Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Coordinating investments in habitat management and economic development

  • Published:
Journal of Bioeconomics

Abstract

Development generates environmental externalities when it degrades or destroys habitat and damages ecosystems services. In practice, governments and industry control these externalities by restricting development and/or practicing environmental management. This paper uses bioeconomic theory to examine strategies that optimally balance economic production and habitat management. Our results suggest that while habitat management may be an ecological substitute for less economic development, the efficient coordinated conservation scheme in the social planner’s problem treats them as economic complements over the course of a recovery program, such as for imperiled species. However, resource managers should substitute toward habitat management if they cannot efficiently coordinate habitat management and economic development. We illustrate our results with an application to the lesser prairie chicken, an imperiled bird species in the U.S. Great Plains.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Code availability

All source code can be retrieved from the Open Science Framework (osf.io/3ysh4).

Notes

  1. As pointed out by a reviewer, alternatively one could write \(g\left( \cdot \right)x\left( t \right) = G\left( \cdot \right)\), where \(G\left( \cdot \right)\) is quadratic in \(x\left( t \right)\). Doing so will change the general expressions of the model, but plugging in functional forms yields the same results (Supplemental Material D). This observation is supported by Conrad and Clark (1987) and Conrad (1999), who use a variety of notations depending on the problem and the intuition that can be obtained by adopting one or the other. We find that using the form \(g\left( \cdot \right)x\left( t \right)\) allows us to better simplify our results into economically meaningful groups.

  2. This is often done in the United States through federal assistance programs run by the Natural Resources Conservation Service. For example, in the case of the lesser prairie chicken there is a five-state range-wide plan that offers voluntary conservation incentives (Van Pelt et al., 2013).

  3. These dynamics imply the population is evenly distributed over the landscape. This assumption keeps the model tractable, but it precludes insights into how the spatial density of reserves and development may be altered to conserve wildlife (Sanchirico & Wilen, 1999). In practice, an agency may want to take advantage of habitat heterogeneity in regulating development (Polasky et al., 2005).

  4. The latter could correspond to the case in which a private owner possesses property rights to species habitat, which is not protected under the ESA. In this case, the private property owner would seek to choose the level of economic investment to maximize (4) subject to (2). The solution to this problem is presented in Supplemental Material B.

  5. From the necessary first order condition in (17), it would seem that the levels of economic investment in (20) could depend on the shadow value of economic capital (sensu Horan & Wolf (2005)). However, following Conrad and Clark (1987) and Clark (2010), the control variable must be able to efficiently regulate the state variable in order to be optimal. That is, the control should be able to regulate the state variable to its equilibrium and then hold it at that equilibrium via the singular solution. It can be shown that this is not the case when (20) is regulated by the shadow value of economic infrastructure. See Supplemental Material B for details.

  6. The maximum amount of capital investment is bounded by the capacity of the developer and its suppliers, though it is not obvious what this limit should be. We therefore follow the approach of Conrad and Clark (1987) and allow for an arbitrary large \(I_{{MAX}}\) such that the developer can effectively adjust the stock of economic infrastructure.

  7. It is worth recalling that in the uncoordinated conservation program the level of economic infrastructure is taken as given or exogenous. In the absence of habitat management there exists a threshold in the level of economic infrastructure, \(\bar{K} = {L \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {L {s_{2} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {s_{2} }}\), over which the species population will decline and die out. In this case habitat management is required for the species to persist. If \(\bar{K} < {L \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {L {s_{2} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {s_{2} }}\), as is the case for the developer’s optimum (Supplemental Material B), then economic infrastructure scales the species’ carrying capacity and habitat management is chosen solely to maximize the net present-value benefits of the species.

  8. While it is possible that a corner solution would be optimal, we assume that the extra biomass of prairie chickens associated with an interior solution makes the interior equilibrium preferable.

  9. This behavior is consistent with nonlinear feedback rules characteristic of multiple control systems and the switching between multiple singular arcs, depending on initial conditions (Bryson & Ho, 1975; Conrad & Clark, 1987; Horan & Wolf, 2005).

References

  • Bair, L. S., Yackulic, C. B., Springborn, M. R., Reimer, M. N., Bond, C. A., & Coggins, L. G. (2018). Identifying cost-effective invasive species control to enhance endangered species populations in the Grand Canyon, USA. Biological Conservation, 220, 12–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbier, E. B. (2007). Valuing ecosystem services as productive inputs. Economic Policy, 22(49), 179–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertram, C., & Quaas, M. F. (2016). Biodiversity and optimal multi-species ecosystem management. Environmental Resource Economics, 67, 321–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryson, A. E., & Ho, Y. (1975). Applied optimal control: Optimization, estimation, and control. Hemisphere Publishing Corporation.

  • Casazza, M. L., Overton, C. T., Bui, T. D., Hull, J. M., Albertson, J. D., Bloom, V. K., Bobzien, S., McBroom, J., Latta, M., Olofson, P., Rohmer, T. M., Schwarzbach, S., Strong, D. R., Grijalva, E., Wood, J. K., Skalos, S. M., & Takekawa, J. (2016). Endangered species management and ecosystem restoration: Finding the common ground. Ecology and Society, 21(1), 19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, C. W. (1976). A delayed-recruitment model of population dynamics, with an application to baleen whale populations. Journal of Mathematical Biology, 3(3–4), 381–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, C. W. (2010). Mathematical bioeconomics: The mathematics of conservation (3rd ed.). John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

  • Conrad, J. M. (1999). Resource economics. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, J. M., & Clark, C. W. (1987). Natural resource economics: Notes and problems. Cambridge University Press.

  • Costello, C., & Polasky, S. (2008). Optimal harvesting of stochastic spatial resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 56, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel, E. P., & Abbott, J. K. (2014). Natural capital from metaphor to measurement. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 1, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel, E. P., Gopalakrishnan, S., & Bayasgalan, O. (2015). Bioeconomics: Nature as capital. In R. Halvorsen & D. F. Layton (Eds.), Handbook on the Economics of Natural Resources (pp. 165–205). Edward Elgar.

  • Fenichel, E. P., Horan, R. D., & Bence, J. R. (2010). Indirect management of invasive species with biocontrol: A bioeconomic model of salmon and alewife in Lake Michigan. Resource and Energy Economics, 32, 500–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garton, E. O., Connelly, J. W., Horne, J. S., Hagen, C. A., Moser, A., & Schroeder, M. A. (2011). Greater sage-grouse population dynamics and probability of persistence. In J. W. Connelly & S. T. Knick (Eds.), Greater Sage-Grouse: Ecology and conservation of a landscape species and its habitats (pp. 293–382). University of California Press.

  • Greenstone, M., & Gayer, T. (2009). Quasi-experimental and experimental approaches to environmental economics. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 57(1), 21–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L. (2007). Conservation reserve program: Environmental benefits update. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, 36(2), 267–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman, R. (1976). The harvest decision when a standing forest has value. Economic Inquiry, 14(1), 52–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, J., & Davis, D. (2012). Oklahoma lesser prairie chicken conservation plan: A collaborative strategy for species conservation. Seeley Lake, Montana: Ecosystem Management Research Institute

  • Horan, R., & Fenichel, E. P. (2007). Economics and ecology of managing emerging infectious animal diseases. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89(5), 1232–1238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan, R. D., Fenichel, E. P., Drury, K. L. S., & Lodge, D. M. (2011). Managing ecological thresholds in coupled environmental-human systems. Proceedings of the National Academy of the Sciences, 108(18), 7333–7338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan, R. D., & Melstrom, R. T. (2011). No sympathy for the devil. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 62(3), 367–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan, R. D., Shogren, J. F., & Gramig, B. M. (2008). Wildlife conservation payments to address habitat fragmentation and disease risks. Environment and Development Economics, 13(03), 415–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan, R. D., & Wolf, C. A. (2005). The economics of managing infectious wildlife disease. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(3), 537–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langpap, C., & Kerkvliet, J. (2012). Endangered species conservation on private land: Assessing the effectiveness of habitat conservation plans. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 64(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langpap, C., Kerkvliet, J., & Shogren, J. F. (2018). The economics of the U.S. Endangered Species Act: A review of recent developments. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 12(1), 69–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenhart, S., & Workman, J. T. (2007). Optimal control applied to biological models. Chapman and Hall.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, E. (2014). Conservation, the farm bill, and US agri-environmental policy. Choices, 29(3), 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, J. B., & White, D. S. (1996). Economic benefits of rare and endangered species: Summary and meta-analysis. Ecological Economics, 18(3), 197–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, S., Swinton, S. M., Lupi, F., & Jolejole-Foreman, C. (2012). Farmers’ willingness to participate in payment-for-environmental-services programmes. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63(3), 604–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, E., Homans, F., & Haight, R. (2000). Exploring strategies for improving the cost effectiveness of endangered species management: The Kirtland’s Warbler as a case study. Land Economics, 76(3), 462–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehmood, S. R., & Zhang, D. (2005). Determinants of forest landowner participation in the Endangered Species Act Safe Harbor program. Human Dimensions of Wildlife, 10(4), 249–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melstrom, R. T. (2017). Where to drill? The petroleum industry’s response to an endangered species listing. Energy Economics, 66, 320–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melstrom, R. T., & Horan, R. D. (2013). Managing excessive predation in a predator-endangered prey setting. Ecological Economics, 90, 85–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melstrom, R. T., Lee, K., & Byl, J. P. (2018). Do regulations to protect endangered species on private lands affect local employment? Evidence from the listing of the lesser prairie chicken. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 43(3), 346–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: Biodiversity synthesis. World Resources Institute.

  • Miller, J. K., Scott, M. J., Miller, C. R., & Waits, L. P. (2002). The endangered species act: Dollars and sense? BioScience, 52(2), 163–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monke, J., & Johnson, R. (2010). Actual farm bill spending and cost estimates. In Congressional Research Service Report for Congress.

  • Naidoo, R., Balmford, A., Ferraro, P. J., Polasky, S., Ricketts, T. H., & Rouget, M. (2006). Integrating economic costs into conservation planning. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 21(12), 681–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nalle, D. J., Montgomery, C. A., Arthur, J. L., Polasky, S., & Schumaker, N. H. (2004). Modeling joint production of wildlife and timber. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48(3), 997–1017.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perman, R., Yue, M., McGilvray, J., & Common, M. (2003). Natural resource and environmental economics (3rd ed.). Pearson.

  • Polasky, S., Camm, J. D., & Garber-Yonts, B. G. (2001). Selecting biological reserves cost-effectively: An application to terrestrial vertebrate conservation in Oregon. Land Economics, 77(1), 68–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polasky, S., & Doremus, H. (1998). When the truth hurts: Endangered species policy on private land with imperfect information. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 35(1), 22–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polasky, S., Nelson, E., Lonsdorf, E., Fackler, P., & Starfield, A. (2005). Conserving species in a working landscape: Land use with biological and economic objectives. Ecological Applications, 15(4), 1387–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pruett, C. L., Patten, M. A., & Wolfe, D. H. (2009). Avoidance behavior by prairie grouse: Implications for development of wind energy. Conservation Biology, 23(5), 1253–1259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salau, K. R., & Fenichel, E. P. (2015). Bioeconomic analysis supports the Endangered Species Act. Journal of Mathematical Biology, 71, 817–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchirico, J. N., & Springborn, M. (2011). How to get there from here: Ecological and economic dynamics of ecosystem service provision. Environmental and Resource Economics, 48(2), 243–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchirico, J. N., & Wilen, J. (1999). Bioeconomics of spatial exploitation in a patchy environment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 37, 129–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanafelt, D. W., Clobert, J., Fenichel, E. P., Hochberg, M., Kinzig, A., Loreau, M., Marquet, P., & Perrings, C. (2018). Species dispersal and spatial insurance in human-dominated systems. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 457, 199–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skonhoft, A., & Armstrong, C. W. (2005). Conservation of wildlife: A bioeconomic model of a wildlife reserve under the pressure of habitat destruction and harvesting outside the reserve. Natural Resource Modeling, 18(1), 69–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swallow, S. K. (1990). Depletion of the environmental basis for renewable resources: The economics of interdependent renewable and nonrenewable resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 19, 281–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • USEIA. (2019). Oklahoma state energy profile. https://www.eia.gov/state/print.php?sid=OK

  • USFWS. (2010). Attwater's prairie chicken recovery plan. Albuquerque, New Mexico: U.S. Department of the Interior

  • USFWS. (2013). Federal and state endangered and threatened species expenditures. Washington D.C.: U.S. Department of the Interior

  • USFWS. (2014). Determination of threatened status for the lesser prairie-chicken. Federal Register, 79(69), 19974–20071.

    Google Scholar 

  • USFWS. (2016). Lesser prairie-chicken removed from the list of endangered and threatened wildlife. Federal Register, 81(139), 47047–47048.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Pelt, W. E., Kyle, S., Pitman, J., Klute, D., Beauprez, G., Schoeling, D., Janus, A., & Hauer, J. (2013). The lesser prairie-chicken rangewide conservation plan. Cheyenne, Wyoming: Western Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies

  • Wilcove, D. S., Rothstein, D., Dubow, J., Phillips, A., & Losos, E. (1998). Quantifying threats to imperiled species in the United States. BioScience, 48(8), 607–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J., Adams, R. M., & Boggess, W. G. (2000). Cumulative effects and optimal targeting of conservation efforts: Steelhead trout habitat enhancement in Oregon. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82(2), 400–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

We have no funding to declare.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David W. Shanafelt.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

We declare that we have no conflicts or competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 523 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Melstrom, R.T., Shanafelt, D.W. & Reeling, C.J. Coordinating investments in habitat management and economic development. J Bioecon 24, 67–91 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-021-09318-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-021-09318-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation