Skip to main content
Log in

Cartel agreement reached, but price not raised

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Journal of Economic Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines the impact of a nationwide shutter price cartel mentioned in the Japan Fair Trade Commission’s June 2010 press release using producers’ shipment data obtained from publicly available information statistics. The economics literature has referred to cartel overcharges in excess of 20%. However, in reality, price hikes by cartels should be very difficult to implement under economic deflation. In our case, the realized price hike was only 4% against the agreed 10% hike. The reasons for this limited hike may be as follows: (i) seasonal factors, that is, bad months for fixing prices; (ii) excessively high price elasticity for price fixing; and (iii) the effect of cartels on inappropriate management perspectives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Availability of data and materials

Derived data supporting the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author on request.

Notes

  1. This cartel case began with the hearing of the JFTC on October 4, 2010. With this case, the JFTC took up the order adjustment issue in Kinki district in Japan to find that the companies had decided the prospective winners through private auction (request for an estimate) discussions in advance with a construction company. The JFTC concluded that this violated the Antimonopoly Act, and issued a cease-and-desist order to the business operators along with a surcharge payment order. This was also disputed in the JFTC hearing process.

  2. The software: EViews Version 11.0 (IHS Inc., Douglas County, CO, USA).

References

  1. Allain, M.-L., Boyer, M., Kotchoni, R., & Ponssard, J.-P. (2015). Are cartel fines optimal? Theory and evidence from the European Union. International Review of Law Economics, 42, 38–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Asker, J. (2011). Leniency and post-cartel market conduct: Preliminary evidence from parcel tanker shipping. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(4), 407–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Bolotova, Y. (2009). Cartel overcharges: An empirical analysis. Jourlan of Econnomic Behavavior & Organization, 70, 321–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bonnet, C., & Zohra, B. M. (2020). Empirical methodology for the evaluation of collusive behaviour in vertically-related markets: An application to the “yogurt cartel” in France. International Review of Law and Economics, 61(C), 105872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Bos, I., Stephen, D., Harrington, J. E., Jr., & Ormosi, P. L. (2018). Does enforcement deter cartels? A tale of two tails. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 50, 372–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Boyer, M., & Kotchoni, R. (2015). How much do cartel overcharge? Review of Industrial Organization, 47(2), 119–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bresnahan, T. F. (1989). Empirical methods for industries with market power. In R. Schmalensee & R. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization (Vol. 2, pp. 1011–1058). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publication B.V.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Bresnahan TF, Baker J. Empirical methods of identifying and measuring market power. Antitrust Law Journal. 1992; Summer 1992.

  9. Connor JM. Price-fixing overcharges: Revised 3rd Edition; 2014. SSRN-2400780. Available at: SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2400780

  10. Connor, J. M., & Bolotova, Y. (2006). A meta-analysis of cartel overcharges. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1109–1137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Connor, J. M., & Lande, R. H. (2005). How high do cartels raise prices? Implications for optimal cartel fines. Tulane Law Review, 80, 513–570.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Fox, N. R. (1992). An empirical analysis of ocean liner shipping. International Journal of Transportataion Economics, 19, 205–225.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Genesove, D., & Wallace, P. (2001). Rules, communication, and collusion: Narrative evidence from the sugar institute case. Americn Economic Review, 91, 379–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Hellwig, M., & Kai, H. (2018). When do firms leave cartels? Determinants and the impact on cartel survival. International Review of Law and Economics, 54, 68–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Igami M, Sugaya T. Measuring the incentive to collude: The vitamin cartels, 1990–1999. Review of Economic Studies 2021; forthcoming. available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2889837

  16. Levenstein, M. C., & Suslow, V. Y. (2006). What determines cartel success? Journal of Economic Literature, 69, 43–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Lopez-Morell, M. A., & Luciano, S. (2015). The international mercury cartel, 1928–1954: Controlling global supply. Bussiness History Review, 89, 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Mardanugraha E. Indirect evidence of cartel in Indonesian garlic trade. JEPA 2018 annual meeting; October 27, 2018. Kanagawa, Japan.

  19. Miller, N. H. (2009). Strategic Leniency and cartel enforcement. American Economic Review, 99(3), 750–768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Miller NH, Sheu G, Weinberg MC. Oligopolistic price leadership and mergers: The United States beer industry. American Economic Review, 2021; forthcoming. Available at: http://www.nathanhmiller.org/priceleadership.pdf

  21. Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry 2011–19. The Industrial Statistics.

  22. Mncube, L. (2014). The South African wheat flour cartel: Overcharges at the mill. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 14(4), 487–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Nieberding, J. F. (2006). Estimating overcharges in antitrust cases using a reduced-form approach: Methods and issues. Journal of Applied Economics, 11, 361–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Porter, R. (1983). A study of cartel stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886. Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 301–314.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  25. Setten F., & Sorgard, L. Semicollusion. Now Publishers, 2010, Boston, MI.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Hiroyuki Odagiri and seminar participants at the Competition Policy Research Center for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this study. Reiko Murakami's comments on an earlier version of this study in a presentation at the Japan Economic Policy Association annual meeting improved this study. The author would like to thank her for the comments. Two anonymous reviewers provided helpful comments in the preparation of this paper. The author would like to express my gratitude to them.

Funding

This work was supported by JSPS KAKENHI (Grant Number 19K01610 and 23K01404).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Koki Arai.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Raw data were generated at Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry 2011–2019, the Industrial Statistics.

Competing interests

None.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Japan Fair Trade Commission, Hearing Decision, September 2, 2020

Appendix: Japan Fair Trade Commission, Hearing Decision, September 2, 2020

Contents of the agreement between three shuttering companies to raise prices by 10%

Rationality of the nationwide agreement

First, it is possible for the sales representatives of the three companies to implement a price increase by a certain percentage of the base transaction price (the current price), assuming that the price increase is based on the estimated price and the unit price per square meter, calculated by multiplying a certain discount rate using past transactions as indicators.

Next, to raise the selling price, the three companies have actually used the method of raising the total cost price, and the employees of the three companies have stated that raising the total cost price is an effective means of raising the selling price. In addition, in the trading field of specific shutters, it is not unreasonable to raise the total price as a means to raise the selling price. Further, if the three companies, which have a combined market share of more than 90% in the specific shutter business field, present their quoted prices at the same time with the same range of increase, the possibility of losing customers is reduced, compared to the case where they conduct price increase activities alone. They will be able to negotiate at a higher price level than before. Thus, it cannot be denied that this will result in avoiding competition. Therefore, it cannot be said that such an agreement itself is unreasonable even if there are times when the sales price do not increase as agreed, due to the power relationship with consumers or economic conditions.

Furthermore, it is obvious that the rate of price increase may vary due to the nature of transactions in which prices are determined through individual negotiations. Even if individual prices are determined by each sales office or sales representative, the premise for such determination is the sales policy of the head office. The fact that the head office does not have the authority to decide on individual prices does not mean that it is impossible to implement a price increase based on the agreement by instructing the head office to implement price increase activities in accordance with the policy presented to each sales office.

Communication of intentions ("Jointly")

In order to fall under the category of "jointly" as set forth in Article 2, Paragraph 6 of the Antimonopoly Act, it is understood that there must be communication of intentions among multiple business operators in raising the price. It is not sufficient for one party to simply recognize and accept the other party's increase in consideration; however, it is not necessary for the parties to expressly agree to be bound by each other's increase in consideration. It is reasonable to conclude that it is sufficient to mutually recognize and tacitly accept the act of other businesses of raising the consideration.

In making such a judgment, the court should consider what the recognition and intention of the business operators were, taking into account the various circumstances before and after the increase in the consideration, and determine whether there is joint recognition and acceptance among the business operators. If a specific business operator (i) exchanges information with other business operators regarding the act of raising the consideration, (ii) takes the same or similar action, and (iii) there exists a relationship between these business operators in which they are expected to take cooperative action, unless there are special circumstances that indicate that the action was taken based on their own judgment that it can withstand competition for consideration in the transaction market, irrespective of the actions of other business operators, then, in the case of an increase in the price, the increase in the price is expected to be lower than the increase in the previous year.

  • (a) Exchange of information on price increase actions.

    At the March 5, 2008 meeting, it is recognized that the two parties exchanged information regarding the implementation of the increase in the price of the shutters, etc., rather than merely making small talk.

  • (b) Consistency of post-facto actions.

    Although none of the three companies had set a target of raising the sales price of the specified shutters by 10% prior to the March 5 meeting, after the March 5 meeting, they set a target of raising the sales price of the specified shutters by 10% and instructed their respective branches and sales offices to raise the sales price. Therefore, it is recognized that the three companies took the same action to raise the sales price of the specified shutters by about 10% from the current price.

  • (c) Existence or non-existence of special circumstances indicating that the three companies acted on their own judgment in raising prices.

    According to (a) and (b) above, unless there are special circumstances indicating that the actions of each of the three companies to raise prices were taken independently and based on their own judgment that they could withstand competition in the trading market, it is presumed that there is communication of intent. In this case, it cannot be recognized that the agreement was made based on the independent judgment of the three companies.

Inference of the nationwide agreement

(1) The three companies exchanged information regarding the act of raising the price of shutters, etc., by approximately 10% percent. (2) The three companies set a target of raising the selling price of the specified shutters by 10% after April 1, 2008 at their respective headquarters, and conducted sales activities to raise the selling price. (3) It is recognized that the three companies took the same action of setting the sales price increase at 10% and conducted sales activities to increase the sales price. It is considered to be an unnatural coincidence that after the March 5 meeting, the three companies set "10%" as the target, at the same time as the information exchange, even though the three companies had different considerations on the range of increase before the March 5 meeting. (4) There is no particular circumstance indicating that the three companies' actions to raise the price were made based on their own judgment that the price could withstand competition in the trading market and independently of the actions of the other two companies that exchanged information at the March 5 meeting. Therefore, it is presumed that the three companies mutually anticipated that the sale price of the specified shutters would be increased by approximately 10% from the current price and intended to keep pace with this increase.

Although the timing of the price increase was not clearly stated at the March 5 meeting, the agreement to raise the price of shutter products is in line with the price increase of steel, a raw material, after April 1, 2008. In principle, the price of shutter products is raised through price negotiations with consumers based on the quoted price provided by the shutter manufacturer; hence, it is presumed that the three companies agreed to raise the price at least from the quoted price on the same day.

Therefore, it is presumed that the three companies communicated their intentions based on the nationwide agreement.

(in Japanese: https://www.jftc.go.jp/houdou/pressrelease/2020/sep/200902_2.html).

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Arai, K. Cartel agreement reached, but price not raised. IJEPS 18, 259–282 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-023-00127-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-023-00127-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation