Skip to main content
Log in

An Analysis of the Financing Decisions of REITs: The Role of Market Timing and Target Leverage

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the role of capital market conditions and target leverage on the marginal financing decisions of Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs), which include both capital raising and capital reduction activities. We investigate the relevance of a hybrid hypothesis whereby REITs have target leverage, but they also choose and time their marginal financing decisions according to the capital market conditions. The empirical results suggest that target leverage behavior plays a secondary role to market timing behavior in the financing decisions of REITs. In particular, we find strong and consistent evidence that REITs exhibit market timing behavior in terms of when and what type of capital to issue or reduce. Such market timing practices, motivated by attempts to take advantage of capital market conditions, may shift the firms away from their target leverage. However, we observe that in the long run, most REITs do move their capital structure towards the target debt level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Interest charges account for between 30% and 70% of the total expenses incurred by REITs in our study sample.

  2. Firstly, REITs do not pay corporate tax; consequently, the tax benefit associated with using debt, which is central to the trade-off models, is not so applicable in the REIT context (Jaffe 1991). Secondly, equity REITs buy and hold properties, which are tangible and not firm-specific assets (Gentry and Mayer 2002). Consequently, they are less exposed to bankruptcy and agency costs as compared to firms in other industries. Third, the transparent nature of REITs’ operations implies lower information asymmetry between the insiders and outsiders. REITs also operate under more stringent corporate governance and reporting rules. Fourth, due to the high distribution requirement, REIT managers have less discretion to engage in managerial opportunism or over-investment activities. Even successful REITs have to raise capital externally and are, hence, subjected to frequent monitoring and disciplining in the capital market (Ghosh et al. 1997).

  3. Titman and Wessels (1988) further argue that small firms rely less on equity issues because they face a higher per unit cost. Consequently, they have no choice but to rely more on debt capital.

  4. Baker and Wurgler (2002), in contrast, contend that this relationship reflect the practice of firms timing their equity issuances to periods when their M/B ratios are high because managers believe that shares of such firms are overvalued.

  5. Using data of repurchase from 1997 to 1999, Ghosh et al. (2008) estimate a logistic model of the decision to repurchase. Whilst the main focus of the study was on the role of executive stock options, they find that REIT uses repurchase announcements to signal undervaluation. Brau and Holmes (2006) also observe that REIT managers initiate repurchases when they perceive that the stocks are undervalued.

  6. Ghosh et al. (1997) also observe that REITs issued equity three times more frequently than debt and raised almost twice as much through equity than debt between 1991 and 1996.

  7. Whilst REIT stock returns and general stock returns have moved in tandem in the earlier years, they have started to diverge from each other in the mid 1990s. The divergence allows an examination of the correlation between the level of REIT equity issues and the broader stock market condition. Interestingly, the pattern exhibited in Fig. 3 appears to indicate that the aggregate dollar amount of equity offerings by REITs tend to follow more closely to the general stock market performance than to the REIT sector performance. For instance, the equity offering surge observed between 1995 and 1998 corresponded with above 20% annual return in S&P 500, whilst a sharp drop in the REIT sector’s performance in 1998 did not slow the pace of REITs equity offerings. On the other hand, the sharp decline in equity issuance activities during 2000–2002 coincided with below -10% returns in S&P 500, whereas the NAREIT equity-REITs Index registered healthy returns during the same period.

  8. Since NAREIT and COMPUSTAT do not provide data on bank commitment of REITs, we employ the flow-of-fund data published by Federal Reserve to provide an overview of the aggregate private bank versus public debt fund flow into the REIT sector.

  9. Prior to the legislation, REITs functioned primarily as passive income-producing asset owner and operator under a third-party management structure. However, after 1986, REITs were allowed to self-manage. Since then, equity REITs have increasingly become like real estate operating corporations that engage in a wide range of real estate activities, including leasing, development of real property and tenant services.

  10. Although the statements of cash flow do not pick up any non-cash transactions, such as exchange offers, this limitation does not detract us from focusing on the normal financing activities of REITs, instead of exceptional equity or debt issuance events related to major mergers or corporate restructuring. The main advantage of adopting the cash flow-approach is that private debt, which constitute a significant proportion of REITs’ debt structure, is included in the study sample.

  11. This classification is consistent with Baker and Wurgler (2002) and Fama and French (2002). Boudry et al. (2007) also find that REITs view preferred equity as a substitute for debt.

  12. The filtering criteria for debt issues is less restrictive than equity issues because debt issues are reported as “net” amount as compared to “gross” amount in the case equity issues. For illustration, the cash flow statement of Equity Office Properties Trust recorded that it drew $5.169 billion from its lines of credit, whilst paying back $ 5.987 billion in 2000. In our classification, the financing activities would be categorized as a net reduction in debt amounting to $ 818 million. Note that the distinction between ‘net” and “gross” is less critical for equity financing because seasoned equity offerings and stock repurchases are often made separately.

  13. Hovakimian et al. (2001), Baker and Wurgler (2002), Frank and Goyal (2003), Huang and Ritter (2004) and Leary and Roberts (2005) adopted similar classifications and filtering criterion.

  14. Recent studies which have employed MNL models to examine the financing choices of firms include Guedes and Opler (1996), Huang and Ritter (2004), and Boudry et al. (2007).

  15. The purpose of this first stage regression is to provide an estimate of each firm’s optimal or target leverage ratio, which is define as the debt ratio that firms would choose in the absence of information asymmetries, transaction costs, or other adjustment costs (Hovakimian et al. 2001).

  16. Several authors have pointed out that M/B is both a proxy for mispricing and growth opportunity (Pagan et al. 1998; Kayhan and Titman 2007).

  17. To interpret coefficients of the MNL model, it is helpful to bear in mind that the probability of each marginal financing activity is measured against the base alternative, which in our case is the “passive” option. Thus, a significantly positive coefficient estimate in the equity issuance equation would indicate that high values of the variable increase the probability of an equity issue against the no transaction alternative.

  18. Whilst we appreciate that the net effect of a dual issue is actually dependent on the relative size of new equity and debt capital issued, our classification of dual issues as leverage-neutral assumes that the mix of new debt and equity raised is similar to the existing leverage of the individual REITs (see Gentry and Mayer 2002).

  19. If firms, on average, experience a positive drift in their equity values, Leary and Roberts (2005) argue that leverage has a natural tendency to decline. Thus, they posit that to counteract this tendency, firms will lever up more often than down if they are rebalancing their debt ratios.

  20. As highlighted by Boudry et al. (2007), an implicit assumption of the MNL model is the Irrelevance of Independent Alternative, which tends to be violated when alternatives are close substitute of each other. Thus, by condensing the financing choices faced by REITs, our subsequent analysis reduces the likelihood of this assumption being violated.

  21. Using partial adjustment models, Jalilvand and Harris (1984) and Fama and French (2002) note that debt ratios adjust slowly towards the firms’ targets. In a recent study, Leary and Roberts (2005) show that the speed with which firms reverse deviations from their target debt ratios depends on the trade-off between costs of adjusting leverage and the costs of operating with suboptimal leverage. They show that in a frictionless world, firms would always maintain their target leverage.

  22. We also estimated the corresponding MNL model embracing the three decisions with the dependent variables coded 1 for equity issuers and 2 for dual issuers with the base alternative being debt issuers. Since the results are similar to the logistic models, they are not reported here.

  23. The pre-and post-event deviation from target leverage of dual issuers, as exhibited in Fig. 6, also follows a time path pattern that is more consistent with equity issuers rather than debt issuers.

  24. Note that profitability is, nevertheless, included in the first-stage regression to derive the firm’s target leverage.

  25. As pointed out by one of the referees, it seems important to know whether the firm purchased or sold assets in a particular quarter. Thus, we also re-estimate the regression with an additional variable to proxy capital expenditures of the individual REITs. The results, which are not presented, confirm that firms which raised capital in the current quarter experienced higher asset growth rate in the next quarter. This is consistent with the finding of Leary and Roberts (2005) that firms with large anticipated investment expenses are more likely to use external financing.

References

  • Ang, J. J., & McConnell J. (1982). The administrative costs of corporate bankruptcy: a note. Journal of Finance, 37, 219–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M., Greenwood, R., & Wurgler, J. (2003). The maturity of debt issues and predictable variation in bond returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 70, 261–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M., & Wurgler J. (2000). The equity share in new issues and aggregate stock returns. Journal of Finance, 55, 2219–2257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M., & Wurgler, J. (2002). Market timing and capital structure. Journal of Finance, 57, 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brau, J. C., & Holmes, A. (2006). Why do REITs repurchase stocks? Extricating the effect of managerial signaling in open market share repurchase announcements. Journal of Real Estate Research, 28(1), 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudry, W. I., Kallberg, J. G., & Liu, C. H. (2007). An analysis of REIT security issuance decisions. Working paper.

  • Brown, D. T., & Riddiough, T. J. (2003). Financing choice and liability structure of real estate investment trusts. Real Estate Economics, 31(3), 313–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittmar, A. K. (2000). Stock repurchase wave. Journal of Business, 73(3), 331–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, F. E., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2002). Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividends and debt. The Review of Financial Studies, 15, 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng, Z., Ghosh, C., & Sirmans, C. F. (2007). On the capital structure of real estate investment trusts. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34(1), 81–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery, M. J., & Rangan, K. P. (2006). Partial adjustment toward target capital structures. Journal of Financial Economics, 79, 469–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, M. Z., & Goyal, V. K. (2003). Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 217–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentry, W. M., & Mayer, C. J. (2002). What can we learn about investment & capital structure with better measure of q? Working paper, University of Columbia.

  • Gentry, W. M., & Mayer, C. J. (2003). The effects of share prices relative to ‘fundamental’ value on share issuances and repurchases’. Working paper, University of Columbia.

  • Ghosh, C., Harding, J., Sezer, O., & Sirmans, C. F. (2008). The role of executive stock options in REIT repurchases. Journal of Real Estate Research, 30, 27–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, C., Nag, R., & Sirmans, C. F. (1997). Financing choice by equity REITs in the 1990s. Real Estate Finance, 14(3), 41–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, C., Nag, R., & Sirmans, C. F. (1999). An analysis of seasoned equity offerings by equity REITs (1991–1995). Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 19(3), 175–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, J. R., & Harvey, C. R. (2001). The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics, 60, 187–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guedes, J., & Opler, T. (1996). The determinants of the maturity of corporate debt issues. Journal of Finance, 51(5), 1809–1833.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovakimian, A. (2004). The role of target leverage in security issues and repurchases. Journal of Business, 77(4), 1041–1071.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovakimian, A., Hovakimian, G., & Tehranian, H. (2004). Determinants of target capital structure: the case of dual debt and equity issuers. Journal of Financial Economics, 71, 517–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovakimian, A., Opler, T., & Titman, S. (2001). The debt–equity choice. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 36(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, R., & Ritter, J. R. (2004). Testing the windows-of-opportunity theory of capital structure. Working paper, University of Florida.

  • Jaffe, J. (1991). Taxes and the capital structure of partnerships, REITs, and related entities. Journal of Finance, 46, 401–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jalilvand, A., & Harris, R. S. (1984). Corporate behavior in adjusting to capital structure and dividend targets: An econometric study. Journal of Finance, 39, 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jung, K., Kim, Y.-C., & Stulz, R. M. (1996). Timing, investment opportunities, managerial discretion, and the securities issue decision. Journal of Financial Economics, 42, 159–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kayhan, A., & Titman, S. (2007). Firms’ histories and their capital structures. Journal of Financial Economics, 83, 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leary, M., & Roberts, M. R. (2005). Do firms rebalance their capital structure? Journal of Finance, 60(6), 2575–2619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., Ibrahim, M. F., Ong, S. E., & Ooi, J. T. L. (2006). Market timing and REIT capital structure changes. Working paper, National University of Singapore.

  • Marsh, P. (1982). The choice between equity and debt: an empirical study. Journal of Finance, 37, 121–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. S. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ooi, J. T. L. (2000). Managerial opportunism and the capital structure decisions of property companies. Journal of Property Investment & Finance, 18(3), 316–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagan, O., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. (1998). Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance, 53, 27–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter, J. R. (2002). The windows of opportunity theory of capital structure. Working paper, University of Florida.

  • Shyam-Sunder, L., & Myers, S. C. (1999). Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 51, 219–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strebulaev, I. A. (2007). Do test of capital structure theory mean what they say? Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1747–1787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R. M. (1990). Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 501–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Titman, S., & Wessels, R. (1988). The determinants of capital structure. Journal of Finance, 43, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warner, J. (1977). Bankruptcy costs: some evidence. Journal of Finance, 32, 337–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Z., & Riddiough, T. (2005). Bank line of credit, REIT investment and banking relationship. Working paper, University of Wisconsin-Madison.

Download references

Acknowledgement

We would like to thank Brent Ambrose, David Downs, Glenn Mueller and participants at the 2006 American Real Estate and Urban Economics (AREUEA) international meeting in Vancouver and the 2008 American Real Estate Society (ARES) meeting in Captiva for their valuable comments. We also acknowledge the constructive reviews of two anonymous referees. All remaining errors are sole responsibility of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joseph T. L. Ooi.

Additional information

This paper is the winner of the best paper on Real Estate Finance award (sponsored by Real Capital Analytics) presented at the 2008 American Real Estate Society Meeting in Captiva Island, Florida.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ooi, J.T.L., Ong, SE. & Li, L. An Analysis of the Financing Decisions of REITs: The Role of Market Timing and Target Leverage. J Real Estate Finan Econ 40, 130–160 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-008-9127-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-008-9127-1

Keywords

Navigation