Skip to main content
Log in

Trust in generosity: an experiment of the repeated Yes–No game

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Compared to ultimatum games allowing for altruistic sanctioning via monitoring, Yes–No games only allow for unmonitored altruistic sanctioning. Game theoretically, the sequentially rational outcomes (for non-positive conflict payoffs of the responder) coincide, but the large multiplicity of equilibrium outcomes of ultimatum games is avoided by Yes–No games. As Avrahami et al. (J Socio-Econ 47: 47–54, 2013) for the ultimatum game, we experimentally implemented 100-period plays of Yes–No games for newly and randomly rematched player pairs to test whether their observation of fast and nearly universal convergence to equal sharing depends on its equilibrium property. Will there be significant altruistic sanctioning, convergence to solution play, or cyclicity in behavior? There are two possible pie sizes which either only proposers or both players know. The dynamics of play differ fundamentally from the quick convergence to equal sharing for ultimatum games. There is neither convergence to equal sharing nor to equilibrium play, but persistent heterogeneity in offers and (non)acceptance. Some participants engage in game theoretically unpredicted sanctioning even in later periods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Only a few randomly selected pairs were actually paid.

  2. We refrain from a systematic comparison of YNGs with other game paradigms in experimental economics, (social and economic) psychology, and beyond. For a recent survey of the experimental literature of ultimatum and related games, see Güth and Kocher (2014).

  3. The equilibrium dictates that the proposer offers 1 and the responder always accepts. This is consistent with the unique equilibrium in the Info treatment and the unique Bayesian equilibrium in the No Info treatment.

  4. Note that we assume an awareness of YNG-rules. Without such an awareness initial repeated play would likely rely on the law of effect, specifically on reinforcement learning (see Erev and Roth 1998, for an application to repeated ultimatum play).

  5. Whereas UG-rules risk to crowd out intrinsic work motivations (related to this, see Falk and Kosfeld 2006), which could be much stronger when employers rely on trust, the risk of YNG-rules is that they may trigger free-riding of opportunistic employees.

  6. See Güth and Kocher (2014) for various sharing games and their experimental results

  7. This endogenous multiplier is the decisive difference between the YNG and the trust game of Berg et al. (1995) with an exogenously constant multiplier.

  8. Altruism may not be restricted to responder participants who can engage in altruistic sanctioning. It could also induce proposer participants to abstain more or less from greedy behavior whose future consequences could harm other proposer participants.

  9. Random rematching did not rule out the possibility that participants meet again in the future periods as the size of a matching group was quite small as compared to the number of periods. This may contribute to the emergence of some kind of indirect reciprocity. The results reported in this paper may not generalize to perfectly stranger random rematching.

  10. Only positive offers were possible in our experiment so that the YNG possesses a unique equilibrium. We also excluded negative offers because allowing for negative offers would render the YNG a social dilemma game, similar to YNGs with only positive offers in which the lowest positive offer is below the responder’s positive conflict payoff.

  11. This independent elicitation of the proposer’s and the responder’s strategy is similar to that of Avrahami et al. (2013) who used the monotonic strategy method (responder participants had to state acceptance thresholds). Game theoretically, it does not matter for the YNG whether the responder choice is elicited before, simultaneously, or after the proposer’s allocation proposal as long as the responder cannot condition (non)acceptance on the proposal.

  12. Our experiment was run without imposing a time limit per period; participants were allowed to submit their decisions at their own pace. Only during the first 10 periods did we observe very slow responses.

  13. Of course, the effectiveness of such sanctioning relies on how proposers perceive rejection. Since responders cannot condition rejection on the offer, proposers may consider rejection just as bad luck, not as sanctioning.

  14. This phenomenon was observed in the UG experiment by Hoffman et al. (1996) and in the YNG experiment by Güth and Kirchkamp (2012). These studies also reported that rejection rates are lower for higher stakes.”

  15. See footnote 14.

  16. We use the following R’s packages: lme4 package (version 1.1.21) to estimate random effect models and texreg package (version 1.36.23) by Leifeld (2013) to generate the tables for estimation results.

  17. The fact that offering 4 is the median offer in case of \(\pi =24\) in the No Info treatment (see Table 1) also illustrates “hiding greed behind the small pie” by large-pie proposers in the No Info treatment, i.e., when they have moral wiggle room.

  18. As long as the responder’s conflict payoff is not positive.

References

  • Angelovski A, Di Cagno D, Grieco D, Güth W (2019) Trusting versus monitoring: an institutional choice experiment. Evol Inst Econ Rev. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-019-00126-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avrahami J, Güth W, Hertwig R, Kareev Y, Otsubo H (2013) Learning (not) to yield: an experimental study of evolving ultimatum game behavior. J Socio-Econ 47:47–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg J, Dickhaut J, McCabe K (1995) Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Game Econ Behav 10:122–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dana J, Weber RA, Kuang JX (2007) Exploiting moral wiggle room: experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Econ Theory 33:67–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dulleck U, Kershbamer R, Sutter M (2011) The economics of credence goods: an experiment on the role of liability, verifiability, reputation, and competition. Am Econ Rev 101:526–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniela DC, Galliera A, Güth W, Panaccione L (2018) Gender differences in yielding to social influence: an impunity experiment. Games 9:86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erev I, Roth A (1998) Predicting how people play games: reinforcement learning in experimental games with unique, mixed strategy equilibria. Am Econ Rev 88:848–881

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Kosfeld M (2006) The hidden costs of control. Am Econ Rev 96:1611–1630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Kirchsteiger G, Riedl A (1998) Gift exchange and reciprocity in competitive experimental markets. Eur Econ Rev 42:1–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher U (2007) z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10:171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrig T, Güth W, Levati V, Levínský R, Ockenfels A, Uske T, Weiland T (2007) Buying a pig in a poke: an experimental study of unconditional veto power. J Econ Psychol 28:692–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner B (2015) Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. J Econ Sci Assoc 1:114–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Huck S, Ockenfels P (1996) Two-level ultimatum bargaining with incomplete information: an experimental study. Econ J 106:593–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Kirchkamp O (2012) Will you accept without knowing what? The Yes-No game in the newspaper and in the lab. Exp Econ 15:656–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Kocher MG (2014) More than thirty years of ultimatum bargaining experiments: motives, variations, and a survey of the recent literature. J Econ Behav Org 108:396–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, McCabe KA, Smith VL (1996) On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. Int J Game Theory 25:289–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leifeld P (2013) texreg: conversion of statistical model output in R to LATEX and HTML tables. J Stat Softw 55:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hironori Otsubo.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest

Informed consent

To register for experiments at the Max Planck Institute, all participants were required to accept the laboratory’s rules and privacy policy. This procedure fulfilled informed consent requirements.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We would like to thank Claudia Zellmann and Adrian Liebtrau for their excellent assistance in data collection and an anonymous referee for constructive comments and suggestions. Generous financial support from the Max Planck Society is gratefully acknowledged.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (PDF 33 kb)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Güth, W., Otsubo, H. Trust in generosity: an experiment of the repeated Yes–No game. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 18, 63–77 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00170-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00170-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation