Skip to main content

Interests, Information, and Incentives in Higher Education: Principal-Agent Theory and Its Potential Applications to the Study of Higher Education Governance

  • Chapter
Higher Education

Part of the book series: Handbook of Theory and Research ((HATR,volume 23))

In recent years, a handful of scholars have begun to focus on the role of individual and organizational interests, information flows, and incentives in higher education administration and governance, particularly in the realm of public institutions. These scholars ground their work on assumptions derived from the principal-agent framework, a theoretical perspective that views relationships from a contractual paradigm wherein a principal actor or organization contracts with an agent to carry out certain functions. The framework allows for analysis of how structures impact the agent’s willingness and/or ability to fulfill the contracted obligations. This chapter explores the economic and political assumptions of the principal-agent framework and introduces scholars to its utility for understanding how governance and policy making operates in the postsecondary setting. Further, the chapter provides insights as to how the principal-agent framework can help reframe and extend current practical and scholarly conceptions of postsecondary governance and policy decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, R., Boyne, G. A., & Enticott, G. (2006). Performance failure in the public sector. Misfortune or mismanagement? Public Management Review, 8(2), 273–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1990). The debate between traditional management theory and organizational economics: Substantive differences or intergroup conflict? Academy of Management Review, 15(3), 382–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B., & Hesterly, W. (1996). Organizational economics: Understanding the relationship between organizations and economic analysis. In Glegg, S. R., Hardy, C., & Nord, W. R. (eds.), Handbook of organization studies (pp. 115–147). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B., & Ouchi, W. G. (eds.) (1986). Organizational economics (3rd printing). San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Begg, D., Fischer, S., & Dornbusch, R. (1994). Economics (4th ed.). London: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bendor, J., & Meirowitz, A. (2004). Spatial models of delegation. American Political Science Review, 98(2), 293–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bendor, J., Taylor, S., & Van Gaalen, R. (1987). Politicians, bureaucrats, and asymmetric information. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 796–828.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berdahl, R. O. (1990). Academic freedom, autonomy and accountability in British universities. Studies in Higher Education, 15(2), 169–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergen, M., Dutta, S., & Walker, O. C. Jr. (1992). Agency relationships in marketing: A review of the implications and applications of agency and related theories. Journal of Marketing, 56, 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birnbaum, R. (1988). How colleges work. The cybernetics of academic organization and leadership. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. R. (1977). Investment in learning. The individual and social value of American higher education. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. R. (1980). The costs of higher education. How much do colleges and universities spend per student and how much should they spend? San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, F.M., Bracco, K.R., Callan, P.M., Finney, J.E., Richardson, Jr., R.C., Trombley, W. (1997). State Structures for Governance of Higher Education: A comparative study. San Jose, CA: The California Higher Education Policy Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun, D. (1993). Who governs intermediary agencies? Principal-agent relations in research policy-making. Journal of Public Policy, 13(2), 135–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brehm, J., & Gates, S. (1993). Doughnut shops and speed traps. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 555–581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvert, R., McCubbins, M., & Weingast, B. (1989). A theory of political control and agency discretion. American Journal of Political Science, 33(3), 588–611.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cave, M., Hanney, S., Henkel, M., & Kogan, M. (1997). The use of performance indicators in higher education. The challenge of the quality movement (3rd ed.). London: Jessica Kingsley Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, B. R. (1983). The higher education system. Academic organization in cross-national perspective. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1972). A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(1), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review, 22(1), 20–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L. (1990). The ethereal hand: Organizational economics and management theory. Academy of Management Review, 15(3), 369–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, L. (1995). American anti-management theories of organization. A critique of paradigm proliferation. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, G. W., & Rocke, D. M. (1994). Conflict, agency, and gambling for resurrection: The principal-agent problem goes to war. American Journal of Political Science, 38(2), 362–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doyle, W. R. (2006). Adoption of merit-based student grant programs: An event history analysis. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 28(3), 259–285.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doyle, W. R., McLendon, M. K., & Hearn, J. C. (2005). The adoption of prepaid tuition and savings plans in the American states: An event history analysis. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Association for the Study of Higher Education, Philadelphia, PA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunn, D. (2003). Accountability, democratic theory, and higher education. Educational Policy, 17(1), 60–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duryea, E. D. (2000). The Academic corporation: A history of college and university governing boards. New York: Falmer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D. (1999). Electoral accountability and the control of politicians: Selecting good types versus sanctioning poor performance. In Przeworski, A., Stokes, S. C., & Manin, B. (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50, 5–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferris, J. M. (1991). Contracting and higher education. The Journal of Higher Education, 62(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1982). Legislative choice of regulatory reforms: Legal process or administrative process? Public Choice, 39, 33–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, K. (2006). The university as economic savior. The Chronicle of Higher Education, 52(45), A18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1993). Does monitoring increase work effort? The rivalry with trust and loyalty. Economic Inquiry, 31(4), 663–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garvin, D. A. (1980). The economics of university behavior. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geuna, A. (1999). The economics of knowledge production. Funding and structure of university research. Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S. (2005). Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4(1), 75–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gittell, M., & Kleiman, N. S. (2000). The political context of higher education. American Behavioral Scientist, 43(7), 1058–1091.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, C. A., Gates, S. M., & Brewer, D. J. (2001). Prestige or reputation: Which is a sound investment? Chronicle of Higher Education, 48(6), B13–B15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gomez-Mejia, L. R., & Balkin, D. B. (1992). Determinants of faculty pay: An agency theory perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 35(5), 921–955.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gornitzka, Å., Stensaker, B., Smeby, J-C., & de Boer, H. (2004). Contract arrangements in the Nordic countries. Solving the efficiency/effectiveness dilemma? Higher Education in Europe, 29(1), 87–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gourdrian, R., & DeGroot, H. (1990). A principal-agent model of regulation applied to the case of American universities. In Prud’homme, R. (ed.), Public finance with several levels of government (pp. 181–194). The Hague, The Netherlands: Foundation Journal Public Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T. H., & Knott, J. H. (1996). Who controls the bureaucracy? Presidential power, Congressional dominance, legal constraints and bureaucratic autonomy in a model of multi-institutional policy-making. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 12(1), 119–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hearn, J. C., & Griswold, C. P. (1994). State-level centralization and policy innovation in U.S. postsecondary education. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 16(2), 161–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, J. (2005). Beyond self-interest: Agency theory and the board in a satisfying world. British Journal of Management, 16(1), S55–S63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicklin, A., & Meier, K. (2004). Race, structure, and state governments: The politics of higher education diversity. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtta, S. (1995). Towards the self-regulative university. Publications Joensuu: University of Joensuu.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, M. J., & Shepsle, K. A. (1989). Commentary on “administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies”: Administrative process and organizational form as legislative responses to agency costs. Virginia Law Review, 75(2), 499–508.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, E. (1986). Cross-subsidization in higher education: Does it pervert private choice and public policy? In Levy, D. C. (ed.), Private education. Studies in choice and public policy (pp. 237–257). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, E. (1990). Decision processes and priorities in higher education. In Hoenack, S. A. & Collins, E. L. (eds.), The economics of American universities. Management, operations, and fiscal environment (pp. 77–106). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, E., & Neuberger, E. (1981). The university department as a non-profit labor cooperative. In Bowman, M. J. (ed.), Collective choice in education (pp. 207–234). Boston, MA: Kluwer/Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C. (1983). Organization theory and methodology. The Accounting Review, 58(2), 319–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnes, J., & Taylor, J. (1990). Performance indicators in higher education. UK universities. Buckingham: SRHE/Open University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jongbloed, B., & Vossensteyn, H. (2001). Keeping up performances: an international survey of performance-based funding in higher education. Journal of Higher Education Policy and Management, 23(2), 127–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, D. R., & McCubbins, M. (1991). The logic of delegation: Congressional parties and the appropriations process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kivisto, J. A. (2005). The government-higher education institution relationship: Theoretical considerations from the perspective of agency theory. Tertiary Education and Management, 11(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kivisto, J. A. (2007). Agency theory as a framework for the government-university relationship. Tampere: Higher Education Group/Tampere University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knott, J. H., & Payne, A. A. (2004). The impact of state governance structures on management and performance of public organizations: A study of higher education institutions. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 23(1), 13–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • LaFollette, M. C. (1994). The politics of research misconduct: Congressional oversight, universities, and science. The Journal of Higher Education, 65(3), 261–285.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J. E. (2003). State government oversight of public higher education: Police patrols and fire alarms. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Association for the Study of Higher Education, Portland, OR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J. E. (2005). State oversight of higher education: A theoretical review of agency problems with complex principals. Paper presented at 2005 Annual Conference of the Association for the Study of Higher Education, Philadelphia, PA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J. E. (2007). Spider Web of Oversight: Latent and Manifest Regulatory Controls in Higher Education. Journal of Higher Education, 78(6), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lassar W. M., & Kerr, J. L. (1996). Strategy and control in supplier-distributor relationships: An agency perspective. Strategic Management Journal, 17(8), 613–632.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liefner, I. (2003). Funding, resource allocation, and performance in higher educations systems. Higher Education, 46, 469–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowry, R. C. (2001). Governmental structure, trustee selection, and public university prices and spending. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 845–861.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lyne, M., & Tierney, M. (2003) The politics of common agency: Unitary, multiple and collective principals. Paper presented at the annual meeting of The American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, PA.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1984). The New Institutionalism: Organizational factors in political life. The American Political Science Review, 78(3), 734–749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massy, W. F. (1996). Reengineering resource allocation systems. In Massy, W. F. (ed.), Resource allocation in higher education (pp. 15–47). Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massy, W. F., & Zemsky, R. (1994). Faculty discretionary time. Departments and the “academic ratchet”. Journal of Higher Education, 65(1), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D. (1985). Legislative design of regulatory structure. American Journal of Political Science, 29(4), 721–748.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 165–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). Administrative procedures as instruments of political control. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 3(2), 243–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Structure and process, politics and policy: Administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies. Virginia Law Review, 75, 431–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLendon, M. K. (2003). The politics of higher education: Toward an expanded research agenda. Educational Policy, 17(1), 165–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLendon, M. K., Deaton, R., & Hearn, J. C. (2007). The enactment of state governance reforms in higher education. The Journal of Higher Education, 78(6), 645–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLendon, M. K., Hearn, J. C., & Deaton, R. (2006). Called to account: Analyzing the origins and spread of state performance-accountability policies for higher education. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 28(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLendon, M. K., Heller, D. E., & Young, S. (2005). State postsecondary education policy innovation: Politics, competition, and the interstate migration of policy ideas. The Journal of Higher Education, 76(4), 363–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, K. J., & Bohte, J. (2003). Not with a bang, but a whimper. Explaining organizational failures. Administration & Society, 35(1), 104–121.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mellahi, K., & Wilkinson, A. (2004). Organizational failure: A critique of recent research and a proposed integrative framework. International Journal of Management Reviews, 5/6(1), 21–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. J. (2005). The political evolution of principal-agent models. Annual Review of Political Science, 8, 203–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mintzberg, H. (1979). The structuring of organizations: A synthesis of the research. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitnick, B. M. (1980). The political economy of regulation. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (1984). The new economics of organization. American Journal of Political Science, 28(4), 739–777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (1985). Control and feedback in economic regulation: The case of the NLRB. American Political Science Review, 79(4), 1094–1116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T.M. (1989). “The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure”. In J. E. Chubb and P. E. Peterson, (eds). Can Government Govern? Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 267–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (1990). Political institutions: The neglected side of the story. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 6, 213–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (2005). Power and political institutions. Perspectives on Politics, 3(2), 215–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mora, J.-G., & Vila, L. E. (2003). The economics of higher education. In Begg, R. (ed.), The dialogue between higher education research and practice (pp. 121–134). Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray, D., & Dollery, B. (2006). Institutional breakdown? An explanatory taxonomy of Australian universities. Higher Education Policy, 19, 479–494.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicholson-Crotty, J., & Meier, K. J. (2003). Politics, structure, and public policy: The case of higher education. Educational Policy, 17(1), 80–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogul, M.S. & Rockman, B. (1990). Overseeing Oversight: New Departures and Old Problems. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 15(1), 5–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortmann, A., & Squire, R. (2000). A game-theoretic explanation of the administrative lattice in institutions of higher learning. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43, 377–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, A. A. (2003). The effects of Congressional appropriation committee membership on the distribution of federal research funding to Universities. Economic Inquiry, 41(2), 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, A. A., & Roberts, J. (2004). Government oversight of organizations engaged in multiple activities: Does centralized governance encourage quantity or quality? Unpublished manuscript, McMaster University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, T. (1993). The economics of organization: The principal-agent relationship. Acta Sociologica, 36, 277–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrow, C. (1986). Complex organizations. A critical essay (3rd ed.). New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, D. J. (eds.) (1991). The New Institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricketts, M. (2002). The economics of business enterprise. An introduction to economic organization and the theory of firm (3rd ed.). Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (1973). The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem. American Economic Review, 63(2), 134–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scholz, J. T. (1991). Cooperative regulatory enforcement and the politics of administrative effectiveness. American Political Science Review, 85(1), 115–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Boncheck, M. S. (1997) Analyzing politics: Rationality, behavior, and institutions. New York: W. W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. (1993). Information control in the principal-agent problem. International Economic Review, 34(2), 259–269.

    Google Scholar 

  • Songer, D., Segal, J. A., & Cameron, C. M. (1994). The hierarchy of justice: Testing a principal-agent model of supreme court-circuit court interactions. American Journal of Political Science, 38(3), 673–696.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toma, E. F. (1986). State university boards of trustees: A principal-agent perspective. Public Choice, 49, 155–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toma, E. F. (1990). Boards of trustees, agency problems, and university output. Public Choice, 67, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tosi, H. L. Jr., Katz, J. P., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (1997). Disaggregating the agency contract: The effects of monitoring, incentive alignment, and term in office on agent decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 40(3), 584–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trow, M. A. (1996). Trust, markets and accountability in higher education: A comparative perspective. Higher Education Policy, 9(4), 309–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vedder, R. (2004). Going broke by degree. Why college costs too much? Washington, DC: AEI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vining, A. and Globerman, S. (1999), “A Conceptual Framework for Understanding the Outsourcing Decision”, European Management Journal, 17(6), 645–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waterman, R. W., & Meier, K. J. (1998). Principal-agent models: An expansion? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8, 173–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1984). The Congressional bureaucratic system: A principal-agent perspective (with application to the SEC). Public Choice, 44(1), 147–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., & Moran, M. J. (1983). Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control: Regulatory policymaking by the federal trade commission. Journal of Political Economy, 91(5), 765–800.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whynes, D. K. (1993). Can performance monitoring solve the public services’ principal-agent problem? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 40, 434–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, G. (1995). The “marketization” of higher education: Reforms and potential reforms in higher education finance. In Dill, D. D. & Sporn, B. (eds.), Emerging patterns of social demand and university reform: Through a glass darkly. Oxford: IAU/Pergamon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. A study in the economics of internal organization. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiseman, M. S. (1999). Faculty performance: Evaluation and principal-agent concerns at Texas state-supported universities. Unpublished dissertation, Texas Tech University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, B. D. (1988). Principals, bureaucrats, and responsiveness in clean air enforcements. The American Political Science Review, 82(1), 213–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, B. D. & Waterman, R. W. (1991). The dynamics of political control of the bureaucracy. American Political Science: Review, 85(3), 801–828.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Springer Science + Business Media B.V

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lane, J.E., Kivisto, J.A. (2008). Interests, Information, and Incentives in Higher Education: Principal-Agent Theory and Its Potential Applications to the Study of Higher Education Governance. In: Smart, J.C. (eds) Higher Education. Handbook of Theory and Research, vol 23. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4020-6959-8_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics