Skip to main content
Log in

Young Mr. Mises and younger historicists: origins of Mises’s liberalism

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Mises’s very first expression of a liberal outlook is usually associated with the 1919 Nation, Economy, and State because very little is known about his earlier work. Several recent studies, however, suggest that the Viennese social space and the Habsburg’s socioeconomic reality influenced Mises’s liberalism during his studies at the University of Vienna. This paper shows that Mises’s liberal outlook traces back to his early work, influenced by Younger Historicist members of the Verein für Sozialpolitik, such as Knapp and Grünberg. We argue that Mises’s early work expressed a rationalist liberal outlook that intertwined with the social policy reform aspirations of the Verein für Sozialpolitik.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Schmoller was a professor at the University of Halle from 1864 to 1872 (Nau 2000).

  2. Schmoller, Gustav. 1873. Eröffnungsrede in Verhandlungen der Eisenacher Versammlung zur Besprechung der socialen Frage am 6 und 7 Oktober 1872, Leipzig, Germany S. 4. Similarly, Schmoller argued in the 1875Über einige Grundfragen des Rechts und der Volkswirtschaft that the Verein was the third way between the Manchester School and the Social Democrats.

  3. Hayek (1960) writes that he imports the definition of rationalism from Bernard Groethuysen in “Rationalism,” Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, vol. 13, p.113.

  4. Dietzel (1900) writes about the individualist/collective divide of social reform to explain how social policy reform connects liberalism with interventionism. He defines liberalism as an outgrowth of rationalism and methodological individualism. Dietzel (ibid) argues that the collective principle that prioritizes collective welfare over individual welfare justifies interventionism as means of liberal social policy. Heinrich Dietzel (1857–1935) was a German economist and representative of the last generation of Younger Historicists.

  5. Bismarck’s Anti-Socialist Legislation (1878–1889) lapsed in 1890 (Congleton 2011). Bismarck’s government implemented it in response to two failed assassination attempts on Wilhelm I in 1878. The legislation aimed to curtail the political activity of the Social Democrats, including outlawing trade unions and closing socialist newspapers.

  6. In 1891, Bismarck’s government passed an act allowing factory workers to establish committees for overseeing work conditions (Grimmer-Solem 2003).

  7. In his Memoirs, Mises criticizes both Grünberg’s work and his early work for following Knapp’s system because of its historicism (Mises, [1978] 2009: 6). We take this statement with skepticism as with any autobiographical publication.

  8. Mises completed active army service between October 1, 1902 and September 30, 1903 (Hülsmann 2007: 74).

  9. After his enrollment in the Faculty of Law at the University of Vienna, Mises started working on a thesis project in the Grünberg seminar in the spring of 1901. The thesis project turned into his first academic publication. Hülsmann (2007: 69–73) provides an English-language summary of this book, and Krasnozhon and Bunyk (2018) present a detailed analysis of it.

  10. Galicia, the birthplace of Mises, is now within the borders of modern Ukraine. In 1772, Russia, Prussia, and Austria partitioned Poland. Austria annexed Galicia.

  11. For an English-language translation of Wimbersky (1906), please see Greaves and McGee (1993: 104). Wimbersky published two books on the history of agrarian social reform in Austria: Ernst Mischler and Hubert Wimbersky, Die landwirtschaftlichen Dienstboten in der Steiermark, Graz 1907 (Agricultural workers in Styria) and Hubert Wimbersky, Eine obersteirische Bauerngemeinde in ihrer wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung 1498–1899, Graz 1907 (Economic Development of Peasantry in Upper Styria, 1498–1899). Mischler was a student of Theodor von Inama-Sternegg (1843–1908), a head of the Austrian Office of Statistics and a leading representative of the historical economists in Austria (Grimmer-Solem 2003).

  12. Franko earned a PhD in History from the University of Vienna in 1893. He was a member of the editorial board of the Polish newspaper Kurjer Lvowski, founded by Studnicki in Lemberg, Galicia, and a regular correspondent for the Viennese democratic weekly, Die Zeit.

  13. We are aware of the following six reviews of Mises (von Mises 1902): five German-language reviews (Wimbersky 1906; Kaser 1904; Hülsmann 2007; Ludwig 1904; Studnicki 1903) and one Ukrainian-language review (Franko 1902).

  14. Cohn (1906) writes that Austrian newspapers anticipated with excitement the Mannheim convention but it failed to provide new policy solutions. Cohn (ibid.) points out that Schmoller who led the discussion on antitrust policy strongly opposed nationalization of railways as a policy option. Mises had probably joined the Verein by that time (Boese 1939). In 1909, in Vienna, Mises attended the seminars organized by Philippovich at the Verein meetings (Hülsmann 2007: 195). Hülsmann (2007: 73-74) discusses Kaser (1904), Ludwig (1904), and Kaindl (1904).

  15. Mises (1904) is a three-page research note that briefly reviews the history of Austrian social security system. It focuses on disability payments and retirement benefits. For more details, see Kott (1996) that compares German social security system to French one in the late nineteenth century. Like Austrian social reform, German social security reform focused on disability payments. By contrast, French reform prioritized retirement benefits.

References

  • Backhouse, R. (1985). A history of modern economic analysis. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balabkins, N. (1988). Not by Theory Alone...The Economics of Gustav von Schmoller and Its Legacy to America. Berlin: Duncker und Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blum, J. (1945). Land tenure in the Austrian monarchy before 1848. Agricultural History, 19(2), 87–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boese, F. (1939). Geschichte des Vereins für Sozialpolitik 1872 – 1932, Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

  • Boettke, P. J. (2018). F. a. Hayek: Economics, political economy and social philosophy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2016). Comparative historical political economy. Journal of Institutional Economics, 9(3), 285–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (1995). Why are there no Austrian socialists? Ideology, science and the Austrian school. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17(1), 35–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von. (1890). Zur Litteraturgeschichte der Staats- und Sozialwissenschaften. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, Bd. 54, 75–95.

  • Butler, E. (1988). Ludwig von Mises: Fountainhead of the modern microeconomics revolution. Brookfield: Gower.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohn, G. (1906). Epilog zur Generalversammlung des Vereins für Sozialpolitik in Mannheim, September 25–28, 1905. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Bd. 62, H, 2, 214–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2011). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of Western democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E. (2016). The Viennese students of civilization: The meaning and context of Austrian economics reconsidered. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dietzel, H. (1900). Individualismus. In J. Conrad et al. (Eds.), Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, 2nd ed., v.4, Jena, Germany, pp. 1328–1345.

  • Edwards, J. R. (1985). The economist of the country: Ludwig von Mises in the history of monetary thought. New York: Carlton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franko, I. (1902). Proceedings of the. Shevchenko Science Society, 50(6), 37–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorges, I. (2017). The history of the Verein für Socialpolitik: An unintended contribution to the pre-history of the Institutinalization of sociology. In Handbuch Geschichte der deutschsprachigen Soziologie. Wiesbaden: Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-07998-7.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Greaves, B., & McGee, R. (1993). Mises: An Annotated Bibliography. Irvington-on-Hudson: The Foundation for economic education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grimmer-Solem, E. (2003). The rise of historical economics and social reform in Germany, 1864–1894. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grünberg, Carl. (1894). Die Bauernbefreiung und die Auflösung des gutsherrlich-bäuerlichen Verhältnisses in Böhmen, Mähren und Schlesien.

  • Hagemann, H. (2001). The Verein für Sozialpolitik from its foundation (1872) until world war I. In M. Augello & M. Guidi (Eds.), The Spread of Political Economy and the Professionalization of Economists. Economic Societies in Europe, America and Japan in the Nineteenth Century (pp. 152–175). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The constitution of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hülsmann, J. G. (2007). Mises: The last knight of liberalism. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaser, K. (1904). Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung. Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reich, 28(1), 374–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (2001). Ludwig von Mises. Wilmington: ISI Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knapp, G. F. (1887). Die Bauernbefreiung und der Ursprung der Landarbeiter in den älteren Teilen Preussens. München: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knapp, G. F. (1891). Die Landarbeiter in Knechtschaft und Freiheit: Vier Vorträge. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kott, S. (1996). Gemeinschaft oder Solidarität? Unterschiedliche Modelle der französischen und deutschen Sozialpolitik am Ende des 19. Jahrhunderts. Geschichte und Gesellschaft, 22(3), 311–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasnozhon, L., & Bunyk, M. (2018). The role of the German historical School in the Development of Mises’s thought. The Review of Austrian Economics, 31(3), 343–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, J. (2015). Rationalism, pluralism, and freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ludwig, Theodore, 1904. Historische Vierteljahrschrift 7(1): 124–26. Online source: https://archive.org/details/historischevier01unkngoog/page/n6. Accessed 10 June 2019.

  • von Mises, L. (1902). Die Entwicklung des Gutsherrlich-Bäuerlichen Verhältnisses in Galizien, 1772-1848 (The Development of the Relationship between Lords of Manor and Peasants in Galicia, 1772–1848). In Series: Wiener Staatswissenschaftliche Studien. Wien und Leipzig: Franz Deuticke.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, Ludwig von. (1904). “Zur Frage der Altersversorgung der Arbeiter,” (Concerning Workers’ Old Age Pensions) Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung, 13: 463–465.

  • von Mises, L. (1905a). “Zur Geschichte der österreichischen Fabrikgesetzgebung,” (The History of Austrian Factory Legislation) Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft. Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung, 14, 209–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L von (1905b). A summary of “Der Weltwirtschaft auf die Ausgestaltung der Sozialpolitik,” (The World Economy and the Organization of Social Reform). Statistische Monatschrift 10: 948–950. Online source: http://anno.onb.ac.at/cgi-content/anno-plus?aid=stm&datum=1905&page=952&size=45. Accessed 10 June 2019.

  • von Mises, L.[1978] 2009. Notes and recollections. South Holland: Libertarian Press.

  • Nau, H. H. (2000). Gustav Schmoller’s Historico-ethical political economy: Ethics, politics, and economics in the younger German historical school, 1860-1917. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 7(4), 507–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oschina, S. (2010). Die Entwicklung des Vereins für Sozialpolitik von seiner Gründung bis 1980. Graz: Institut für Unternehmensrechnung und Controlling.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pallas, C. (2005). Ludwig von Mises als Pioneers der modernen Geld- und Konjunkturlerhe. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Philippovich, E. (1891). Verein für Sozialpolitik. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 5(20), 220–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pribram, K. (1983). A history of economic reasoning. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1988). Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, hero. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rozdolski, R. (1962). Stosunki poddancze w dawnej Galicji. Warszawa: Panstwowe Wydawn. Naukowe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmoller, G. (1875). Über einige Grundfragen des Rechts und der Volkswirtschaft. Ein offenes Sendschreiben an Herrn Professor Dr. Jena: Heinrich von Treitschke.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1954). History of economic analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sima, J., & Nikodym, T. (2015). Classical liberalism in the Czech Republic. Econ Journal Watch, 12(2), 274–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simons, T. (1971). The peasant revolt of 1846 in Galicia: Recent polish historiography. Slavic Review, 30(4), 795–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slobodian, Q. (2019). Perfect capitalism, imperfect humans: Race, migration, and the limits of Ludwig von Mises’s globalism. Contemporary European History, 28(2), 143–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Studnicki, Ladislaus. 1903. Zeitschrift für Socialwissenschaft 6: 673–76. Online source: https://archive.org/details/bub_gb_38kjAQAAIAAJ/page/n683. Accessed 10 June 2019.

  • Struve, K. (2008). Citizenship and National Identity: the Peasants of Galicia during the 19th Century. In P. Wawrzeniuk (Ed.), Societal Change and Ideological Formation Among the Rural Population of the Baltic Area 1880–1939 (pp. 75–93). Huddinge: Södertörn högskola.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teuteberg, Hans-Jürgen. (1977). “Die Doktrin des ökonomischen Liberalismus und ihre Gegner dargestellt an der prinzipiellen Erörterung des Arbeitsvertrages im “Verein für Sozialpolitik” (1872–1905)” in Wissenschaft und Kodifikation des Privatrechts im 19. Jahrhundert, Bd. 2, pp. 47–73, Frankfurt am Main.

  • Weber, M. [1892] 1984. Die Lage der Landarbeiter im ostelbischen Deutschland in Martin Riesebrodt, ed., Max Weber Gesamtausgabe, vol.3, Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

  • Wimbersky, H. (1906). Zeitschrift fur Volkswirtschaft. Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung., 15, 275.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Julio Cole, Daniel D’Amico, Michael Douma, Stephen Meardon, seminar participants at the Department of Economics and Finance at Troy University, and panel participants at the 2018 Southern Economic Association/Society for Development of Austrian Economics meeting, Washington, D.C., for helpful comments on earlier drafts. We thank Valentin Riebesell and Johannes Forstpointner for their outstanding research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Leonid Krasnozhon.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bunyk, M., Krasnozhon, L. Young Mr. Mises and younger historicists: origins of Mises’s liberalism. Rev Austrian Econ 35, 177–191 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-020-00499-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-020-00499-5

Keywords

JEL

Navigation