Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical?

  • RESEARCH ARTICLE
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

By putting together a relatively large data set on bilateral remittances of emigrants, this paper is able to shed light on the important hypothesis of smoothing. The smoothing hypothesis is that remittances are countercyclical with respect to income in the worker’s country of origin (the recipient of the remittance), while procyclical with respect to income in the migrant’s host country (the sender of the remittance). The econometric results confirm the hypothesis. This affirmation of smoothing is important for two reasons. First, it suggests that remittances should be placed on the list of criteria for an optimum currency area. Second, it brings into doubt plans by governments in some developing countries to harness remittances for their own use, in that government spending in these countries generally fails the test of countercyclicality which remittances pass.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Among trade economists, the subject goes back at least to Bhagwati and Hamada (1974).

  2. Rapoport and Docquier (2006) review the theory that has been developed as part of the New Economics of Labor Migration. Recent contributions include Özden and Schiff (2006) and Kugler and Rapoport (2007).

  3. Statistics cited here come from “Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration” in Global Economic Prospects 2006, World Bank, pp. 86–92.

  4. Sanket Mohapatra and Dilip Ratha, “Impact of the Global Financial Crisis on Migration and Remittances,” Economic Premise, World Bank Feb. 2010, 2.

  5. Prasad et al. (2003), Prasad et al. (2004), Prasad and Rajan (2008).

  6. Kaminsky et al. (2005), Reinhart and Reinhart (2009), Perry (2009), Gavin et al. (1996), and Mendoza and Terrones(2008).

  7. Lucas (1990), Alfaro et al. (2005), Gourinchas and Jeanne (2007), Prasad et al. (2007), Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2009).

  8. E.g., Lane and Tornell (1998).

  9. Chami et al. (2005).

  10. Chami et al. (2008a) see macroeconomic advantages of remittances of the sort considered here. Martin (1990), on the other hand, points out that a steady flow of remittances can undermine the incentive for governments to create a sound institutional framework—a sort of natural resource curse for remittances.

  11. Talvi and Végh (2005), Gavin and Perotti (1997), Alesina et al. (2008).

  12. Jiménez-Martin et al. (2007) estimate bilateral workers’ remittance flows from the 27 members of the EU, to all recipient countries. Ratha and Shaw (2005), in the absence of hard data on bilateral flows, allocate the totals across partners.

  13. Roughly 10% come from developing countries. South Africa, for example, receives many immigrants from neighboring countries to work in its mines, farms, and factories, and sends remittances back to the home countries. In many Gulf countries, immigrants (called ex-patriate workers) constitute more than half of the private-sector labor force, both skilled and unskilled. For example, outward remittances from Saudi Arabia (not included in the developing country statistic) are about 7% of all remittances globally.

  14. There were problems in the Gulf countries in 2006–2008, for example.

  15. Singer (2008) makes the argument that remittances should be and are a determinant of the currency decision. His equation uses the level of remittances, but he cites earlier authors’ evidence of countercyclicality.

  16. Mundell (1961).

  17. There are also examples of inflows of remittances from emigrants apparently sustaining violent conflict—Northern Ireland, Eritrea/Ethiopia, Israel/Palestine—which again resemble effects of mineral wealth.

  18. World Bank (2006, Tables 4A.2.1 and 4A.2.3).

  19. Sayan (2006).

  20. Clarke and Wallstein (2004) and Yang (2007) find that remittance receipts go up in response to a natural disaster. Kapur (2005) finds that they go up in response to an economic downturn. Yang and Choi (2007) find that they respond to rainfall-induced economic fluctuations.

  21. Ghosh (2006) and Jiménez-Martin et al. (2007, p. 8, 14).

  22. The working paper version of this paper estimated regression equations for remittances that are received by four of the smaller countries of southern Africa. In this case it is a safe bet that the majority of emigrants reside in South Africa, and so we can use South African income as foreign income. The results suggested countercyclicality for most of these countries, especially when the coefficients on domestic and foreign (i.e., South African) income are constrained to be equal in magnitude and of opposite signs.

  23. In a study of remittances into Jamaica, Lake (2006) finds that they do respond to the difference between US and Jamaican income. She also argues against Jamaican government taxes or regulation on remittances.

  24. The other variables in their equation are per capita income in both countries, a measure of the transaction cost, and the exchange rate spread, and a dummy variable for dual exchange rates. Faini (2006) argues that the skill level of the migrant has a negative effect on remittances.

  25. The data point representing remittances from Portugal to Moldova looks like an outlier. But investigation reveals that this is a real phenomenon, not a data error or artifact.

  26. One might ask, if the cyclical behavior of migration flows is of equal interest to the cyclical behavior of remittances per migrant, why not also the stock of migrants? Two answers. First, in most cases the stock of migrants has been determined over a long history (by geographic, political, cultural and other factors), during which cyclical considerations are not relevant; we should get a better-specified equation and better estimates when controlling for it. It is only over a horizon of a few years that the cyclical question arises. Second, it is important to control for some sort of scale variable. It would not do to treat the absolute dollar level of US-Mexico remittances on a par with the absolute dollar level of Luxembourg-Lesotho remittances.

  27. Japan, for example, was essentially in recession throughout the 1990s; 10 years of stagnation continued to reduce the stock of immigrants.

  28. The countercyclicality does not show well, however, if the income measure is used in the panel data set or if the unemployment measure is used in the pure cross-section. I am indebted to Maurice Kugler for suggesting one possible explanation of this puzzle: the relative variation of detrended unemployment across countries may be limited, and the same with the variation over time of detrended income.

  29. Jiménez-Martin et al. (2007). Inspection of country pairs that appear in more than one data set show that the Lueth-Ruiz numbers are much higher, presumably because of a more expansive definition of remittances. In this light, an important next step would be to allow each remittance data set have its own intercept term (in logs).

  30. Singer (2008) finds that remittances as a share of GDP are a statistically significant predictor of the probability that a country will choose a fixed over a floating exchange rate.

  31. Chami et al. (2008b).

  32. Transactions costs for sending remittances have in the past been surprisingly high, due to lack of competition in such services. Ratha and Riedberg (2005).

References

  • Acosta P, Lartey E, Mandelman F (2009) Remittances and the Dutch Disease, FRB of Atlanta Working Paper No. 2007-8a, August

  • Alesina A, Campante F, Tabellini G (2008) Why is fiscal policy often procyclical? J Eur Econ Assoc 6(5):1006–1036

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfaro L, Kalemli-Ozcan S, Volosovych V (2005) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? An empirical investigation NBER WP No. 11901, Dec

  • Amuendo-Dorantes C, Pozo S (2004) Workers remittances and the real exchange rate: a paradox of gifts. World Dev 32(8):1407–1417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati J, Hamada K (1974) The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment : a theoretical analysis. J Dev Econ April, 19–42

  • Chami R, Fullenkamp C, Jahjah S (2005) Are immigrant remittance flows a source of capital for development? World Dev 27:1493–1502

    Google Scholar 

  • Chami R, Barajas A, Cosimano T, Fullenkamp C, Gapen M, Montiel P (2008a) Macroeconomic consequences of remittances, Occasional Paper No. 259 (International Monetary Fund)

  • Chami R, Fullenkamp C, Gapen M (2008b) Measuring workers’ remittances: what should be kept in and what should be left out? International Monetary Fund, March

  • Clarke G, Wallstein S (2004) Do remittances protect households in developing countries against shocks? Evidence from a natural disaster in Jamaica? World Bank

  • Faini R (2006) Remittances and the brain drain. CEPR discussion paper no. 5720, June

  • Freund CL, Spatafora N (2005) Remittances: costs, determinants, and informality. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3704, Washington, DC

  • Gavin M, Hausmann R, Perotti R, Talvi E (1996) Managing fiscal policy in Latin America and the Caribbean: volatility, procyclicality, and limited creditworthiness. Inter-American Development Bank, RES Working Papers 4032

  • Gavin M, Perotti R (1997) Fiscal policy in latin America. In: Bernanke BS, Rotemberg J (eds) NBER Macro Annual 1997. MIT Press, pp 11–72

  • Ghosh B (2006) Migrants’ remittances and development: myths rhetoric and realities. International Organization for Migration

  • Gourinchas P-O, Jeanne O (2007) Capital flows to developing countries: the allocation puzzle. IMF Working Paper, forthcoming

  • Jiménez-Martin S, Jorgensen N, Labeaga JM (2007) The volume and geography of remittances from the EU, European Commission

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Reshef A, Sorensen B, Yosha O (2009) Why does capital flow to rich states? NBER Working Paper No. 11301, May 2005, Revised February 2009

  • Kaminsky G, Reinhart C, Vegh C (2005) When it rains, it pours: procyclical capital flows and macroeconomic policies. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004 19:11–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapur D (2005) Remittances: the new development mantra? In: Maimbo SM, Ratha D (eds) Remittances: development impact and future prospects. World Bank, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler M, Rapoport H (2007) International labor and capital flows: complements or substitutes? Econ Lett 94(2):155–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake L (2006) Remittances and the Jamaican economy: from fundamentals to effective policy recommendations. MPA/ID Second Year Policy Analysis, Harvard Kennedy School

  • Lane P, Tornell A (1998) Voracity and growth in discrete time. Econ Lett 62(1):139–145

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1990) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am Econ Rev 80:92–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Lueth E, Ruiz-Arranz M (2006) A gravity model of workers’ remittances, International Monetary Fund Working Paper

  • Lueth E, Ruiz-Arranz M (2008) Determinants of bilateral remittance flows, the B.E. J Macroecon, October

  • Martin P (1990) Labor migration and economic development, Report of the Commission for the Study of International Migration and Cooperative Economic Development, Washington DC

  • Mendoza E, Terrones M (2008) An anatomy of credit booms: evidence from macro aggregates and micro data, NBER Working Paper No. 14049, May 2008

  • Mundell R (1961) Optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 51:509–517

    Google Scholar 

  • Özden C, Schiff M (eds) (2006) International migration, remittances and the brain drain. World Bank and Palgrave MacMillan

  • Perry G (2009) Beyond lending: how multilateral banks can help developing countries manage volatility. Center for Global Development, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad E, Rajan R (2008) A pragmatic approach to capital account liberalization. J Econ Perspect, Summer 2008 (NBER Working Paper No.14051)

  • Prasad E, Rogoff K, Wei S-J, Kose M (2003). Effects of financial globalization on developing countries: some empirical evidence. Occasional Paper No. 220, Research Department, International Monetary Fund. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10942 (2004), forthcoming in Ann Harrison (ed) Globalization and poverty, University of Chicago Press

  • Prasad E, Rogoff KS, Wei S-J, Kose MA (2004) Financial globalization, growth and volatility in developing countries, NBER Working Papers 10942

  • Prasad E, Rajan R, Subramanaian A (2007) The paradox of capital, finance and development, IMF, March 2007, 44, no. 1

  • Rajan R, Subramanian A (2005) What undermines aid’s impact on growth? NBER Working Paper No. 11657, September

  • Rapoport H, Docquier F (2006) The economics of migrants’ remittances, Chapter 17. In: Mercier-Ytheier J, Kolm SC (eds) Handbook on the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity. Elsevier, North Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Ratha D, Riedberg J (2005) On reducing remittance costs, Development Research Group, World Bank

  • Ratha D, Shaw W (2005) South-South migration and remittances, World Bank

  • Reinhart C, Reinhart V (2009) Capital flow bonanzas: an encompassing view of the past and present. In: Frankel J, Pissarides C (eds) NBER International Seminar in Macroeconomics 2008, University of Chicago Press

  • Rose A (2000) One money, one market: estimating the effect of common currencies on trade. Econ Policy

  • Sayan S (2006) Business cycles and workers’ remittances: how do migrant workers respond to cyclical movements of GDP at home? IMF WP/06/52, February

  • Schiopu I, Siegfried N (2006) Determinants of workers’ remittances: evidence from the european neighboring regions, ECB Working Paper No. 688

  • Singer D (2008) Migrant remittances and exchange rate regimes in the developing world, Political Science Department, MIT, July. Forthcoming, Am Polit Sci Rev 104, no. 2

  • Talvi ET, Végh CA (2005) Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy in developing countries. J Dev Econ 78(1):156–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2006) Economic implications of remittances and migration, in Global Economic Prospects 2006, World Bank, pp 86–92

  • Yang D (2007) Coping with disaster: the impact of hurricans on international financial flows, 1970–2002, Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan

  • Yang D, Choi H (2007) Are remittances insurance? Evidence from ranifall shocks in the Phillippines. World Bank Econ Rev 21(2):219–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author wishes to thank Olga Romero for dedicated research assistance; Erik Lueth and Marta Ruiz-Arranz for generously making data available; Maurice Kugler, Hillel Rapoport and conference participants for comments; and Robert Hildreth, Harvard’s Center for International Development, and the MacArthur Foundation for support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeffrey Frankel.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Frankel, J. Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical?. Open Econ Rev 22, 1–16 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9184-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9184-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation