\delta}_{r, j}^{lab}\bullet {QLAB}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{va}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r, j}^{va}}} $$
(6.14)

Moreover, composite energy input is CES aggregation of electricity input and fossil fuel input:

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}^{fe}={p}_{r, j}^{fe}\bullet {QFE}_{r, j}-\left({p}_{r,{}^{``} ele"}^q\bullet {QELE}_{r, j}+{p}_{r, j}^{fos}\bullet {QFOS}_{r, j}\right) $$
(6.15)

subject to

$$ {QFE}_{r, j}={\alpha}_{r, j}^{fe}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r, j}^{ele}\bullet {QELE}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{fe}}+\left(1-{\delta}_{r, j}^{ele}\right)\bullet {QFOS}_{r, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{fe}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r, j}^{fe}}} $$
(6.16)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^{va} \)::

Profit of j-th firm producing composite input of value added

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^{fe} \)::

Profit of j-th firm producing composite input of energy

QCAPr , j::

Capital input required per unit of value-added input

QLABr , j::

Labor input required per unit of value-added input

QELEr , j::

Electricity input required per unit of composite energy input

QFOSr , j::

Composite fossil fuel input required per unit of composite energy input

pl r ::

Labor price in region r

pkr , j::

Capital price in j-th sector of region r

\( {p}_{r,`` ele"}^q \)::

Price of the composite goods of electricity

\( {p}_{r, j}^{fos} \)::

Price of composite fossil fuel input in j-th sector

\( {\alpha}_{r, j}^{fe} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the CES function

\( {\delta}_{r, j}^{fe},{\delta}_{r, j}^{cap},{\delta}_{r, j}^{lab} \)::

CES share parameters, \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, j}^{\ast}\le 1,\ \sum_i{\delta}_{r, j}^{\ast }=1 \)

\( {\rho}_{r, j}^{fe} \)::

CES substitution parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between electricity and composite fossil fuel, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{1+\rho} \)

\( {\sigma}_{r, j}^{va} \)::

Elasticity of substitution between capital and labor

\( {\sigma}_{r, j}^{vae} \)::

Elasticity of substitution between electricity and fossil fuel

At the fourth level of the production function, composite fossil fuel is CES aggregation of coal, crude oil, natural gas, coke, petrol oil, and manufactured gas:

$$ \max\ {\pi}_{r, j}^{fos}={p}_{r, j}^{fos}\bullet {QFOS}_{r, j}-\left(\sum_{fos}{p}_{r, fos}^q\bullet {QFF}_{r, fos, j}\right) $$
(6.17)

subject to

$$ {QFOS}_{r, j}={\alpha}_{r, j}^{ff}\bullet {\left(\sum_{fos}{\delta}_{r, j}^{ff}\bullet {QFF}_{r, fos, j}^{{-\rho}_{r, j}^{ff}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r, j}^{ff}}} $$
(6.18)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, j}^{fos} \)::

Profit of j-th firm producing composite input of fossil fuel

QFFr , fos , j::

CES shift (or efficiency) parameter

\( {p}_{r, fos}^q \)::

Price of fossil fuel input

\( {\alpha}_{r, j}^{ff} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the CES function

\( {\delta}_{r, j}^{ff} \)::

CES share parameter, \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, j}^{ff}\le 1,\ \sum_i{\delta}_{r, j}^{ff}=1 \)

\( {\rho}_{r, j}^{ff} \)::

CES substitution parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution among fossil fuels, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{1+\rho} \)

\( {\sigma}_{r, j}^{ff} \)::

Elasticity of substitution among fossil fuels

6.1.1.2 Energy Transformation Sector (Except Power Generation)

Energy transformation sectors include gas production and supply, petroleum and nuclear fuel processing, and coking. The energy bundle is linked at the top level in order to maintain the first law of thermal efficiency of the conversion of primary energy to the secondary energy (Fig. 6.10). Functions at other levels are the same as the basic sectors.

Fig. 6.10
figure 10figure 10

Production tree of energy transformation sectors

Thus the problem is expressed in

$$ \begin{array}{ll} \max\ {\pi}_{r,j}^z=& {p}_{r,j}^z\bullet {Z}_{r,j}\hfill \\ {}& -\left({p}_{r,j}^{vae}\bullet {\mathit{\mathrm{QVAE}}}_{r,j}+{p}_{r,j}^{fe}\bullet {QFE}_{r,j}+{p}_{r,j}^{\mathit{\mathrm{inta}}}\bullet {\mathit{\mathrm{QINTA}}}_{r,j}+{p}_r^{ghg}\bullet {\mathit{\mathrm{QGHG}}}_{r,j, act, ghg}\right)\ \hfill \end{array} $$
(6.19)

subject to

$$ {Q}_{r, j}=\mathit{\min}\left(\frac{{ Q VAE}_{r, j}}{qvae_{r, j}},\frac{{ Q FE}_{r, j}}{qfe_{r, j}},\frac{{ Q INTA}_{r, j}}{qinta_{r, j}},\frac{{ Q GHG}_{r, j, act, ghg}}{qghg_{r, j, act, ghg}}\right) $$
(6.20)

where

QFEr , j::

Aggregate energy input (electricity and fossil energy)

qfer , j::

Technical coefficient expressing the aggregate energy inputs required per unit of Qr , j

6.1.1.3 Power Generation Sector

Electricity is generated by eight technologies, e.g., coal, gas, oil, nuclear, hydro, wind, solar PV, and biomass power. Disaggregation of the electricity sector into eight technologies in the base year follows the methodology developed by Sue Wing (2006, 2008). Production function of each technology is the same as that of energy transformation sectors. Each technology is perfectly substitutable with another. Electricity output is almost in a linear relationship with energy inputs (Fig. 6.11).

Fig. 6.11
figure 11figure 11

Production tree of electricity generation sectors

6.1.1.4 Household Consumption

Household and government are the final consumers. The representative household endows primary factors to the firms and receives income from the rental of primary factors (labor and capital), rents from fixed factors (land and natural resources), and lump-sum transfer from the government (e.g., carbon tax revenue of the government). The income is then used for either investment or final consumption. The objective of household consumption is to maximize utility by choosing levels of goods consumption following Cobb-Douglas preferences, subject to commodity prices and budget constraint. The agent’s problem is expressed as

$$ \max\ {u}_{r, h}\left[{X}_{r,1}^p,\dots, {x}_{r, i}^p\right]={A}_r^p\bullet \prod_{i=1}^N{\left({X}_{r, i}^p\right)}^{\alpha_{r, i}^p} $$
(6.21)

subject to

$$ {EH}_r=\sum_i{p}_{r, j}^q\bullet {X}_{r, i}^p=\sum_{f=1}^F{\omega}_{r, f}\bullet {V}_{r, f}+\sum_j{p ld}_r\bullet {QLAND}_{r, j}+ \sum_{r es, j}{p}_{r, j}^{r es}\bullet {QRES}_{r, j}+{T}_r^{cab}-{T}_r^d-{S}_r^p $$
(6.22)
$$ {T}_r^{cab}={pghg}_{r,`` CO2"}\bullet {\mathrm{TEMS}}_{r,`` CO2"} $$
(6.23)
$$ {T}_r^d={\tau}_r^d\bullet \sum_f{\omega}_{r, f}\bullet {V}_{r, f} $$
(6.24)
$$ {S}_r^p={sr}_r^p\bullet \sum_f{\omega}_{r, f}\bullet {V}_{r, f} $$
(6.25)

where

ur , h::

Utility function of households

EH r ::

Household expenditure

\( {X}_{r, i}^p \)::

Household consumption of i-th commodity

Vr , f::

f-th primary factor endowment by household

\( {S}_r^p \)::

Household savings

TEMSr ,  “ CO2”::

CO2 emissions in region r

pghgr ,  “ CO2”::

Carbon price

\( {T}_r^d \)::

Direct tax

\( {\tau}_r^d \)::

Direct tax rate

\( {sr}_r^p \)::

Average propensity to save by the household

ωr , f::

Price of the f-th primary factor

\( {A}_r^p \)::

Scaling parameter in Cobb-Douglas function

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^p \)::

Share parameter in Cobb-Douglas function, \( 0\le {\alpha}_{r, i}^p\le 1,\ \sum_i{\alpha}_{r, i}^p=1 \)

6.1.2 Government

The government is assumed to collect taxes, including a direct tax on household income, ad valorem production tax (indirect tax) on gross domestic output, ad valorem import tariff on imports, and carbon tax. Based on a Cobb-Douglas demand function (Hertel and Tsigas 2004), the government spends its revenue on public services which are provided to the whole society and on the goods and services which are provided to the households free of charge or at low prices (NBS 2006). The model assumes that the revenue from the carbon tax is recycled to the representative agent as a lump-sum transfer:

$$ \max\ {u}_{r, g}\left[{x}_{r,1}^g,\dots, {x}_{r, i}^g\right]={A}_r^g\bullet \prod_{i=1}^N{\left({x}_{r, i}^g\right)}^{\alpha_{r, i}^g} $$
(6.26)

subject to

$$ \sum_i{p}_{r, i}\bullet {x}_{r, i}^g={T}_r^d+\sum_j{T}_{r, j}^z+\sum_j{T}_{r, j}^m-{S}^g $$
(6.27)
$$ {T}_{r, j}^z={\tau}_{r, j}^z\bullet {p}_{r, j}\bullet {Z}_{r, j} $$
(6.28)
$$ {T}_{r, i}^m={\tau}_{r, i}^m\bullet {pm}_{r, i}\bullet {M}_{r, i} $$
(6.29)
$$ {S}_r^g={sr}_r^g\bullet \left({T}_r^d+\sum_j{T}_{r, j}^z+\sum_j{T}_{r, j}^m\right) $$
(6.30)

where

ur , g::

Utility function of government

\( {x}_{r, i}^g \)::

Government consumption of i-th commodity

\( {S}_r^g \)::

Government savings

\( {T}_{r, j}^z \)::

Production tax on the j-th commodity

\( {T}_{r, j}^m \)::

Import tariff on the j-th commodity

\( {\tau}_{r, j}^z \)::

Production tax rate on the j-th commodity

\( {\tau}_{r, i}^m \)::

Import tariff rate on the i-th commodity

\( {sr}_r^g \)::

Average propensity to save by the government

Zr , j::

Gross domestic output of the j-th commodity

Mr , i::

Import of the i-th commodity

pmr , i::

Price of the i-th imported commodity

\( {A}_r^g \)::

Scaling parameter in Cobb-Douglas function

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^g \)::

Share parameter in Cobb-Douglas function, \( 0\le {\alpha}_{r, i}^g\le 1,\ \sum_i{\alpha}_{r, i}^g=1 \)

6.1.3 Investment and Savings

Investment is an important part of the final demand. In the CGE model, a virtual agent is assumed for investment which receives all the savings from the household, the government, and the external sector to purchase goods for domestic investment. The virtual investment agent is assumed to maximize the utility based on a Cobb-Douglas demand function subject to its (virtual) income constraint. Mathematically, the investment problems can be described as follows:

$$ \max\ {u}_{r, v}\left[{x}_{r,1}^v,\dots, {x}_{r, i}^v\right]={A}_r^v\bullet \prod_{i=1}^N{\left({x}_{r, i}^v\right)}^{\alpha_{r, i}^v} $$
(6.31)

subject to

$$ \sum_i{p}_{r, i}\bullet {x}_{r, i}^v={S}_r^p+{S}_r^g+\varepsilon \bullet {S}_r^f $$
(6.32)

where

ur , v::

Utility of virtual investment agent

\( {S}_r^f \)::

Current account deficits in foreign currency terms (or alternatively foreign savings)

ε::

Foreign exchange rate

\( {x}_{r,1}^v \)::

Demand for the i-th investment goods

\( {A}_r^v \)::

Scaling parameter in Cobb-Douglas function,

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^v \)::

Share parameter in Cobb-Douglas function, \( 0\le {\alpha}_{r, i}^v\le 1,\ \sum_i{\alpha}_{r, i}^v=1 \)

6.1.4 International Transaction

The model is an open economy model that includes the interaction of commodity trade with the rest of the world. Like most other countries’ CGE models, this model assumes the small open economy, meaning that an economy is small enough for its policies not to alter world prices or incomes. The implicit implication of small-country assumption is that export and import prices are exogenously given for the economy. In this study, future international prices are fixed to be the same level for non-energy commodities but increase by 3% yearly for energy commodities compared to the 2005 level.

Two types of price variables are distinguished. One is prices in terms of the domestic currency \( {p}_i^e \) and \( {p}_i^m \); the other is prices in terms of the foreign currency \( {p}_i^{We} \) and \( {p}_i^{Wm} \). They are linked with each other as follows:

$$ {p}_i^e=\varepsilon \bullet {p}_i^{We} $$
(6.33)
$$ {p}_i^m=\varepsilon \bullet {p}_i^{Wm} $$
(6.34)

Furthermore, it is assumed that the economy faces balance of payments constraints, which is described with export and import prices in foreign currency terms:

$$ \sum_i{p}_i^{We}\bullet {E}_{r, i}+{S}_r^f=\sum_i{p}_i^{Wm}\bullet {M}_i $$
(6.35)

where

Er , i::

Export of i-th commodity in region r

Mr , i::

Import of i-th commodity in region r

\( {p}_i^{We} \)::

Export price in terms of foreign currency,

\( {p}_i^e \)::

Export price in terms of domestic currency

\( {p}_i^{Wm} \)::

Import price in terms of foreign currency,

\( {p}_i^m \)::

Import price in terms of domestic currency

6.1.4.1 Substitution Between Imports and Domestic Goods

The Armington assumption is adopted, i.e., the domestic and imported goods are imperfectly substitutable for each other, which implies that households and firms don’t directly consume or use imported goods but instead a so-called Armington composite goods, which is made up of imported and locally produced goods as well as goods produced in other provinces by a two-level nested CES function (Fig. 6.12).

Fig. 6.12
figure 12figure 12

Nesting of imported goods, locally produced goods, and goods produced in other provinces

Import activity is described by the bottom nesting of Fig. 6.12. In the CGE model, the Armington composite goods at this level are created by virtual firms which maximize their profits by choosing a proper combination of imported and locally produced goods. The solution of their profit-maximization problem leads to their input demands for imported and domestic goods, which depend on the corresponding relative prices of domestic and imported goods. Mathematically, this problem can be expressed as

$$ \mathrm{Max}\ {\pi}_{r, i}^{m d}={p}_{r, i}^{m d}\bullet {Q}_{r, i}^{m d}-\left[\left(1+{\tau}_{r, i}^m\right)\bullet {p}_i^m\bullet {M}_{r, i}+{p}_{r, i}^d\bullet {D}_{r, i}^d\right] $$
(6.36)

subject to

$$ {Q}_{r, i}^{m d}={\alpha}_{r, i}^{m d}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r, i}^m\bullet {M}_{r, i}^{{-\rho}_{r, i}^{m d}}+{\delta}_{r, j}^d\bullet {D}_{r, i}^{{-\rho}_{r, i}^{m d}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r, i}^{m d}}} $$
(6.37)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, i}^{md} \)::

Profit of the firm producing the i-th Armington composite goods of import and locally produced goods

\( {Q}_{r, i}^{md} \)::

The i-th Armington composite goods of import and locally produced goods

\( {D}_{r, i}^d \)::

The i-th locally produced goods

\( {p}_{r, i}^{md} \)::

Armington price of the i-th imported and locally produced goods

\( {p}_{r, i}^d \)::

Price of the i-th locally produced goods

\( {\tau}_{r, i}^m \)::

Import tariff rate on the i-th commodity

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^{md} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the Armington composite goods production function

\( {\delta}_{r, i}^m \), \( {\delta}_{r, j}^d \)::

Input share parameters in the Armington composite goods production function (\( {0\le \delta}_{r, i}^m\le 1 \), \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, j}^d\le 1 \), \( {\delta}_{r, i}^m+{\delta}_{r, i}^d=1 \))

\( {\rho}_{r, i}^{md} \)::

The CES substitution parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between imported and domestic goods, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{1+\rho} \)

Then the composite imported and locally produced goods will be further aggregated with the goods produced in other provinces to form the final Armington composite goods that are consumed by households and the government and as intermediate inputs by firms, which will be introduced in section F.

6.1.4.2 Transformation Between Exports and Domestic Goods

On the supply side, the produced commodities are distributed to the international market, local market, and market in other provinces by a two-level nested constant elasticity of transformation function. Similar to the treatment of import, a virtual firm is assumed for each commodity which transforms the gross domestic output into exports and domestic goods as follows:

$$ \mathrm{Max}\ {\pi}_{r, i}^{dx}=\left({p}_i^e\bullet {E}_{r, i}+{p}_{r, i}^{dd}\bullet {D}_{r, i}^s\right)-\left(1+{\tau}_{r, i}^z\right)\bullet {p}_{r, i}^z\bullet {Q}_{r, i}^{dx} $$
(6.38)

subject to

$$ {Q}_{r, i}^{d x}={\alpha}_{r, i}^{d x}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r, i}^e\bullet {E}_{r, i}^{\rho_{r, i}^{d x}}+{\delta}_{r, j}^d\bullet {D_{r, i}^s}^{\rho_{r, i}^{d x}}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\rho_{r, i}^{d x}}} $$
(6.39)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, i}^{dx} \)::

Profit of the firm engaged in the i-th transformation

\( {Q}_{r, i}^{dx} \)::

Gross domestic output of the i-th goods

\( {D}_{r, i}^s \)::

i-th goods supplied to domestic market

\( {p}_{r, i}^z \)::

Price of the i-th gross domestic output

\( {p}_{r, i}^{dd} \)::

Price of domestically supplied goods

\( {\tau}_{r, i}^z \)::

Production tax rate on the i-th commodity

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^{dx} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the transformation function

\( {\delta}_{r, i}^e \), \( {\delta}_{r, j}^d \)::

Share parameters in the transformation function (\( {0\le \delta}_{r, i}^e\le 1 \), \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, j}^d\le 1 \), \( {\delta}_{r, i}^e+{\delta}_{r, i}^d=1 \))

\( {\rho}_{r, i}^{dx} \)::

Transformation elasticity parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between imported and domestic goods, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{\rho -1} \)

It should be noted that the goods supplied to the domestic market at this level, \( {D}_{r, i}^s \), will be further distributed to local market and market in other provinces through interprovincial trade, which will be described in the next section.

6.1.5 Interprovincial Trade

An important feature of this model is that it is a country model in which interprovincial trade is treated. Similar to the case of international trade, Armington assumption is adopted to distinguish between locally produced commodity and commodity produced by firms in other provinces, and CES and CET functions are employed to describe commodity inflow from and outflow to all provinces, respectively.

6.1.5.1 Substitution Commodity Between Local Market and Inflow from Other Provinces

This section describes the top-level nesting of Fig. 6.12 which treats interprovincial inflow of commodity. By this stage the commodity in the local market is an aggregation of locally produced and imported goods, which needs to be further aggregated with goods produced in other provinces to form the final Armington composite goods to be consumed by the final consumers and firms. The treatment is similar to import:

$$ \mathrm{Max}\ {\pi}_{r, i}^{dd}={p}_{r, i}^a\bullet {Q}_{r, i}^{dd}-\left[{p}_{r, i}^{md}\bullet {Q}_{r, i}^{md}+\sum_{r r}{p}_{r r, i}^{inf}\bullet {D}_{r r, r, i}^{inf}\right] $$
(6.40)

subject to

$$ {Q}_{r,i}^{dd}={\alpha}_{r,i}^{dd}\bullet {\left({\delta}_{r,i}^{md}\bullet {Q_{r,i}^{md}}^{{-\rho}_{r,i}^{dd}}+\sum_{rr}{\delta}_{rr,r,i}^{inf}\bullet {D_{rr,r,i}^{inf}}^{{-\rho}_{r,i}^{dd}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\rho_{r,i}^{dd}}} $$
(6.41)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, i}^{dd} \)::

Profit of the firm producing the i-th Armington composite goods of local market and inflow from other provinces

\( {Q}_{r, i}^{dd} \)::

Armington composite goods

\( {D}_{rr, r, i}^{inf} \)::

The i-th goods inflowing from region rr to region r

\( {p}_{r, i}^a \)::

Armington price taken by the final consumers and firms

\( {p}_{rr, i}^{inf} \)::

Price of the i-th goods inflowing from province rr to region r

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^{dd} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the Armington composite goods production function

\( {\delta}_{r, i}^{md} \), \( {\delta}_{rr, r, j}^{inf} \)::

Input share parameters in the Armington composite goods production function (\( {0\le \delta}_{r, i}^{md}\le 1 \), \( 0\le {\delta}_{rr, r, j}^{inf}\le 1 \), \( {\delta}_{r, i}^{md}+\sum_{r r}{\delta}_{r r, r, i}^{inf}=1 \))

\( {\rho}_{r, i}^{dd} \)::

The CES substitution parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between imported and domestic goods, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{1+\rho} \)

6.1.5.2 Transformation Between Goods Sold in Local Market and Outflowing to Other Provinces

Goods supplied to the domestic market, \( {D}_{r, i}^s \), will be further distributed to local market and market in other provinces through, similar to the treatment of export, a CET function as follows:

$$ \mathrm{Max}\ {\pi}_{r, i}^{p p}=\left({p}_i^d\bullet {D}_{r, i}^{local}+\sum_{r r}{p}_{r r, i}^{out}\bullet {D}_{r, rr, i}^{out}\right)-{p}_{r, i}^{d d}\bullet {D}_{r, i}^s $$
(6.42)

subject to

$$ {\mathrm{Q}}_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{pp}}={\upalpha}_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{pp}}\bullet {\left({\updelta}_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{local}}\bullet {D_{r,i}^{\mathit{\mathrm{local}}}}^{\rho_{r,i}^{pp}}+\sum_{rr}{\updelta}_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{rr},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{out}}\bullet {{\mathrm{D}}_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{rr},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{out}}}^{\uprho_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{pp}}}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\uprho_{\mathrm{r},\mathrm{i}}^{\mathrm{pp}}}} $$
(6.43)

where

\( {\pi}_{r, i}^{pp} \)::

Profit of the firm engaged in the i-th transformation

\( {Q}_{r, i}^{pp} \)::

Out of the i-th goods supplied to local and other provinces’ markets

\( {D}_{r, i}^{local} \)::

i-th goods supplied to local market

\( {D}_{r, rr, i}^{out} \)::

i-th goods outflowing from region r to other province rr

\( {p}_{rr, i}^{out} \)::

Price of the i-th goods outflowing to other province rr

\( {\alpha}_{r, i}^{pp} \)::

Shift (or efficiency) parameter in the transformation function

\( {\delta}_{r, i}^{local} \), \( {\delta}_{r, rr, i}^{out} \)::

Share parameters in the transformation function (\( {0\le \delta}_{r, i}^{local}\le 1 \), \( 0\le {\delta}_{r, rr, j}^{out}\le 1 \), \( {\delta}_{r, i}^{local}+\sum_{r r}{\delta}_{r, rr, i}^{out}=1 \))

\( {\rho}_{r, i}^{pp} \)::

Transformation elasticity parameter, in which the elasticity of substitution between imported and domestic goods, σ, equals \( \frac{1}{\rho -1} \)

6.1.6 Market Clearance Conditions

The above sections describe the behavior of economic agents such as the households, firms, government, and investment agents and the interactions with other provinces and the rest of the world. The final step is to impose the market-clearing conditions to all commodities and factor markets as follows:

$$ {Q}_{r, i}={x}_{r, i}^p+{x}_{r, i}^g+{x}_{r, i}^v+\sum_j{x}_{r, i, j} $$
(6.44)
$$ \sum_j{v}_{r, f, j}={V}_{r, f} $$
(6.45)

6.1.7 Macro Closure

In a CGE model, the issue of macro closure is the choice of exogenous variables among all variables in the model, mainly including investment and saving macro closure and current account balance macro closure. In this model, investment is exogenously assumed. In addition, foreign exchange rate is fixed and thus balance of payment is an endogenous variable.

Appendix 2: The Decomposition Method

The appendix describes how carbon reduction can be attributed to each countermeasure in section 4.3.1 by decomposition techniques. As shown in Eq. 6.46, the total carbon emission (EM) is the summation of emissions from power generation (EMele) and end-use sectors (EMend) minus emissions captured by CCS technology (EMccs). EMend and EMele can be further broken down into subcomponents. In Eq. 6.47, EMend is a product of the underlying factors of activity levels (GDP), industry structure (STR = VAi/GDP), end-use energy efficiency (EFF = Ei/VAi), and fuel-switch factor (FS = EMi/Ei). Similarly, in Eq. 6.48, emission from power generation (EMele) is a product of the underlying factors of total electricity demand (ELEtot), non-fossil-fired electricity (NF = ELEfos/ELEtot), and power generation efficiency (EFF = EMele/ELEfos):

$$ \mathrm{EM}={\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{end}}+{\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ele}}\hbox{--} {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ccs}} $$
(6.46)
$$ {\mathrm{E}\mathrm{M}}_{\mathrm{end}}={\Sigma}_{\mathrm{i}}\left(\mathrm{GDP}\ast {\mathrm{VA}}_{\mathrm{i}}/\mathrm{GDP}\ast {\mathrm{E}}_{\mathrm{i}}/{\mathrm{VA}}_{\mathrm{i}}\ast {\mathrm{E}\mathrm{M}}_{\mathrm{i}}/{\mathrm{E}}_{\mathrm{i}}\right)=\mathrm{ACT}\ast \mathrm{STR}\ast \mathrm{EFF}\ast \mathrm{FS} $$
(6.47)
$$ {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ele}}={\mathrm{ELE}}_{\mathrm{tot}}\ast {\mathrm{ELE}}_{\mathrm{fos}}/{\mathrm{ELE}}_{\mathrm{tot}}\ast {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ele}}/{\mathrm{ELE}}_{\mathrm{fos}}=\mathrm{EL}\ast \mathrm{NF}\ast \mathrm{EFF} $$
(6.48)

where

EM::

Total emission

EMend::

Emission from end-use sectors

EMele::

Emission from power generation

EMccs::

Emission captured by CCS technology

VAi::

Value added of sector i

Ei::

Energy consumption of sector i

EMi::

Emission from sector i

ELEtot::

Total electricity demand

ELEfos::

Fossil-fired electricity production

ACT::

Activity level effect

STR::

Industry structure effect

EFF::

Energy efficiency effect

FS::

Fuel-switching effect

EL::

Total electricity demand effect

NF::

Non-fossil power effect

A change in emissions from the reference to countermeasure scenarios, △EM, can be expressed as a change in emission from end-use sectors, power generation, CCS absorption, and emissions trade (Eq. 6.49). Using the Laspeyres index method (Sun and Ang 2000), a change in emissions from end-use sectors and power generation can be expressed as the joint contribution of the underlying effects indicated by f in Eqs. 6.50 and 6.51, in which each effect can be derived from multiplication, as shown for total electricity demand in Eq. 6.52. The first part of Eq. 6.52, △ELEtot*NF*EFF, can be interpreted as the partial effect of the total electricity demand component on the change of CO2 emissions between the reference and mitigation scenarios. The following parts capture interactions between the remaining variables and form the so-called residual term:

$$ \triangle \mathrm{EM}=\triangle {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{end}}+\triangle {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ele}}-\triangle {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ccs}} $$
(6.49)
$$ \triangle {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{end}}={\mathrm{ACT}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{STR}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{EFF}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{FS}}_{\mathrm{f}} $$
(6.50)
$$ \triangle {\mathrm{EM}}_{\mathrm{ele}}={\mathrm{EL}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{NF}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{EFF}}_{\mathrm{f}} $$
(6.51)
$$ {\mathrm{EL}}_{\mathrm{f}}=\triangle {\mathrm{EL}\mathrm{E}}_{\mathrm{tot}}\ast \mathrm{NF}\ast \mathrm{EFF}+1/2\ast {\mathrm{EL}\mathrm{E}}_{\mathrm{tot}}\ast \left(\triangle \mathrm{NF}\ast \mathrm{EFF}+\mathrm{NF}\ast \triangle \mathrm{EFF}\right)+1/3\ast \left(\triangle \mathrm{NF}\ast \triangle \mathrm{EFF}\right) $$
(6.52)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dai, H., Masui, T. (2017). Achieving Carbon Emissions Peak in China by 2030: The Key Options and Economic Impacts. In: Fujimori, S., Kainuma, M., Masui, T. (eds) Post-2020 Climate Action. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3869-3_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics