Skip to main content

Incoming Labor-Product Society and EU Regional Policy

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Getting Globalization Right

Abstract

This contribute moves from a tentative of labor product taxonomy as opposed to mainstream labor factor, or human capital theory of production. We assume that labor is a product in all those cases where the trade-off between labor and capital blurs: in the case of high and medium-high technology workers, social economy enterprises, self-employment, “social-ethic” and no profit activities, but also in the case of smart entrepreneurship, especially in high and medium high technological sectors, such us start up enterprises. Aim of this paper is to improve analyses and implications of the changes in the EU NUTS 1 regions due to the diffusion of the information/knowledge society. We enlarge the Ex-post Myopic Convergence Model (EMCM) explaining the relative rate of productivity of EU NUTS1 regions, with the inclusion of a new exogenous variable, the share of labor-product on total employment (HTC/Total employment). Coexisting labor product-labor factor interaction in time and by regions, a Labor product-labor factor Interaction Model (LIM) has been specified and quantified starting from the Stone-Ramsey principle. The range of a possible future evolution of the interregional labor division between information technology and digital divide concludes the work.

Misery and Bliss, Richard Stone (Mathematics in Social Science and other Essays).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. The Economic Journal, (99), 116–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (2013). Complexity economics. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Sala i Martín, X. (1997). Technological diffusion, convergence, and growth. NBER, WP (5151).

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Sala i Martín, X. (2004). Economic growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De la Fuente, A. (2001). On the source of convergence: A close look at the Spanish Regions. European Economic Review, (46), 569–599.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2010). An agenda for new skills and jobs: A European contribution towards full employment. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2015). Completing Europe’s Economic and Monetary Union. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2016). Towards a European Pillar of Social Rights. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geary, R. C. (1950). A note on ‘A constant-utility index of the cost of living’. Review of Economic Studies, 18(2), 65–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hieronymi, O., & Lo Cascio, M. (2016). A new social market economy for the 21st century. Roma: Aracne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Cascio, M., & Bagarani, M. (2017a). Inside the EU economic space: Ex-post convergence vs EMU-OCA challenges. In L. Paganetto (Ed.), Sustainable growth in EU—Challenges and solutions. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Cascio, M., & Bagarani, M. (2017b). Coesione? La politica regionale europea tra allargamento “centrifugo” e approfondimento “zoppo”. In L. Paganetto (Ed.), Unione Europea. 60 anni e un bivio, Rapporto del Gruppo dei 20. Eurolink University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Cascio, M., & Bagarani, M. (2018). Europe, “knowledge” driven or divided? In O. Hieronymi (Ed.), Quo vadis Europe. Where is Europe heading sixty years after the signature of the Rome Treaty on the European Economic Community. Geneva: Webster University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Cascio, M., Bagarani, M., & Zampino, S. (2012). Economic space trajectory trough different regional growth model. In M. Bagarani (Ed.), Il governo delle Regioni e lo sviluppo economico. Alessandria: Edizioni dell’Orso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanism of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. (1992). A contribution to the empirics economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 407–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mongelli, P. F. (2008, February). European economic and monetary integration, and the optimum currency area theory. Economic Papers, (302) (Brussels).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pulido, A., & Fontela, E. (2004). Principios del desarrollo económico sostenible. Fundation Iberdrova.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, (94), 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martino Lo Cascio .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1. Convergence Model

1.1 A.1.1 Data

The analysis is mainly based on statistics provided by Eurostat at regional level and focuses on 28 countries and 98 NUTS1 regions in the period 2000–2014.

Different sub-sets of data are used:

1.2 A.1.2 Model Specification

In the original model we proposed a minimal definition of transitional steady state for EU spatial units as the equalization of regional growth rates of productivity, so that regional shares of GDP remain stable over time.

Under the hypothesis of the existence of adaptive development mechanisms towards long-run productivity levels, a generic specification of the model can be formally developed as:

$$ \ln \,Y_{i,t}^{*} = \alpha_{i} + \sum\limits_{j} {\gamma_{j} \ln \,X_{j,i,t - \tau } } + \frac{1}{2}\sum\limits_{j} {\sum {_{h} \omega_{j,h} \ln \,X_{j,t - \tau } } } \ln \,X_{h,t - \tau } $$
(3)
$$ \ln \,Y_{i,t} - \ln \,Y_{i,t - \tau } = \beta (\ln \,Y_{i,t}^{*} - \ln \,Y_{i,t - \tau } ) $$
(4)
$$ \begin{aligned} \ln \,Y_{i,t} & = \beta \alpha_{i} + \beta \sum\limits_{j} {\gamma_{j} \ln \,X_{j,i,t - \tau } } \\ & + \frac{1}{2}\beta \sum\limits_{j} {\sum {_{h} \omega_{j,h} \ln \,X_{j,t - \tau } } } \ln \,X_{h,t - \tau } + (1 - \beta )\ln \,Y_{i,t - \tau } \\ \end{aligned} $$
(5)

where:

\( Y_{i,t}^{*} \) :

expected transitional steady state productivity in regioni relative to EU regions average conditioned to \( \alpha_{i} \) and \( X_{j,i,t - \tau } \)

\( Y_{i,t} \) :

gross productivity in 2001 purchasing power in region ith relative to EU regions average

\( X_{j,i,t - \tau } \) :

physical and human capital structural indexes, relative to EU average and total factor productivity transfers (XP,i), defined below

\( \beta_{{}} \) :

adaptive coefficient to the above defined steady state, with \( 0 \le \beta_{{}} \le 1 \)

\( \alpha_{i} \) :

social/institutional factors specific for region

\( \gamma_{j} ,\omega_{j,h} \) :

across regions constant parameters for observed factors Xj,i

τ :

0,1 depending on factor inputs

j, h :

[1, …, H], i = [1, …, N] and t = [1, …, T]

Three different potential scenarios can be described:

  • \( \alpha_{i} = \alpha \) and \( \gamma_{j} = 0 \) and \( \omega_{j,h} = 0 \) → absolute convergence

  • \( \alpha_{i} = \alpha \) and \( \gamma_{j} \ne 0 \) and \( \omega_{j,j} = \omega_{h,h} \) and \( \omega_{j,j} \) different in sign by \( \omega_{j,h} \) → σ-convergence without fixed effects, if \( \alpha_{i} = \alpha + v_{i} \)

  • then → transitional convergence with fixed effects being vi latent factors not included as exogenous but constant over time for each region.

Transitional steady state is to be considered as “a way by which all agents think on a more stable future for their decisions” (Lo Cascio et al. 2012).

From (3) to (5) the estimable function will be

$$ \begin{aligned} d\,\ln \,Y_{i,t} & = \theta_{i} + \sum\limits_{j} {\phi_{j} \ln \,X_{j,i,t - \tau } } \\ & + \frac{1}{2}\sum\limits_{j} {\sum {_{h} \vartheta_{j,h} \ln \,X_{j,t - \tau } } } \ln \,X_{h,t - \tau } - \beta \,\ln Y_{i,t - \tau } + \varepsilon_{i,t} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(6)

where

\( \theta_{i} = \beta \alpha_{i} \); and \( \vartheta_{j,h} = \beta \omega_{j,h} \); and \( \phi_{j} = \beta_{{}} \gamma_{j} \)

if \( \gamma_{j} \ge 0 \) we expect \( \phi_{j} \le 0 \)

if \( \beta \to 1 \) and \( \omega_{j,h} = 0 \) then the productivity function degenerates into a Cobb-Douglas function

if \( \omega_{j,h} = \omega_{h,j} = - \frac{1}{2}\omega_{j,j}^{2} = - \frac{1}{2}\omega_{h,h}^{2} \) then the productivity function degenerates into a CES function.

For \( d\,\ln \,Y_{i,t} = 0 \) then \( \ln \,Y_{i,t} = \ln \,Y_{i,t - \tau } \) so

$$ \begin{aligned} \ln \,Y_{i,t}^{*} & = \frac{{\theta_{i} }}{\beta } + \sum\limits_{j} {\frac{{\phi_{j} }}{\beta }\ln \,X_{j,i,t - \tau } + \frac{1}{2\beta }\sum\limits_{j} {\sum {_{h} \vartheta_{j,h} \ln \,X_{j,t - \tau } } } \ln \,X_{h,t - \tau } } \\ & = \alpha_{i} + \sum\limits_{j} {\gamma_{j} \ln \,X_{j,i,t - \tau } } + \frac{1}{2}\sum\limits_{j} {\sum {_{h} \omega_{j,h} \ln \,X_{j,t - \tau } } } \ln \,X_{h,t - \tau } \\ \end{aligned} $$
(7)

1.3 A.1.3 The Total Factor Productivity Transfers (TFPT) Specification

The 2007 model included as exogenous variable a proxy of the Total Factor Productivity Transfers (TFPT), defined as:

$$ TFPT_{i,t} = \left( {1 + \frac{{p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} - p_{i,t} Q_{i,t - 1} *\frac{{\sum\nolimits_{i}^{n} {p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} } }}{{\sum\nolimits_{i}^{n} {p_{i,t} Q_{i,t - 1} } }}}}{{p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} }} - m_{t} } \right) $$

With:

m t :

median of Laspeyres chained indices for each year (t) in the EU regions

Q i,t :

chained Laspeyres volume GDP index at time t

$$ p_{i,t} = \frac{{GDP_{i,t}^{curr} }}{{Q_{i,t} }} $$

The TFPTi is a measure of the difference between current GDP and a benchmark hypothetical GDP, being the last one representative of the perfect malleability of production factors, i.e. the Clark’s conditions that productivity of factor inputs are equal to the relative prices, and productivity gains in value are equal to the value of net distributed product for each year. Defining:

$$ \frac{{p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} - p_{i,t} Q_{i,t - 1} *\frac{{\sum\nolimits_{i}^{n} {p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} } }}{{\sum\nolimits_{i}^{n} {p_{i,t} Q_{i,t - 1} } }}}}{{p_{i,t} Q_{i,t} }} = A $$

The (8) below is the realization of the model (3) for EU regions in the time span 2004–2015. Therefore, a viable statistical model can be written as:

$$ \begin{aligned} d\,\ln \,Y_{i,t} & = \theta_{i} + \beta \,\ln \,Y_{i,t - \tau } + \phi_{1} \ln \,Inv_{i,t - \tau } + \phi_{2} \ln \,TPPT_{i,t} \\ & + \vartheta_{1} \ln \,Inv_{i,t - \tau }^{2} + \vartheta_{2} \ln \,TPPT_{i,t}^{2} \\ & + \vartheta_{3} (\ln \,Inv_{i,t - \tau } \times \,\ln \,TPPT_{i,t} ) + \ln \,HTC + \varepsilon_{i,t} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(8)

With: \( \theta_{i} = v_{0} + v_{i} + v_{t} \) and εi,t ~ (0, σ2)

where:

$$ \begin{aligned} Inv_{i,t} & = \frac{{INV_{i,t} }}{{GDP_{i,t} }} = \frac{{K_{i,t} - (1 - \partial )K_{i,t - 1} }}{{L_{i,t} \pi_{i,t} }} \cong \frac{{K_{i,t} }}{{L_{i,t} \pi_{i,t} }} - (1 - \partial_{i} )*\mu_{i} \\ \pi_{i,t} & = \frac{{GDP_{i,t} }}{{L_{i,t} }} \\ \end{aligned} $$
\( \frac{{K_{i,t} }}{{L_{i,t} \pi_{i,t} }} \) :

capital per labor unit, adjusted with internal technical progress

L :

Labor

Inv i,t :

Investment’s share on Gross Domestic Product (GDP)

Capital depreciation rate \( (\partial_{i} ) \) and capital/output ratio \( (\mu ) \) are considered approximately constant over time but different across regions, so Inv represents the capital/labor ratio adjusted for capital/output ratio and related depreciation rate.

Appendix 2. List of Regions Included in Each Cluster

Cluster 1

Cluster 3

RO2—Macroregiunea doi

PT1—Continente

BG3—Severna i yugoiztochna

SI0—Slovenija

RO4—Macroregiunea patru

EL1—Voreia Ellada

RO1—Macroregiunea unu

MT0—Malta

BG4—Yugozapadna i yuzhna tsentr.

EL4—Nisia Aigaiou, Kriti

RO3—Macroregiunea trei

ES6—Sur (ES)

Cluster 2

CY0—Kypros

PL3—Region Wschodni

ES1—Noroeste

HU3—Alföld és Észak

ES4—Centro (ES)

LV0—Latvija

ES7—Canarias (ES)

LT0—Lietuva

EL2—Kentriki Ellada

HU2—Dunántúl

DEG—Thüringen

EE0—Eesti

DE4—Brandenburg

PL6—Region Pólnocny

DE8—Mecklenburg-Vorpommern

SK0—Slovensko

ES5—Este (ES)

PL2—Region Poludniowy

DEE—Sachsen-Anhalt

PL5—Region Poludniowo-Zachodni

DED—Sachsen

PL4—Region Pólnocno-Zachodni

EL3—Attiki

CZ0—Ceská republika

ES2—Noreste

HR0—Hrvatska

ES3—Comunidad de Madrid

PL1—Region Centralny

 

HU1—Közép-Magyarország

 

PT2—Região Autónoma dos Açores

 

PT3—Região Autónoma da Madeira

 

Cluster 4

NL2—Oost-Nederland

DEC—Saarland

BE3—Région wallonne

FR2—Bassin Parisien

DEF—Schleswig-Holstein

UKD—North West (UK)

UKL—Wales

SE3—Norra Sverige

DEB—Rheinland-Pfalz

UKH—East of England

NL1—Noord-Nederland

BE2—Vlaams Gewest

DE9—Niedersachsen

FR5—Ouest (FR)

AT2—Südösterreich

AT3—Westösterreich

UKC—North East (UK)

FR6—Sud-Ouest (FR)

UKF—East Midlands (UK)

UKM—Scotland

UKE—Yorkshire and The Humber

DEA—Nordrhein-Westfalen

ITF—Sud

SE2—Södra Sverige

ITG—Isole

FR3—Nord—Pas-de-Calais

UKN—Northern Ireland (UK)

DE2—Bayern

DE3—Berlin

DE1—Baden-Württemberg

NL4—Zuid-Nederland

FRA—Départements d’outre-mer

UKK—South West (UK)

FI1—Manner-Suomi

UKG—West Midlands (UK)

FI2—Åland

FR4—Est (FR)

 

Cluster 5

Cluster 6

AT1—Ostösterreich

DE5—Bremen

FR7—Centre-Est (FR)

DE6—Hamburg

NL3—West-Nederland

FR1—Île de France

FR8—Méditerranée

UKI—London

ITH—Nord-Est

LU0—Luxembourg

DE7—Hessen

BE1—Région de Bruxelles-Capitale

UKJ—South East (UK)

 

ITI—Centro

 

ITC—Nord-Ovest

 

IE0—Éire/Ireland

 

SE1—Östra Sverige

 

DK0—Danmark

 

Appendix 3. Through Pass Financial Crisis and Credit Crunch in Gross Productivity Versus Labor Product Share (Clusters of Regions)

figure a

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Lo Cascio, M., Bagarani, M. (2018). Incoming Labor-Product Society and EU Regional Policy. In: Paganetto, L. (eds) Getting Globalization Right. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-97692-1_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics