Skip to main content
Log in

Rediscovering Buchanan’s rediscovery: non-market exchange versus antiseptic allocation

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While Buchanan is best known for the economics of politics and constitutions, his seminal contributions to this field are but one branch of his more underlying methodology and approach to doing social science. Buchanan’s fundamental project was to re-orient economics and social science toward an analysis of symbiotic exchange (catallactics) rather than of antiseptic allocation (optimization). The most definite statement of this contribution lies in Buchanan’s 1963 presidential address to the Southern Economic Association, “What should economists do?” which was later expanded into a book of the same title. This paper seeks to draw attention to several of Buchanan’s more recent but lesser known articles where he fully develops this theme. He calls on economists to rediscover Adam Smith’s “elementary notion” about the division of labor and the extent of the market, and he professes the notion of “generalized increasing returns” as a mechanism for economists to rediscover their Scottish Enlightenment roots within the neoclassical framework. In this same vein, we also discuss how Buchanan’s rediscovery might apply to two prominent and ongoing twenty-first century issues, trade restrictions and populism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source (video): “Daring to Be Different: Reflections on the Life and Work of James Buchanan”, GMU Archives.

  2. Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences press release, October 16, 1986, at www.nobelprize.org.

  3. Buchanan repeats a similar response in other places. For example, a few years earlier, in his 1979 essay “Politics without Romance”, he called public choice a “new… sub-discipline that falls halfway between economics and political science…. Public choice theory essentially takes the tools and analysis that have been developed to quite sophisticated analytical levels in economic theory and applies these tools and methods to the political or government sector, to politics, to the public economy” (Buchanan 1996[1999], pp.46–48).

  4. Note that even if Boettke, Fink and Smith locate John Hicks in the mainstream groups, Hicks himself seems to have changed his position later in life: “In my sub-title, and in the text of Chapter I, I have proclaimed the ‘Austrian’ affiliation of my ideas; the tribute to Böhm-Bawerk, and to his followers, is a tribute that I am proud to make. I am writing in their tradition; yet I have realized, as my work continued, that it is a wider and bigger tradition than at first appeared. The ‘Austrians’ were not a peculiar sect, out of the main stream; they [?] were in the main stream; it was the others who were out of it” (Hicks 1973, p. 12, n. 1).

  5. For excellent papers that trace Buchanan’s methodology to his SEA presidential speech, see Shughart and Thomas (2014), Wagner (2017) and Boettke and Candela (2017). For details concerning the reception and diffusion of Robbins’s definition of economics during the twentieth century, see Backhouse and Medema (2009).

  6. Buchanan does not claim that economists entirely abandoned Smithean questions. In each of the works discussed here (Buchanan 1964, Buchanan and Yoon 1994, 1999, 2000), we find pointers to isolated works along the way that failed to influence the practitioners of economics and instead became mere fixtures in the history of thought. For excellent work tracing the lineage of Buchanan’s thought from pre-Enlightenment philosophers through his twentieth century adversaries, see Leighton and Lopez (2013), Shughart and Thomas (2014), and Boettke and Candela (2017).

  7. Kirzner (1965, p. 257) replies by arguing that Buchanan’s concern has been raised for years by a “group of writers” and that, while agreeing with Buchanan, computational problems still are part of the economic problem (even if not the main subject of study).

  8. Buchanan also was a radical subjectivist, a point about which he writes plainly but incisively in, for example, Buchanan (1963[1999]) and Buchanan and Vanberg (2002).

  9. See Pennington’s (2011) discussion of robust political economy.

  10. For applications of public choice to civil and criminal law, see Lopez (2010) and Stearns and Zywicki (2019). For coverage of the other broad areas mentioned, and more, see the Encyclopedia of Public Choice (Rowley and Schneider 2003).

  11. For a review of the implications of the mathematization of economics, see Cachanosky (1985, 1986). Also see Boettke (1997).

  12. Salient examples of the political economy of trade being absorbed into the mainstream include Magee et al. (1989), Grossman and Helpman (1994), Rodrik (1995) and Baldwin and Magee (2000).

  13. This is, for instance, the approach taken by García Hamilton (1998) with respect to Latin America’s propemsity for authoritarian governments and low levels of productivity.

  14. On populism see Cachanosky and Padilla (2020), Chesterley and Roberti (2016), de la Torre (2016), Dornbusch and Edwards (1990), Hawkins (2003), Riker (1988) and Weyland (2003).

References

  • Abts, K., & Rummens, S. (2007). Populism versus democracy. Political Studies,55(2), 405–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity and poverty. New York: Crown Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhouse, R. E., & Medema, S. G. (2009). Defining economics: The long road to acceptance of the Robbins definition. Economica,76, 805–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Magee, C. S. (2000). Is trade for sale? Congressional voting on recent trade bills. Public Choice,105, 79–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principal agents? The political economy of good government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boaz, D. (2013). James M. Buchanan, RIP. https://www.cato.org/blog/james-m-buchanan-rip. Retrieved 10 July 2019.

  • Boettke, P. J. (1997). Where did economics go wrong? Modern economics as a flight from reality. Critical Review,11(1), 11–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Candela, R. (2017). The liberty of progress: Increasing returns, institutions, and entrepreneurship. Social Philosophy and Policy,34(2), 136–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Fink, A., & Smith, D. J. (2012). The impact of Nobel Prize winners in economics: Mainline vs. mainstream. American Journal of Economics and Sociology,71(5), 1219–1249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Newman, P. (2016). The History of a Tradition: Austrian Economics from 1871 to 2016. Research in the History ofEconomic Thought and Methodology, 34A, 199–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Lopez, E. J. (2002). Austrian and public choice economics: On common ground. The Review of Austrian Economics,15(2/3), 111–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. The Journal of Political Economy,57(6), 496–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1963[1999]). The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 6. Cost and Choice (Vol. 6). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1964). What should economists do? Southern Economic Journal,30(3), 213–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975 [2000]). The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 7. The limits of liberty. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1996 [1999]). Politics without romance: A sketch of positive public choice theory and its normative implications. In J. M. Buchanan & R. D. Tollison (Eds.), The theory of Public Choice II. The University of Michigan Press.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Brennan, G. (1980 [2000]). The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 9. The power to tax. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Brennan, G. (1985 [2000]). The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 10. The reason of rules. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (2006). Politics by principle, not by interest. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962 [1999]). The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 3. The calculus of consent. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Vanberg, V. J. (2002). Constitutional implications of radical subjectivism. The Review of Austrian Economics, 15, 121–129. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1015754302238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Wagner, R. E. (1977 [2000]). The collected works of James M. Buchanan. Volume 8. Democracy in Deficit. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yoon, Y. J. (1994). The return of increasing returns. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yoon, Y. J. (1999). Generalized increasing returns, Euler’s theorem, and competitive equilibrium. History of Political Economy,31(3), 511–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yoon, Y. J. (2000). A smithean perpective on increasing returns. Journal of the History of Economic Thought,22(1), 43–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachanosky, J. C. (1985). La ciencia económica vs. la economía matemática (I). Libertas,3(octubre), 1–3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachanosky, J. C. (1986). La ciencia económica vs. la economía matemática (II). Libertas, mayo.

  • Cachanosky, N., & Padilla, A. (2019). Latin american populism in the 21st century. The Independent Review,24(2), 209–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachanosky, N., & Padilla, A. (2020). A panel data analysis of Latin American populism. Constitutional Political Economy. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-020-09302-w.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesterley, N., & Roberti, P. (2016). Populism and institutional capture. Working Paper DSE No. 1086. Bologna: University di Bologna.

  • Cowen, T. (2013). A few James Buchanan reminiscences. Retrieved from https://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2013/01/a-few-james-buchanan-reminiscences.html.

  • de la Torre, C. (2016). Populism and the politics of the extraordinary in Latin America. Journal of Political Ideologies,21(2), 121–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doherty, B. (2013). Nobel Prize winning economist James Buchanan, R.I.P. https://reason.com/2013/01/09/nobel-prize-winning-economist-james-buch/. Retrieved 10 July 2019.

  • Dornbusch, R., & Edwards, S. (1990). Macroeconomic populism. Journal of Development Economics,32(2), 247–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. (2010). Left behind: Latin America and the false promise of populism. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eusepi, G., & Wagner, R. E. (2017). Public debt: An illusion of democratic political economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gallo, E. L. (1987). La tradición del orden social espontáneo: Adam Ferguson. David Hume y Adam Smith. Libertas,6(mayo), 131–153.

    Google Scholar 

  • García Hamilton, J. I. (1998). El autoritarismo y la improductividad en hispanoamérica. Sudamericana.

  • Grier, K., & Maynard, N. (2016). The economic consequences of Hugo Chavez: A synthetic control analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,125, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. (2013). Nobel economist James M. Buchanan, 19192013. Retrieved from https://ricochet.com/177970/archives/nobel-economist-james-m-buchanan-1919-2013/.

  • Grossman, M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. The American Economic Review,84(4), 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, L., Herrera, H., Morelli, M., & Sonno, T. (2017). Demand and supply of populism. EIEF working paper no. 17/03. Roma: Einaudo Institute for Economics and Finance.

  • Hawkins, K. A. (2003). Populism in Venezuela: The rise of Chavismo. Third World Quarterly,24(6), 1137–1160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967 [1978]). Studies in philosophy, politics and economics. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

  • Hicks, J. R. (1973). Capital and time. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgs, R. (2013). James M. Buchanan (October 3, 1919January 9, 2013). https://blog.independent.org/2013/01/09/james-m-buchanan-october-3-1919-january-9-2013/. Retrieved 10 July 2019.

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2013). James M. Buchanan: 19192013. https://blog.independent.org/2013/01/09/james-m-buchanan-1919-2013/. Retrieved 10 July 2019.

  • Horwitz, S. G. (2013). RIP: James M. Buchanan (19192013). http://bleedingheartlibertarians.com/2013/01/rip-james-m-buchanan-1919-2013/. Retrieved 10 July 2019

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1965). What economists do. Southern Economic Journal,31(3), 257–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohn, M. (2004). Value and exchange. Cato Journal,24(3), 303–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. S. (1962 [1996]). The structure of scientific revolutions. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press.

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics,50(2), 303–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2014). Anarchy unbound: Why self-governance works better than you think. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Leighton, W. A., & Lopez, E. J. (2013). Madmen, intellectuals, and academic scribblers: The economic engine of political change. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lekachman, R. (1986). A controversial Nobel choice?; Turning into these conservative times. The New York Times1. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/1986/10/26/business/business-forum-controversial-nobel-choice-turning-these-conservative-times.html.

  • Lopez, E. J. (2010). The pursuit of justice: Law and economics of legal institutions. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, C. S., Brock, W., & Young, L. (1989). Black hole tariffs and endogenous policy theory: Political economy in general equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, A. (2020). The subjectivist-contrarian position. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00808-3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, D. (2013). RIP James Buchanan: The man who got economists to care about politics. The Washington Post Wonk Blog. Retrieved from https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2013/01/09/rip-james-buchanan-the-man-who-got-economists-to-care-about-politics/?arc404=true.

  • Mazzuca, S. L. (2013). The rise of rentier populism. Journal of Democracy,24(2), 108–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D. (1979). A note on the computability of tests of the strong axiom of revealed preference. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 6(1), 15–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4068(79)90020-X.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambrdige University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ocampo, E. (2015). Entrampados en la farsa: El populismo y la decadencia argentina. Buenos Airers: Claridad.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (2000). Power and prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. L. (2002). Explaining the persistent growth in tax complexity. In D. P. Racheter & R. E. Wagner (Eds.), Politics, taxation, and the rule of law (pp. 167–184). Boston, MA: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pennington, M. (2011). Robust political economy: Classical liberalism and the future of public policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesendorfer, W. (1995). Design innovation and fashion cycles. American Economic Review,85, 771–792.

    Google Scholar 

  • Podemska-Mikluch, M., & Wagner, R. E. (2013). Dyads, triads, and the theory of exchange: Between liberty and coercion. The Review of Austrian Economics,26(2), 171–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reksulak, M., Shughart, W. F., II, & Tollison, R. D. (2004). Economics and english: Language growth in economic perspective. Southern Economic Journal,71(2), 232–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1988). Liberalism against populism: A confrontation between the theory of democracy and the theory of social choice. Long Grove: Waveland Pr Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzo, M. J. (2013). James M. Buchanan: A preliminary appreciation. https://thinkmarkets.wordpress.com/2013/01/09/james-m-buchanan-a-preliminary-appreciation/. Retrieved 10 July 2019.

  • Rode, M., & Revuelta, J. (2015). The wild bunch! An empirical note on populism and economic institutions. Economics of Governance,16(1), 73–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1995). Political economy of trade policy. Handbook of international economics,3, 1457–1494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2018). Is populism necessarily bad economics? AEA Papers and Proceedings,108, 196–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowan, H. (1986). Discreetly Lifted Eyebrows over Buchanan’s Nobel. The Washington Post1.

  • Rowley, C. K., & Schneider, F. (Eds.). (2003). The encyclopedia of public choice. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seaberry, J. (1986). Nobel winner sees economics as common sense; Buchanan says his public choice helps explain political actions. The Washington Post.

  • Shughart, W. F., II, & Thomas, D. W. (2014). What did economists do? Evolutionary, voluntary, and coercive institutions for collective action. Southern Economic Jounal,80(4), 926–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (2002). Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. In Nobel memorial lecture.

  • Stearns, M., & Zywicki, T. (2019). Public choice concepts and applications in law. Eagan: West Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. D. (2013). James M. Buchanan: In memoriam. Southern Economic Journal,80(1), 1–4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry,5(3), 224–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg, G. (2017). Consitutional political economy, democratic theory, and institutional design. Public Choice,177, 199–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1933). Epistemological problems of economics. Auburn: The Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2017). James M. Buchanan and liberal political economy: A rational reconstruction. Lanham, MD: Lexington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weyland, K. (2001). Clarifying a contested concept: Populism in the study of Latin American politics. Comparative Politics,34(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weyland, K. (2003). Latin American neopopulism. Third World Quarterly,24(6), 1095–1115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicolás Cachanosky.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cachanosky, N., Lopez, E.J. Rediscovering Buchanan’s rediscovery: non-market exchange versus antiseptic allocation. Public Choice 183, 461–477 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00819-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00819-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation