Skip to main content

Decentralization, Fiscal Effort, and Social Progress in Colombia at the Municipal Level, 1994–2009: Why Does National Politics Matter?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Improving Access and Quality of Public Services in Latin America

Part of the book series: Latin American Political Economy ((LAPE))

  • 312 Accesses

Abstract

The chapter explores the relationship between political competition and effective public goods delivery systems in a decentralized context to study whether the awareness generated through such a competitive environment and the existence of more political options are a part of the causal mechanisms for effective governance. In particular, we want to observe the effect of electoral competition on the incentives to build fiscal capacity and provide public goods, such as education and water, that are, to a large extent, the responsibility of the local municipalities. The research hypothesis is that political competition strengthens the decentralized municipalities through building their local fiscal capacity. In turn, the fiscal capacity is the fundamental variable that explains the differences in sector performance across local governments. Local fiscal capacity brings about better policy outcomes, as well as a better match between resources and the needs—what we call responsiveness—which simultaneously ensures greater efficiency in local spending. Using a rich panel municipal data set from 1994 to 2009, we have shown that on comparing the differences across education and the water and sewerage sectors, the power of fiscal effort appears to be the driving force behind better policy outcomes than any other resource commonly made available to the municipalities, such as national transfers or royalties.

This chapter is a reduced version of the Interamerican Development Bank (IDB) Working Paper No. IDB-WP-396, available at http://bit.ly/1AK0PfO. The authors would like to thank the Global Development Network and all the participants at the workshops held during the course of this project for their support and comments. They would specially like to thank Ramona Angelescu, Guillermo Perry, Matthias Krause, Jean Paul Faguet, and Ben Ross Schneider for their very useful and insightful commentsthat helped advance the ideas that were put forth. The authors also thank Sandra Margarita Zamora, Susana Rubinstein, and Santiago de la Cadena for their research assistance, and finally they acknowledge the help given by the Social Sciences Faculty at Universidad de los Andes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The periods of mayors and governors changed to three-year term after 1994, and to four-year terms in 2003.

  2. 2.

    Before the reform, royalties would automatically be transferred to municipalities in which the extraction of resources was done. In June 2011 the Royalties Reform was approved in Congress, transforming the way in which they were regionally allocated. Instead of just transferring those to municipalities, sub-national entities need to compete for the resources by presenting projects which, in turn, need to be approved by entities with representation from the national, departmental, and local tiers of government.

  3. 3.

    In order to increase the efficiency of resource transfers, a reform of the system was undertaken in 2000. In the first place, it created a revenue sharing system (Sistema General de Participaciones, or SGP) that fixed the amount of resources to be transferred and established a 2 percent annual growth in real terms. In addition, the formula to allocate the resources across sub-national entities based on Law 60 of 1993 was also changed by the Laws 715 of 2001 and 1176 of 2007.

  4. 4.

    According to Rodden (2002), large and persistent deficits occur when the sub-national governments depend strongly on inter-governmental transfers, and have, at the same time, free access to credit, generating fiscal indiscipline.

  5. 5.

    As a matter of fact, the territorial debt rose from 1.1 to 3.5 percent of the GDP between 1990 and 1999 (Ministerio de Hacienda 2014). In an effort to better align incentives of politicians to improve their policy performance, the Law 715 determined that the transfer’s distribution would be based on the coverage and growth of the health and education services provided by the territorial entities, and not by population and poverty rates—criteria that had been established by Law 60 of 1993. Concerning the generation of own resources, Congress approved Law 488 of 1998 whereby the base for some sub-national taxes such as the register tax was increased, and Law 1111 of 2006, which raised cigarette taxes. In order to augment health revenues, Decree 127 of 2010 increased the rates of the departmental cigarette and liquors tax, as well as VAT for beer and gambling. Furthermore, the gasoline surcharge was unified, and a surcharge on petro-diesel was levied.

  6. 6.

    According to Rodriguez (2010), the lack of adequate data may explain why the results have suggested both positive and negative impacts of decentralization. Using panel data techniques, she evaluates the effects of decentralization on the quality of education in public schools, concluding that reforms increase the gap in the results of standardized test preparation applied in public and private schools. She argues that the results are driven neither by the lack of transfers from central government nor by the lack of investment of resources in the sector. They are mainly driven by the increased enrollment of poor students in public schools. When this factor is controlled for, it is found that the public education system serves a larger number of students, besides offering better quality education.

  7. 7.

    Law 142 of 1994, Article 15. Other changes introduced by Law 142 were (a) the definition of a pricing regime based on the cost of providing the service, (b) the creation of a control mechanisms of the provider performance enforced by citizens, (c) establishment of a regime of free enterprise which constitutes the base for the entry of the private sector as a provider, and (d) for the implementation of management control and internal control systems within the provider companies. See Krause (2007) for a complete explanation of the differences between EICEs and ESP.

  8. 8.

    Also, the Colombian system of user’s fees follows a cross-subsidization approach in which residential users from low socio-economic strata (1, 2, and 3) receive discounts in their fees, which are covered by fees charged from the high socio-economic strata (5 and 6) as well as by the commercial and industrial users. Due to the deficit nature of the scheme in most municipalities, central government transfers partially finance these subsidies. The remaining resources cover a fraction of the investments needed to provide the services, either through direct subsidies to the provider—that could be municipality itself—or through the delivery of physical infrastructure (Silva 2007).

  9. 9.

    “En ese entonces, casi que todos los cargos adscritos a la prestación de estos servicios eran de cuotas políticas. Entonces, que las escobitas: vaya usted, vaya usted; que la persona que se encargaba de la facturación. Personas que no tenían ni idea que tenían que hacer en un cargo de esos y era así como se colocaban las posiciones de los cargos en una empresa de pequeña estructura que tenía el municipio. No había políticas claras, no había directrices, el servicio era prácticamente regalado: la gente pagaba 20 pesos por el agua.” Manager, Water Company of el Peñol, Antioquia.

  10. 10.

    Referring to the municipalities in which the service is provided by private parties, the manager of the Water Company of El Peñol argued; “Los alcaldes generan compromisos con ese tipo de gente y vienen, ese modelo es perverso, muchas veces esa gente viene y esa gente de lo que tratan es de escurrir al usuario. Finalmente vienen, lo clavan con unas tarifas exorbitantes, le sacan el jugo al negocio, no hacen ninguna inversión y salen y se van con la plata. Entonces yo pienso que una entidad pública, siempre y cuando, se logre manejar con cierta autonomía administrativa, financiera, con cierta independencia del tema político, si se maneja así se puede manejar con unos criterios de rentabilidad más que, o sea una rentabilidad económica que le permita ser auto sostenible en el tiempo.”

  11. 11.

    This is the term used by politicians to refer to the effort to get money from the national government.

  12. 12.

    “Básicamente una buena administración en este municipio se hace con gestión. Por eso les decía yo ahora que aspiramos a ser una de las mejores administraciones que haya tenido el municipio de Santa Barbara por la coyuntura que tenemos a León Darío en la Cámara. Porque aparte de todo, él pertenece a la comisión tercera, que como ustedes bien saben es la de presupuesto y eso le da ciertas ventajas frente a algunos representantes porque ser ponentes y participar en las ponencias del presupuesto, les dan algunos incentivos.”

  13. 13.

    Several specifications were estimated for the years to the last cadastral update: lineal, quadratic, cubic, and diverse forms of dummy variables for the number of cadastral updates.

  14. 14.

    The measure of the effective number of parties is the inverse of the Herfindal Index to measure the competition among party shares of votes. The unit of analysis is the political party.

  15. 15.

    The GINI is a measure of statistical dispersion and measures the concentration across political parties. Thus, if one party controls all the votes for the House, the “political concentration” is highest (GINI of 1). If more parties do, then the “political concentration” goes down.

  16. 16.

    This is the same measure as the effective number of parties, but instead of taking the party as a unit of analysis each candidate is counted independently.

References

  • Andrews, M., and A. Shah. 2003. Towards Citizen Centered Local-level Budgets in Developing Countries. In Handbook on Public Sector Performance Reviews, vol 3, ed. Shah Anwar. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee (ed). 2006. Decentralization and Local Governance in Developing Countries: A Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrera, F., and M. Oliveira. 2007. Does Society Win or Lose as a Result of Privatization? The Case of Water Sector Privatization in Colombia. RES Working Papers 3230, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., and T. Persson. 2010. State Capacity, Conflict, and Development. Econometrica, Econometric Society 78(1): 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., T. Persson, and D.M. Sturm. 2010. Political Competition, Policy and Growth: Theory and Evidence from the US. The Review of Economic Studies 77(4): 1329–1352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cárdenas, M. 2010. State Capacity in Latin America. Economía—Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association 10(2): 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Careaga, M., and B. Weingast. 2003. Fiscal Federalism, Good Governance, and Economic Growth in Mexico. In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, ed. Dani Rodrik. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. 1987. The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political Parties in Victorian England. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Domínguez, C. and E. Uribe. 2005. Evolución del servicio de acueducto y alcantarillado durante la última década. Documentos CEDE 2005-19, Universidad de los Andes-CEDE, Bogotá.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economía Urbana—Centro Nacional de Consultoría. 2012. Una Evaluación del Impacto de las Regalías en 80 Municipalidades. Informe de Consultoría, Departamento Nacional de Planeación, Bogotá, Colombia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faguet, J. 2004. Does Decentralization Increase Government Responsiveness to Local Needs? Evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Economics 88(3–4): 867–893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faguet, J., and F. Sánchez. 2008. Decentralization’s Effects on Educational Outcomes in Bolivia and Colombia. World Development 36(7): 1294–1316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Decentralization and Access to Social Services in Colombia. Documentos CEDE 005401, Universidad de los Andes-CEDE, Bogotá.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falleti, T. 2010. Decentralization and Sub National Politics in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gadenne, L. 2011. Tax Me, But Spend Wisely: The Political Economy of Taxes, Theory and Evidence from Brazilian Local Governments. Mimeo. Paris School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaviria, A., J. G. Zapata, and A. González. 2002. Petróleo y Región: El caso del Casanare. Cuadernos de Fedesarrollo, No. 8, Bogotá, Colombia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gomez-Lobo, A. and M. Meléndez. 2007. Social Policy, Regulation and Private Sector Water Supply: the Case of Colombia. Working Papers wp252, University of Chile, Department of Economics, Santiago de Chile.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granados, C. 2008. Contribuyen las reformas al progreso social?, el caso de los servicios de acueducto y alcantarillado y la mortalidad infantil en Colombia 1990–2004. Documentos CEDE 2008-07, Universidad de los Andes-CEDE, Bogotá.

    Google Scholar 

  • ICFES. 2009. Informe de resultados nacionales, Saber 3, 5, y 9. http://www.icfes.gov.co/investigacion/informes-de-resultados-de-evaluaciones-nacionales/saber-3o-5o-y-9o

  • Junguito, R., and H. Rincón. 2004. La política fiscal en el siglo XX en Colombia. Borradores de Economía, 318, Banco de la República, Bogotá.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krause, M. 2007. The Political Economy of Water and Sanitation in Developing Countries: Cross-country Evidence and a Case Study on Colombia. Dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Economics, Department of Economics, Justus-Liebig-Universität Gießen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melo, B. 2005. Impacto de la Descentralización Fiscal sobre la Educación Pública Colombiana. Borradores de Economía 002802.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministerio de Hacienda. 2014. Responsabilidad fiscal subnacional descentralización en Colombia: Quince años de consolidación. http://www.minhacienda.gov.co/portal/page/portal/HomeMinhacienda/asistenciaentidadesterritoriales/Publicaciones/Libros/15%20anios.pdf

  • Perry, G., and M. Olivera. 2009. El impacto del petróleo y la minería en el desarrollo regional y local en Colombia. Documentos de Trabajo No. 2009/06, CAF-Caracas, Venezuela.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, N. 2006. Privatisation Results: Private Sector Participation in Water Services After 15 Years. Development Policy Review 24(6): 669–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. 2002. The Dilemma of Fiscal Federalism: Grants and Fiscal Performance Around the World. American Journal of Political Science 46(3): 670–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez, C. 2010. Correspondencia de economía política y decisiones de educación en las familias después de la descentralización. El Trimestre Económico LXXVII (4), no. 308, pp. 977–1006, October–December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez, F., and J. Zenteno. 2011. Descentralización y sostenibilidad fiscal subnacional: el caso de Colombia. Documentos CEDE 2011-37, Universidad de los Andes-CEDE, Bogotá.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez, F., I. España, and J. Zenteno. 2012. Sub-National Revenue in Latin America and the Caribbean Countries: The Case of Colombia. Mimeo, BID- Red de Centros de Investigación, Washington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, J. 2007. Reformas Estructurales en el Sector de Agua Potable y Saneamiento Básico en Colombia, 1990–2006, Mimeo. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiller, P.T., and Savedoff, W.D., 2000. Lost Water: Institutional Compromises for the Supply of Public Health Services. Agua perdida: compromisos institucionales para el suministro de servicios publicos sanitarios. Inter-American Development Bank. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. 2009. Second Generation Fiscal Federalism: The Implications of Fiscal Incentives. Journal of Urban Economics 65(3): 279–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix 1: Data sources

Appendix 1: Data sources

Variable

Source

2005 Water coverage

2005 Colombian Population Census, National Statistics Administrative Department (DANE)

Quality-local drinking water compliance

Territorial Development Office, National Planning Department (DNP)

Public school enrollment

Planning Office of the Education Ministry and DANE

Quality—ratio of SABER 11 of public to private schools

Scores from the SABER 11 test, Colombian Institute for Education Evaluation (ICFES)

Per-capita taxes

Municipal Budgetary Executions, DNP

Per-capita transfers

Municipal Budgetary Executions, DNP

Royalties

Municipal Budgetary Executions, DNP

Number of years after the reform

Public Services Superintendence

Poverty rate

For 1993 and 2005 the data were taken from the 1993 and 2005 Population Census done by the DANE. For the other years the poverty rate was calculated by CEDE

Gini of land value

The data were taken from the Geographical Institute Agustín Codazzi and calculated by CEDE

Population

2005 Colombian Population Census, DANE

Effective Number of Parties

Electoral data for each of the years since 1994 from Registraduría Nacional del Estado Civil

Council members re-election average

Electoral data for each of the years since 1994 from Registraduría Nacional del Estado Civil

Intra-party competition

Electoral data for each of the years since 1994 from Registraduría Nacional del Estado Civil

Proportion of council members from mayor’s party

Electoral data for each of the years since 1994 from Registraduría Nacional del Estado Civil

Cadastral undervaluation

The data were taken from the Geographical Institute Agustín Codazzi and calculated by CEDE

Teacher–student ratio (lagged)

Planning Office of the Education Ministry

6-year average teacher–student ratio (lagged)

Planning Office of the Education Ministry

No official students–population ratio (lagged)

Planning Office of the Education Ministry

Per-capita transfers (ln)

Territorial Development Office, National Planning Department (DNP)

Royalties (ln)

Territorial Development Office, National Planning Department (DNP)

Number of years after the reform

Public Services Superintendence

Students–population ratio

Planning Office of the Education Ministry

Public test score

Colombian Institute for Education Evaluation (ICFES)

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Torres, F.S., Pachón, M. (2017). Decentralization, Fiscal Effort, and Social Progress in Colombia at the Municipal Level, 1994–2009: Why Does National Politics Matter?. In: Perry, G., Angelescu Naqvi, R. (eds) Improving Access and Quality of Public Services in Latin America. Latin American Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-59344-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics