1 Introduction

While Brussels is one of the capitals of the European Union, Belgian law is not well known abroad. However, it is not uninteresting, for a major reason: the direct origin of Belgian law in the French tradition is challenged by the increasing importance of its Flemish part of the country. The consequence is a remaining Napoleonian grammar with a different wording. That general assessment is far true about company law. Belgian company law deviated from French law in the nineteenth century and is now absolutely autonomous and original. Firstly, the traditional notion of the commerçant trader has been removed. The core of the commercial law of Belgium is now economic activity, to which a full code adopted in 2018 is dedicated, and any person that undertakes such an activity is considered an enterprise. That major reform was the first step of a wider program and a new code on companies and associations has been enacted in 2019. Nevertheless, these evolutions have not severely changed the legal background for B Corp. The B Corps developed in Belgium like in Europe (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
A line graph of B Corps development has numbers ranging from 0 to 7 on the Y axis and years ranging from 2011 to 2022 on the X axis. The number of B-Corp from 2012 to 2016 is 1 then reaches a peak of 6 in 2019. A dotted line crosses the solid line.

Number of B-Corp per year

It is difficult to have a perfect view of their legal forms since the legal context has changed; for example, the social purpose company disappeared in 2019 (see Fig. 2), but here are the available data.

Fig. 2
A pie chart of the legal form of B-Crop divided into six different color-shaded compartments and each has significant percentages: S.A, 36; S p R L, 29; S a R L, 7; S C A, 7; S c R L, 14; S c R L.f.s, 7.

B-Corp legal form

Since B Corps created before 2019 have been labeled before the new codes, it is necessary to describe the legal landscape in which they developed. Then we will explain the major points of the reform, and we will conclude that the number of B Corps is likely to keep on growing.

2 The Legal Context of the Emergence of B Corps

Belgian law is particularly interesting when considering benefit corporations. Indeed, the authors e debated strongly and during many decades about the notions of association and company (Sect. 2.1), and the legislator concluded that period by the establishment of the first benefit corporation, i.e., the social purpose company (Sect. 2.2).

2.1 The Traditional Notion of Company

After Napoleon’s defeat, Belgium adopted French legislation. Therefore, its company law was similar to the French one, with its famous article 1832: “A partnership is created by two or several persons who agree by a contract to appropriate property or their industry for a common venture with a view to sharing the benefit or profiting from the saving which may result therefrom. It may be created, in the cases provided for by statute, through the act of the will of one person only. The partners bind themselves to contribute to the losses.” The industrual revolution in Europe during the century required a modernization of the legislation. Some adjustments were adopted in the middle of the nineteenth century, but the major reform was passed in 1873.Footnote 1 This act replaces the old sections of the commercial code pertaining to commercial companies. Its main innovations were the removal of the state accreditation required for the creation of public limited companies and the generalization of registration of information in order to protect third parties. It remained the core of Belgian company law till the end of the twentieth century. But the reform of 1873 did not touch the civil code, and article 1832 remained unchanged.

The discussion about the scope covered by the company arose only when a competing institution was legally organized, i.e., the not-for-profit association (association sans but lucratif). Footnote 2 Its article 1 stated that the not-for-profit association is the one which does not undertake industrial or commercial activities, or which does not aim at providing a material win to its members. Apparently, the distinction is clear, except that there were strong debates all along the century about the precise domain of the not-for-profit association. The first point of debate has been grammatical—to acknowledge that the “or” should be understood as an “and” since the two conditions are not alternative but cumulative. Footnote 3 Indeed, the opposite interpretation would have allowed them to provide material win to their members if they did not have an industrial or commercial activity. The problem arose with the development of the economic activities of not-for-profit associations. The case law admitted that a not-for-profit association could have a lucrative activity if such activity is accessory to its main activity and that this lucrative activity is a necessary means to achieve its purpose. Footnote 4 This point will not be further developed, but it has concentrated the debates about the definition of association and company. Indeed, the definition of the association directly impacts the one of the companies.

Undoubtedly, a company is aimed at the distribution of profits, and it is not allowed to adopt the legal form of a company if distribution is not possible. But currently, there is no serious debate on the possibility of integrating social purposes into the object of a company nor into its management. Footnote 5 No case law had yet declared a manager liable for having neglected the maximization of company profits for the shareholders. Moreover, when a company engages into the corporate social responsibility, it is connected with the sustainable development and benefit from the support of the state institutions in charge of this question. The only limit is the prohibition for a company to exclude any distribution or profit.

Belgian authors discussed also the nature of the company: contract, institution, and more recently functional or structural theory. However, Although the debates have not reached an agreement, a disenchanted opinion is that it is an essentially academic dispute and that all these theories cover part of the regulation of the company. Footnote 6 This debate echoes on the notion of company interest. Company interest (intérêt social) refers sometimes to the financial interest of the company to provide the maximum of profits to its shareholders, but it refers as well in other contexts to the interest of all its stakeholders, notably when the board must assess the opportunity of a take-over bid. Footnote 7 The question of the lucratively of the company has been fundamentally renewed since the reform of 1995.

2.2 The Experience of Social Purpose Companies

The adoption of a special framework for benefit corporation, in Belgium with the social purpose company (société à finalité sociale) is strongly related to the general context of company law, and more particularly to the relationship established between companies and associations. For sure, the benefit corporation movement has been initiated by businessmen wishing to escape from the maximization of profit as the single compass for their enterprise. In that respect, the company is the suitable legal status for the enterprise, and not the association is not. Indeed, the association refers to a grouping of persons that pursuit a philanthropic aim or organizes social activities, such as sport, theatre… This has been exactly the implicit conception in which the act on associations was drafted in Belgium. Footnote 8 Meaningfully, the act on associations of 1921 does not deal with all associations but only not for profit associations.

In the meantime, in Belgium like, in other countries, enterprises with an important economic dimension but aimed at the provision of social services without the pursuit of profit emerged, such as schools, hospitals, organizations supporting jobless persons or people with disability. This has created a grey area, and consequently some legal uncertainty, in the restrictive definition of a not-for-profit association and the company. Some social economy enterprises claim the creation of a new legal form Footnote 9 to bring more clarity and in order not to hinder the development of these new enterprises. In the meantime, on a more conceptual level, it was suggested to rethink difference between a company and an association. Some authors claimed that the opposition of companies and associations was not a necessity, but a conceptual construction that could be modified. Footnote 10 In that conception, it would be possible to utilize use the legal form of a company, which demonstrated to be very successful to organize an enterprise, to ran other purposes than, the maximization of profits and their distribution.

This conception was not unanimously approved among the academics, but it was a very promising renewal of the conception of the coordination of the various private law groupings. Footnote 11 In the francophone legal thinking, till the end of the nineteenth century, any grouping was considered as an association, without any connection with its legal personality, and company was a contract by which was created a special association. The first evolution, during the nineteenth century, has been the increasing importance attached to the question of legal personality. With the adoption of acts on association in the beginning of the twentieth century, to which legal personality was attributed under some conditions, association and company appeared as distinct groupings and association could not be considered anymore as the general category. This is the reason why the major doctrinal debate of that time was about the border between the company and the association, even if Belgium and France did not give the same answer. Along the twentieth century, with the company has become the usual way to run an economic activity instead of the traditional personal enterprise undertaking on its personal behalf. Therefore, the company has become the pattern for the enterprise. In that context, the proposal to admit the possibility for a company to run a non-for-profit economic activity is to be considered as the achievement of the evolution: the company would become the general category, and association would be a special grouping.

Whereas there is no direct relationship between that proposal and the functional theory of company, some common features can be established between that latter conception and the functional theory of company. Let’s remind that the functional theory, Footnote 12 proposes, in the 1960s 1970s, to consider the company has a frame for the enterprise. Footnote 13 Instead of being assimilated to the enterprise itself, the company is considered as a tool to regulate the functioning of the enterprise, from the shareholder point of view, with the obligation to mitigate their selfish interests to include the ones of the enterprise’s stakeholders. Related with the institutional conception of the company, the functional approach has been an attempt to incorporate the critics addressed to the institutional conception in a contractual theory perspective. Likewise, the proposal to extend the domain of the company consists in removing its specificity i.e., to distribute profits, and to consider it as a more general pattern, able to perform various functions.

To ensure the validity of such a company with regard to the civil code, the evolution has been explicitly stated in the definition of company. Footnote 14 However, the general definition has not been amended in the core provision, but a new line added to allow such companies that do not pursuit the distribution of profits, in the cases provided by the code. Therefore, the possibility for a company to pursuit another goal was not general but limited to the hypothesis defined by the company code. This came up with the creation of the social purpose company in 1995. Footnote 15

Pursuant to the article 661 of the ancient company code, the social purpose company is a modality of company, that may be added to most companies recognized as legal persons: general partnership, limited liability partnership, private limited liability company, cooperative society, public limited liability company, limited stock ownership company, economic interest grouping. Footnote 16 Of course, to qualify as a social purpose company, these companies must meet additional conditions: they don’t aim at the enrichment of shareholders, and their by-laws contain mandatory provisions. The by-laws have to include some clauses: the shareholders pursue a limited profit or no profit, the definition of the social purpose and the absence of any indirect financial profit as the main purpose of the company, the definition of the profit allocation policy suitable to the object of the company and the rules for the constitution of reserves, the limitation of voting rights in the general meeting to 10% for one shareholder, the limitation of distribution of profit (if any) to the maximum allowed for approved cooperatives, the elaboration of a special annual report on the achievement of the social purpose, the possibility for any employee to become a shareholder one year after he/she has been hired at the latest and the termination of its quality of shareholder one year after he/she is not employee anymore, the allocation of net assets to a similar company in case of liquidation.

The description of the regulation of these companies will not be further developed, Footnote 17 it was only necessary to highlight their legal orientation. Even if social purpose companies and cooperatives differ, the latter inspired the former: there is no historical connection, but the proximity of legal provisions is obvious. Moreover, it seems that most existing social purpose companies were a modality of cooperatives. Footnote 18 Actually, there has been a consensus that social purpose companies have not been a success since they remained rather few. Several reasons have been proposed to explain this relative failure. First of all, there has been no tax incentive since a social purpose company is taxed as another company. Secondly, if a not-for-profit association was able to convert into a social purpose company, the outcome was partially unsecured, since all the public support to associations were not guaranteed for social purpose companies. This is problematic, since one of the goals of the creation of the social purpose company was to provide a solution for associations wishing to develop their economic activities securely. This was not a good starting point to ensure a rich future to that experience, even if it has been positively considered abroad, and sometimes inspired other reforms, like in Luxembourg.

Nevertheless, some authors claimed for the maintenance of the social purpose company in the perspective of a general reform that has been considered in the 2010s. Apart from Michel Coipel, who was one of the promotors of this modality of company, Paul Alain Foriers and Alain François articulated several reasons to keep that possibility. Footnote 19 Firstly, they observe that the high majority of companies remain targeted at the distribution of profits and that it is still meaningful to offer a special pattern for the few companies aiming at another goal. Secondly, that modality would allow these peculiar companies to be visible. Thirdly, there is a practical interest i.e., to benefit from the advantages of companies, notably the attractivity for financing.

However, the major reform of grouping law in 2019 has strongly transformed the whole system.

3 The Recent General Reform of Company Law

Belgium seems to has adopted during the last years a frenetic activity to reform private law. Already in 2001, a company code was adopted, Footnote 20 and in 2013, the process for the drafting of the economic law code started, Footnote 21 but some proposals also appeared for the reformation of the civil code. Footnote 22 The bill to fully reform the civil code was adopted on April 4, 2019, Footnote 23 which is intended to contain nine titles (instead of three books nowadays). Book 3 on property law and Book 8 on proof have been adopted Footnote 24 and have entered into force. Other books are still under discussion. Things sped up in 2018 and 2019 in business law as, respectively, the economic law code was enacted Footnote 25 and the new company and association code adopted. Footnote 26 These new codes do not only aim at better coordination, they also introduced grate innovations, that impact necessarily the question of B-Corp. Footnote 27

The first innovation of the economic law code is his title. If legal thinking uses usually the expression commercial law and business law, it refers more rarely to economic law. The purpose of the code is to cover all areas in the regulation of economic activities: competition law, consumer law, insolvency law, etc. Considering only economic activities, the distinction between civil and commercial has disappeared. But the most unusual is maybe the scope of this new code since it is applicable to any enterprise, and the definition of an enterprise is extremely wide. The definition of an enterprise under the code Footnote 28 lists three categories: (a) any natural person who runs a professional activity in an independent way, (b) any legal person, and (c) any other organization without legal personality. Then, the code provides some derogations, but they concern only some organizations without legal personality or some public persons. For example, a manager of a company, when he is not an employee, is considered as an enterprise for the application of the economic law code. Of course, a company, whether a B Corp or not, will be considered an enterprise, as well as a not-for-profit association. This means that both will be subject to the same legal regime concerning their economic activity. And apart from the new notion of enterprise, the substance of the regulation has been renewed as well and this impacts companies. Footnote 29

Of course, B- corp is far more concern with the new company and association code. Its title may not surprise; as the economic law code considers altogether for-profit and not-for-profit organizations, it is perfectly coherent to deal with the structure of these two groupings into the same legislation. But this new code goes beyond and renews substantially the definition of these two legal persons. The new definition of company is to be quoted in totality: Footnote 30 A company is constituted by a legal act by which one or several persons, named shareholders, make a contribution. It has a patrimony, and its object is the pursuit of one or several activities. One of its goals is to distribute or provide to its shareholders a direct or indirect financial advantage.

Surely, legislation has taken one step further since distribution of profits is not anymore literally the core object of a company. The only prevalence of this object remains, symbolically in the fact it is the only one mentioned, and technically in the impossibility to create a company without, at least partly, that object. Apart from that, there may be other objects the company can pursue, and it is not even required that distribution of profits is the major one. However, this will not change practically the situation of companies since most of them will remain oriented to the maximization of profits for shareholders.

In the meantime, the definition of the association Footnote 31 has been as well renewed: an association is established by a convention between two or several persons, named members. It pursues a not-for-profit purpose in the framework of one or several determined activities that constitute its object. It may not distribute or provide, directly or indirectly, any financial advantage to its founders, its members, any board member or any other person but in the disinterested purpose stated by the by-laws. Any transaction that violates this prohibition is void. Footnote 32

The change seems conceptually less general than for companies, but it is actually probably more important. Indeed, the debate about the coordination of the different conditions required from not-for-profit associations has been terminated by the removal of the most controversial one: the prohibition of commercial and industrial activities. Therefore, the only requirement is now the absence of any distribution of financial advantage, which can be compared to the French solution. Footnote 33 That extension of the domain of activities of not-for-profit associations improves their legal certainty and surely facilitates their development. Whereas associations and companies were distinguished by their activities and their ability to make profit, the single remaining criterion is the possibility or not to distribute the profits. The restriction laid down for not-for-profit associations on this distribution has been extended, or at least specified, about both its substance and its recipients. The prohibition on profit distribution concerns not only the members but also the founders and board members; in other words, it also means a prohibition on any remuneration for these board members. Moreover, the prohibition of any provision of a financial advantage to any other person entails the voidness of any gratuitous act of association that would not be covered by its statutory object. It may be noticed also that the prohibition mentions any financial advantage, that is to say that it is wider than profits. Whereas in French law there is a strict opposition, or complement, between association and company, with the identical criterion of the distribution of profits, the definitions of company and association in Belgian law are situated in two different levels: only company refers to profits and association refers to financial advantage.

These two new definitions have established an original framework for enterprises that pursue a social purpose. Whereas before 1995 these enterprises were likely to meet difficulties in finding a legal form suitable to their specificities, nowadays they have the choice between a not-for-profit association and a company. Indeed, both are possible since a company may easily include other purposes than the distribution of profits in its object, while an association may undertake industrial and commercial transactions. In that new context, and taking into account the low number of social purpose companies, the legislator simply decided to remove this new modality for the company. The authors that were initially reluctant to remove the social purpose company admit now that the new landscape implies logically their disappearance. Footnote 34 Interestingly, it may be noticed that the justification for such as removal is not the possible inclusion of a social purpose in a company’s object but the possibility for a not-for-profit association to run any economic activity.

One concrete effect of the modification of the definition of a company is to facilitate the classification of cooperatives into the category of the companies since its specific object fits better with the new wider definition. The definition of the cooperative itself has been fully changed. Footnote 35 Whereas its definition was very formalistic, referring only to the variability of its capital, Footnote 36 The cooperative is now defined: The cooperative society has as main purpose the satisfaction and/or the development of economic and/or social activities of its shareholders and/or of third parties interested notably by the conclusion of agreements with the former towards the provision of goods or services or the execution of works in the context of the activity that the cooperative society performs or makes perform. Footnote 37

The definition is a little bit complicated, but, the inclusion of the satisfaction or the development of the activities of its members may find an inspiration in the definition provided by the European regulation. Meanwhile, it complies with the definition and principles of the International Cooperative Alliance. This may solve the tricky problem that faced Belgian law during many years i.e. the false cooperatives. Footnote 38 It must be precise as well that the cooperative may be accredited if it meets some more strict conditions, notably about its governance and its limited profitability. Footnote 39 More interestingly for the question of B Corp, it may also be accredited as social enterprise, if it meets three conditions: 1° its main purpose is, in the general interest, to produce a positive social impact for man, environment or society; 2° any advantage for the shareholders are limited by reference to the regulation on true cooperatives; 3° in case of winding-up its net assets have to be allocated in a manner that fits the best possible with its object as social enterprise. Footnote 40 It must be noticed that a cooperative society is the only organization that can be accredited as a social enterprise.

When comparing the new definition of a company with the previous definition of a social purpose company, the company appears to be more of a capitalist since it cannot prohibit the distribution of any profits, whereas the by-laws of a social purpose company could do so. But the general evolution of company law is surely more important and realizes a complete revolution. The pursuit of another goal than the distribution of profits is no longer reserved to special companies but is open to any company without any special regulation. The legislator drew the conclusion of that major evolution, and the social purpose company has been simply removed. The question arises whether that loss makes really no damage; indeed, the social purpose company did not allow only the pursuit of an economic activity without the purpose to distribute profits; it contained as well other provisions, notably about the voting rights or allocation to reserves. The flexibility of Belgian company law makes possible to adopt the same provisions, notably through the choice of the legal form of the cooperative. Therefore, the new solution appears technically neutral, but it may be symbolically considered a defeat for social enterprises, which lost their own legal form.

In the end of that chapter, it must be assessed if the new legislation is more friendly for B Corp. Despite recognizing the possibility for companies to pursue a nonprofitable purpose besides a profitable one, the goal of the reform was not specifically this one. Three guidelines were considered: simplification and coherence, freedom and flexibility, facilitation of the mobility of companies to comply with the European objective. Footnote 41 To put it differently, the possibility for a company to pursue another goal than the maximization of profits is not the consequence of a critic of such maximization; no limit is put to the persons who will wish to create such a company. But the wish to simplify the regulation and a neutral liberalization entails the absence of impediment to use the company in order to achieve a social or whatever else goal. Before 2019, there was no precise impediment to add some social principles to the functioning of the company, and the number of companies labeled B Corp at that time show it clearly. This has never been contested. Therefore, it cannot really be said that the new companies and associations code improved the situation for B-Corp; this would be possible only if some impediments could have been shown before. But that does not mean that nothing has changed. What is new is that these companies that are tempted to run their activities differently are now absolutely free to go further in that direction without adopting another legal form.