Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Dynamics of Firm’s Investment in Education and Training: An Agent-based Approach

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study developed an agent-based model of firms’ investment dynamics in education and training based on the cellular automata model. It turned the issue of the dynamics of education and training to an issue of spaces and conducted a simulation to analyze whether the strategy of firms investing in education and training will be profitable in the long term. The main results of this study can be summed up as follows: First, strategies that invest in education and training tend to be inferior to strategies that do not invest in education and training. However, even if the former strategies are inferior, a certain proportion of investing firms survive to exist in the long term. The outcome of the strategies does not largely depend on the initial proportion of education and training investment firms Second, an increase in learning speed works disadvantageously to firms that use education and training investment strategies. Third, a reduction in training cost brings a decrease in total production. Fourth, expanding the scope of information raises the productivity of a society, but acts negatively on firms that use education and training investment strategies. Fifth, an increase in the proportion of job searching due to a drop in search costs enhances the productivity of a society but works negatively on firms that use education and training investment strategies. Sixth, the government’s support for training expenses increases total production and the proportion of firms that invested in education and training as well.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Because effort expenditure was assumed to be in proportion to training costs in the function of individual workers’ effort expenditure, workers increase their effort not only in the first year when they are employed by the firm that provides training for them but also continually in the following years.

  2. In the following explanations, industry index i is omitted unless it has important meanings.

  3. The results of this study are not sensitive to the specific form of the production function. In the author's other work, Yang (2018)-written in Korean, we assumed and analyzed specific forms of production functions rather than the Sugarscape model, and the main results were substantially the same.

  4. You may request the program code to the researcher in charge by email at jseyang@krivet.re.kr.

  5. Someone may suspect this as the error of the learning method of this study. In other words, the simulation of strategies allocated at random in the initial period may have been maintained to the end as it was. However, it was found that when changes in the sensitivity strategy of workers’ effort expenditure were tracked, the strategy of individual workers has continually changed.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (1997). Training and innovation in an imperfect labour market. The Review of Economic Studies, 64(3), 445–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J.-S. (1998). Why do firms train? theory and evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), 79–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J.-S. (1999a). Beyond becker: Training in imperfect labour markets. The Economic Journal, 109(453), F112–F142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J.-S. (1999b). The structure of wages and investment in general training. The Journal of Political Economy, 107(3), 539–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2000). Certification of training and training outcomes. European Economic Review, 44(4–6), 917–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1982). Labor contracts as partial gift exchange. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97(4), 543–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1984). Gift exchange and efficiency-wage theory: Four views. The American Economic Review, 74(2), 79–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H. (2001). Why do temporary help firms provide free general skills training? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(4), 1409–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ballot, G. (2002). Modeling the labor market as an evolving institution: Model ARTEMIS. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 49, 51–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballot, G., & Taymaz, E. (2001). Training policies and economic growth in an evolutionary world. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 12(3), 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballot, G., Kant, J. D., & Goudet, O. (2013). A multi-agent model of the French Labor Market: WORKSIM. In: WEHIA 2013 - 18th annual workshop on economic science with heterogeneous interacting agents, Reykjavik Iceland. ffhal-01512989.

  • Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in human capital: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), 9–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergmann, B. R. (1974). A microsimulation of the macroeconomy with explicitly represented money flows. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 3(3), 475–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, M. (1981). An empirical test of the theory of on-the-job-search. The Journal of Human Resources, 16(1), 129–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Diamond, P. (1990). The Aggregate matching function. In P. A. Diamond (Ed.), Growth, productivity, unemployment: Essays to celebrate Bob Solow’s birthday (pp. 159–201). MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. (1995). The wage curve. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. L., & Chatterji, M. (1998). Unions and efficient training. The Economic Journal, 108(447), 328–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudreau, J. W. (2010). Stratification and growth in agent-based matching markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 75, 168–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2004). Microeconomics: Behavior, institutions, and evolution. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmichael, L. (1983). Firm-specific human capital and promotion ladders. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 251–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C., & Wang, Y. (1996). Human capital investment under asymmetric information: The Pigovian conjecture revisited. Journal of Labor Economics, 14(3), 505–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., Kabus, K., Neugart, M., & Wersching, K. (2008). Skills, innovation and growth: An agent-based policy analysis. Journal of Economics and Statistics, 228(2–3), 251–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawid, H., Gemkow, S., Harting, P., & Neugart, M. (2009). On the effects of skill upgrading in the presence of spatial labor market frictions: An agent-based analysis of spatial policy design. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 12(4), 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deissenberg, C., van der Hoog, S., & Dawid, H. (2008). Eurace: A massively parallel agent-based model of the European economy. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 204(2), 541–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1977). Competition and market processes in a Simulation model of the Swedish Economy. The American Economic Review, 67(1), 277–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, J. M., & Axtell, R. (1996). Growing artificial societies. Brookings Institution Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Falk, A. (1999). Wage rigidity in a competitive incomplete contract market. The Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 106–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X. (2009). Power laws in economics and finance. Annual Review of Economics, 1, 255–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, M. (1970). The fantastic combinations of John Conway’s new solitaire game ‘life.’ Scientific American, 223, 120–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, F., Machin, S., & Wilkinson, D. (1999). Trade unions and training practices in British workplaces. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52(2), 179–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossberg, A. J., & Sicilian, P. (1999). Minimum wages, on-the-job training, and wage growth. Southern Economic Journal, 65(3), 539–556.

    Google Scholar 

  • Growiec, J., Pammolli, F., Riccaboni, M., & Eugene Stanley, H. (2008). On the size distribution of business firms. Economics Letters, 98, 207–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haepp, T., & Lin, C. (2017). How does the minimum wage affect firm investment in fixed and human capital? evidence from China. Review of Development Economics, 21(4), 1057–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E., & Lazear, E. P. (1984). The excess sensitivity of layoffs and quits to demand. Journal of Labor Economics, 2(2), 233–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handy, F., & Katz, E. (1998). The wage differential between nonprofit institution and corporations: Getting more by paying less? Journal of Comparative Economics, 26(2), 246–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, M. (1981). Firm-specific human capital as a shred investment. American Economic Review, 71(3), 475–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, M. (1982). Minimum wage effects on training on the job. American Economic Review, 72(5), 1070–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M. A., & Ostrom, E. (2006). Empirically based, agent-based models. Ecology and Society, 11(2), 37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, I. S. (1986). Apprentice training costs in British manufacturing establishments: Some new evidence. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 24, 333–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, E., & Ziderman, A. (1990). Investment in general training: The role of information and labour mobility. The Economic Journal, 100(403), 1147–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, L. F. (1986). Efficiency wage theories: A partial evaluation. In S. Fischer (Ed.), NBER macroeconomic annual 1986 (Vol. 1, pp. 235–290). MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leuven, E. (2005). The economics of private sector training: A survey of the literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19(1), 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuven, E., & Oosterbeek, H. (2001). Firm-specific human capital as a shred investment: Comment. American Economic Review, 91(1), 342–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewkovicz, Z., Domingue, D., and Kant, J-D (2009). An agent-based simulation of the French labour market: Studying age discrimination. ESSA 2009, European Social Simulation Association Conference, Guilford, UK.

  • Malcomsona, J. M., Maw, J. W., & McCormick, B. (2003). General training by firms, apprentice contracts, and public policy. European Economic Review, 47, 197–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J., & Leighton, L. (1980). Effect of minimum wages on human capital formation. NBER Working Paper No. 441, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Marx, K. (1992). Capital: Volume 1: A critique of political economy. Penguin Classics, illustrated edition.

  • Martin, C. W., & Neugart, M. (2009). Shocks and endogenous instituions: An agent-based model of labor market performance in turbulent times. Computational Economics, 33, 31–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1981). Union effects: Wages, turnover, and job training. NBER Working Paper No. 808, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • Mosca, M., Musella, M., & Pastore, F. (2007). Relational goods, monitoring and non-pecuniary compensations in the nonprofit sector: The case of the Italian social services. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 78(1), 57–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., & Topel, R. H. (1990). Efficiency wages reconsidered: Theory and evidence. In Y. Weiss & G. Fischelson (Eds.), Advances in the theory and measurement of unemployment (pp. 204–240). St. Martin’s Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Neugart, M. (2008). Labor market policy evaluation with ACE. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 67, 418–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. (1966) The theory of self-reproducing automata, Arthur W. Burks (Ed.), University of Illinois Press, Urbana, IL.

  • Neumark, D., & Wascher, W. (2001). Minimum wages and training revisited. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(3), 563–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neugart, M., & Richiardi, M. G. (2012). Agent-based models of the labor market, Laboratorio Riccardo Revello Center for Employment Studies, Working Paper no. 125.

  • Pigou, A. C. (1912). Wealth and welfare. Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pischke, J.-S. (2001). Continuous training in Germany. Journal of Population Economics, 14(3), 523–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C., & Wadsworth, J. (1994). On-the-job-search, some empirical evidence. European Economic Review, 38, 385–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prachowny, M. F. J. (1993). Okun’s law: Theoretical foundations and revised estimates. Review of Economics and Statistics, 75(2), 331–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rao, N. (2015). General training in labor markets: Common value auction with unobservable investment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 120, 19–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richiardi, M. G. (2012). Agent-based computational economics A short introduction. The Knowledge Engineering Review., 27(2), 137–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenfeld, C. (1977). The extent of job search by employed workers. Monthly Labor Review, Special labor force report 202, 58–62, A-2.

  • Ryan, P. (1980). The cost of job training for a transferable skill. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 8, 334–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1969). Models of segregation. American Economic Review, 59(2), 488–493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1971). Dynamic models of segregation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1, 143–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlicht, E. (1996). Endogenous on-the-job training with moral hazard. Labour Economics, 3, 81–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soskice, D. (1994). Reconciling markets and institutions: The German apprenticeship system. In L. M. Lynch (Ed.), Training and the private sector (pp. 25–60). University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, H. (1993). The economics of youth training in Germany. The Economic Journal, 103(420), 1279–1291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, M. (1994). A theoretical model of on-the-job training with imperfect competition. Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 537–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1982). Alternative theories of wage determination and unemployment: The efficiency wage mode. In M. Gersovitz, C. F. Diaz-Alejandro, G. Ranis, & M. R. Rosenzweig (Eds.), The theory and experience of economic development (1st ed., pp. 78–106). Georg Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilensky, U. (1999). Netlogo. http://ccl.northwestern.edu/netlogo/, Center for connected learning and computer-based modeling, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.

  • Yang, J.-S. (2018). Dynamics of firm investment on training: An agent-based model approach. The Korean Journal of Economic Studies, 51–91.

  • Yu, J.-M., & Cho, S.-B. (2018). An evolutionary agent-based framework for modeling and analysis of labor market. Neurocomputing, 271, 84–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This study was funded by the Korea Research Institute for Vocational Education & Training(KRIVET).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jung-Seung Yang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yang, JS. Dynamics of Firm’s Investment in Education and Training: An Agent-based Approach. Comput Econ 60, 1317–1351 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-021-10206-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-021-10206-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation