Skip to main content
Log in

Platform break-even market share

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study characterizes break-even market share within the context of two-sided platform markets. It combines chicken-and-egg pricing with previously unexplored network-based measures of total addressable market and serviceable available market. In addition, it accounts for the density of transactions across a platform’s network. A network-based driver of market share is how the number of users on each side translates into the platform’s addressable market. A two-sided market-based driver is how fixed costs are spread over the total value of the indirect externality created on the platform’s subsidized side. For marketing managers, these and other facets matter for identifying how large a network-based platform need be to capture significant market value, which is a necessary datum for attracting internal or external financing; calculating break-even volume and market share for potential entrants; and forecasting whether the market is winner-take-all based on transaction density.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A user’s reservation utility is normalized to zero.

  2. If either side can initiate a transaction, this instead becomes \(\min\left\{N_i\cdot{log}_{b_i}\left(N_j\right),N_j\cdot{log}_{b_j}\left(N_i\right)\right\}\)  

  3. For serviceable available market proportional to \(N_i\cdot{log}_b\left(N_j\right)\), the total derivative is \({log}_b\left(N_j\right)+N_i\cdot\frac1{N_j\cdot ln\left(b\right)}>0\) for \(b>1.\)

References

  • Arce, D. G. (2020). Cybersecurity and platform competition in the cloud. Computers & Security, 93, 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belleflamme, P., & Peitz, M. (2019). Managing competition on a two-sided platform. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 28, 5–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briscoe, B., Odlyzko, A., & Tilly, B. (2006). Metcalfe’s law is wrong. IEEE Spectrum, 43(7), 34–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud, B., & Jullien, B. (2003). Chicken & egg: Competition among intermediation service providers. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(2), 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cennamo, C. (2021). Competing in digital markets: A platform-based perspective. Academy of Management Perspectives, 35(2), 265–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cusumano, Michael A., Annabelle Gawer, and David B. Yoffie 2019. The business of platforms. Strategy in the age of digital competition, innovation, and power. New York: HarperCollins.

  • Evans, David S. and Richard Schmalensee 2016. Matchmakers. The new economics of multisided platforms. Boston: Harvard Business Review Press.

  • Gawer, A. (2014). Bridging differing perspectives on technological platforms: Toward an integrative framework. Research Policy, 43(7), 1239–1249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilder, George 2000. Telecosm. How infinite bandwidth will revolutionize our world. New York: The Free Press.

  • Gretz, R. T., & Basuroy, S. (2013). Why quality may not always win: The impact of product generation life cycles on network effects in high-tech markets. Journal of Retailing, 89(3), 281–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knee, J. A. (2021). The platform delusion. Portfolio.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R. S. (2014). Competing platforms. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 23(3), 507–526.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Y., & O’Connor, G. C. (2003). New product launch strategy for network effects products. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 31(3), 241–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Gangmin 2008. Economic sense of Metcalfe’s law. Proceedings of the first international workshop on understanding web evolution. Beijing: Web Science Research Initiative, pp.55–59.

  • Metcalfe, R. M. (1995). Metcalfe’s law: A network becomes more valuable as it reaches more users. InfoWorld, 40(17), 53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Øverby, H., & Audestad, J. A. (2018). Introduction to digital economics (2nd ed.). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G. G., & Van Alstyne, M. W. (2005). Two-sided network effects: A theory of information product design. Management Science, 51(10), 1494–1504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reibstein, D. J. (2009). A broader perspective of network effects. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(2), 154–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reillier, L. C., & Reillier, B. (2017). Platform strategy. Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990–1029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2006). Two-sided markets: A tentative survey. RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 645–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rysman, M. (2009). The economics of two-sided markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(3), 125–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Cartas, J. M., & León, G. (2021). Multisided platforms and markets: A survey of the theoretical literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 35(2), 452–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sriram, S., Manchanda, P., Esteban Bravo, M., Chu, J., Ma, L., Song, M., Shriver, S., & Subramanian, U. (2015). Platforms: A multiplicity of research opportunities. Marketing Letters, 26, 141–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tellis, G. T., Yin, E., & Niraj, R. (2009). Does quality win? Network effects versus quality in high-tech markets. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(2), 135–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weyl, E. G. (2010). A price theory of multi-sided platforms. American Economic Review, 100(4), 1642–1672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I have benefitted from helpful comments from an editor, Russ Winer, and three anonymous reviewers. Fruitful conversations with Sanjay Jain, Ernan Haruvy, and Betsy Arce were also of great assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Arce.

Ethics declarations

Ethical approval

Manuscript has is not under consideration at another journal; no part of the submitted work has been published elsewhere in any form or language; this is the study in its entirety; all theories presented are either the author’s or are attributed to others via citation.

Informed consent

Not applicable.

Conflict of interest

The author declares no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Arce, D. Platform break-even market share. Mark Lett 34, 713–725 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-023-09674-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-023-09674-7

Keywords

Navigation