Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Disruptive innovation and R&D ownership structures

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides a theoretical explanation as to why breakthrough innovations seem to be possible only within capitalist economies (Kornai in Dynamism, rivalry, and the surplus economy: Two essays on the nature of capitalism, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2013). Specifically, our theory explains why disruptive innovations are discovered and financed by large numbers of independently owned small firms in capitalist economies rather than in socialist economies where state ownership is the only option. The key is that the ownership structure of the firm affects the ex-post selection of worthwhile discoveries, which determines the fate of disruptive innovation. Our paper also contributes to empirical work on disruptive innovation, which is missing in the literature. We use new molecular entities (NMEs) in the pharmaceutical industry as a proxy for disruptive innovation. Although pharmaceutical companies are often very large, their R&D projects greatly depend on forming alliances with much smaller independent firms. We find that the number of NMEs discovered by pharmaceutical companies is positively and significantly associated with the number of R&D alliances in which they participate. Our theory is supported by the empirical findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We adopt Kornai’s (1992) definition of socialism as an economy where state ownership dominates. Because the state is the sole owner and controls state firms, no clear boundary between the state and the firm exists in socialism. According to that definition, Western welfare states are not socialist.

  2. We are aware of the problems of the bureaucracy and deficiencies of the FDA, which affect the quality of the drugs approved by them. For example, Klein and Tabarrok (2002) report inefficiencies and delays caused by the FDA. Lasser et al. (2002) document other deficiencies of the FDA. The inefficiency and inaccuracy of the FDA is equivalent to introducing type I and type II errors into our variable and lower the accuracy of NMEs as a proxy of disruptive innovation in drug R&D. However, these problems do not substantially affect disruptive innovation of new drugs in the US (to be discussed in Sect. 4.1). We thank the editor and a referee for suggesting the related literature.

  3. Owing to their inability to invent NMEs, Russia and China rely heavily on the import of pharmaceuticals, and their domestically produced drugs typically are made from imported ingredients.

  4. The private benefit received by an entrepreneur at different project dates includes present and future material and nonmaterial gains, such as perks and reputation.

  5. In the very early stages, particularly with regard to basic research, high-tech R&D projects often are funded by the US government through the National Science Foundation (NSF), the National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA) and the National Institutes of Health (NIH). Regardless of the source of financing, selection mechanism, such as the one we study here, is a key factor determining R&D outcomes.

  6. The total number of patents granted to the class “Drug, bioaffecting, and body treating compositions” (i.e., CCL/424 or CCL/514) between 1 Jan 1998 and 31 Dec 2018 was 144,385 (https://www.uspto.gov/). That is, the average annual number of patents granted closely related to drug development during our study period was 6875. Some other CCLs, such as CCL/435 (Chemistry: molecular biology and microbiology) or CCL/436 (Chemistry: analytical and immunological testing), are not included because those categories sometimes cover things other than drug development. Hence, we understate the total number of drug development patents in general.

  7. https://www.fda.gov/drugs/new-drugs-fda-cders-new-molecular-entities-and-new-therapeutic-biological-products/new-drug-therapy-approvals-2019.

  8. All statistics are sorted based on the information from CapitalIQ, a financial database constructed by Standard and Poor’s.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., & Zilibotti, F. (2006). Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1), 37–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Akcigit, U., Alp, H., Bloom, N., & Kerr, W. (2018). Innovation, reallocation, and growth. American Economic Review, 108(11), 3450–3491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, W., Einav, L., & Levin, J. (2009). Liquidity constraints and imperfect information in subprime lending. American Economic Review, 99(1), 49–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1992). 1991 Nobel lecture: The institutional structure of production. American Economic Review, 82(4), 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, J. L., Morstorf, T., & Zhong, K. (2014). Alzheimer’s disease drug-development pipeline: few candidates, frequent failures. Alzheimer’s Research & Therapy, 6(4), 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M., & Maskin, E. (1995). Credit and efficiency in centralized and decentralized economies. The Review of Economic Studies, 62(4), 541–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esty, B. C., & Megginson, W. L. (2001). Syndicate structure as a response to political risk in the project finance loan market. Working Paper. Harvard Business School, Boston.

  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., & Lerner, J. (2010). The financing of R&D and innovation. In Handbook of the Economics of Innovation (Vol. 1, pp. 609-639). North-Holland.

  • Hart, O. D. (1995). Firms, contracts, and financial structure. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. D. (2017). Incomplete contracts and control. American Economic Review, 107(7), 1731–1752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. D., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, H., & Xu, C. (1998). Soft budget constraint and the optimal choices of research and development projects financing. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26(1), 62–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, H., & Xu, C. (1999). Institutions, innovations, and growth. American Economic Review, 89(2), 438–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kealey, T. (1996). The economic laws of scientific research. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kinch, M. S., Haynesworth, A., Kinch, S. L., & Hoyer, D. (2014). An overview of FDA-approved new molecular entities: 1827–2013. Drug Discovery Today, 19(8), 1033–1039.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, D. B., & Tabarrok, A. (2002), Is the FDA safe and effective. An extensive website sponsored by the Independent Institute (FDAreview. org).

  • Koppl, R. (2018). Expert failure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1979). Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 47(4), 801–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J., (1992). The socialist system: The political economy of communism. Oxford University Press.

  • Kornai, J. (1986). The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39(1), 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (2013). Dynamism, rivalry, and the surplus economy: Two essays on the nature of capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 1095–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lasser, K. E., Allen, P. D., Woolhandler, S. J., Himmelstein, D. U., Wolfe, S. M., & Bor, D. H. (2002). Timing of new black box warnings and withdrawals for prescription medications. Journal of the American Medical Association, 287(17), 2215–2220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lendrem, D. W., & Lendrem, B. C. (2013). Torching the haystack: modeling fast-fail strategies in drug development. Drug Discovery Today, 18(7–8), 331–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V. (1917[1993]). State and revolution. London: Penguin Books.

  • Maskin, E. (1992). Auction and privatization. in Siebert, H., eds. Privatization, pp. 115-136.

  • McMeekin, P., Lendrem, D. W., Lendrem, B. C., Pratt, A. G., Peck, R., Isaacs, J. D., et al. (2020). Schrödinger’s pipeline and the outsourcing of pharmaceutical innovation. Drug Discovery Today, 25(3), 480–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munos, B. (2009). Lessons from 60 years of pharmaceutical innovation. Nature Reviews Drug Discovery, 8(12), 959–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peck, R. W., Lendrem, D. W., Grant, I., Lendrem, B. C., & Isaacs, J. D. (2015). Why is it hard to terminate failing projects in pharmaceutical R&D? Nature Reviews Drug Discovery, 14(10), 663–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., & Xu, C. (1998). Innovation and bureaucracy under soft and hard budget constraints. The Review of Economic Studies, 65(1), 151–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridley, M. (2020). How innovation works: And why it flourishes in freedom. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1991). Changing perspectives on the firm size problem (pp. 24–38). Innovation and Technological Change: An International Comparison.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F. M. (1992). Schumpeter and plausible capitalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 30(3), 1416–1433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1950). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steijvers, T., & Voordeckers, W. (2009). Collateral and credit rationing: A review of recent empirical studies as a guide for future research. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(5), 924–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Prof. Eric Maskin for his generous help on an early version of the present paper; Prof. William Shughart II and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions; and Mr. Zhongming Shi and Ms. Cindy Tian for their skilled research assistance. Chenggang Xu acknowledges support from the CKGSB and the hospitality of Corvinus University of Budapest, Imperial College London, and LSE. The views and errors are those of the authors, and they do not necessarily reflect those of their affiliated institutions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chenggang Xu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 279 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guo, D., Huang, H., Jiang, K. et al. Disruptive innovation and R&D ownership structures. Public Choice 187, 143–163 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00850-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00850-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation