Skip to main content
Log in

Optimizing pricing and ordering strategies for new products in the presence of consumers with pre-purchase beliefs

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The new retail era has dramatically altered consumer behavior, with more people now making purchases based on their pre-purchase beliefs about products, even if they lack prior experience with them. Pre-purchase beliefs represent the anticipated value consumers associate with buying a product or service. This study examines how such beliefs influence consumer purchasing decisions and, in turn, affect retailers’ operational decisions and selling strategies. To achieve this, we create an analytical model that characterizes the consumer decision-making process driven by pre-purchase beliefs and has framed the problem of launching new products as a newsvendor problem. We determine the optimal pricing and ordering strategies for retailers and explored the most effective strategies for different consumer types. Our research indicates that deliberately emphasizing or downplaying product attributes can be more effective in pre-launch marketing than providing strictly accurate information. For value-for-money brands, it’s advisable to adjust the operational strategy to “sell less but at a slightly higher price” as the new product struggles to meet consumer expectations. In markets with diverse consumer segments, retailers must accurately estimate the market sizes of each consumer type and anticipate their pre-purchase beliefs. The value consumers place on these beliefs, along with the market sizes of different consumer categories, play a pivotal role in strategy selection. In summary, this study offers valuable insights into the relationship between consumer purchasing behavior driven by pre-purchase beliefs and retailers’ operational decisions and selling strategy choices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source: https://www.invespcro.com/blog/online-consumer-shopping-habits-behavior/.

  2. We remark that this assumption has been justified and widely applied by extant literature, e.g., “customers know their individual valuations, but the retailer (monopolist) is only privy to the statistical distribution characteristics” (Aviv et al., 2009) and “the seller is unable to observe each customer’s realized valuations, but may know the overall distribution of consumers based on historical sales data” (Fay and Xie, 2010).

  3. Pre-belief consumers may have another decision-making process, i.e., comparing the valuation v and the pre-purchase belief \(v_0\) first, then making a purchase if the surplus \(v-p\) is nonnegative. We remark that the two different decision-making processes have the same expected utility \(U_B(p)\), thereby the difference in the decision-making process does not affect our modeling and results.

  4. Considering a free product as a special case, i.e., \(p=0\), if pre-belief consumers consider buying regardless of whether pre-purchase beliefs are met, then they behave the same as surplus-driven consumers.

  5. We remark that if demand is price-dependent, then the expected profit may not be increasing in p which implies that pricing at \(v_0\) may not be able to maximize the retailer’s profit. On the contrary, achieving profit maximization may cause consumer churn. Therefore, the retailer should tradeoff profit maximization and inducing all consumers to buy when they are in conflict.

References

  • Ali Ülkü, M., & Gürler, U. (2018). The impact of abusing return policies: A newsvendor model with opportunistic consumers. International Journal of Production Economics, 203, 124–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. K., & Wilson, J. G. (2003). Wait or buy? The strategic consumer: Pricing and profit implications. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 54, 299–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aviv, Y., Levin, Y., & Nediak, M. (2009). Counteracting strategic consumer behavior in dynamic pricing systems. In C. S. Tang & S. Netessine (Eds.), Consumer-driven demand and operations management models: A systematic study of information-technology-enabled sales mechanisms (pp. 323–352). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Aviv, Y., & Pazgal, A. (2008). Optimal pricing of seasonal products in the presence of forward-looking consumers. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 10, 339–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, S., & Sarvary, M. (2009). How incumbent firms foster consumer expectations, delay launch but still win the markets for next generation products. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 7, 445–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, O., Hu, M., Najafi-Asadolahi, S., & Qian, Q. (2015). Newsvendor selling to loss-averse consumers with stochastic reference points. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 17, 456–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beard, C., & Easingwood, C. (1996). New product launch: Marketing action and launch tactics for high-technology products. Industrial Marketing Management, 25, 87–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bearden, W. O., & Rose, R. L. (1990). Attention to social comparison information: An individual difference factor affecting consumer conformity. Journal of Consumer Research, 16, 461–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacherjee, A. (2001). An empirical analysis of the antecedents of electronic commerce service continuance. Decision Support Systems, 32, 201–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breidert, C., Hahsler, M., & Reutterer, T. (2006). A review of methods for measuring willingness-to-pay. Innovative Marketing, 2, 8–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brummett, R. G., Nayga, R. M., & Wu, X. (2007). On the use of cheap talk in new product valuation. Economics Bulletin, 2, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burmester, A. B., Becker, J. U., van Heerde, H. J., & Clement, M. (2015). The impact of pre- and post-launch publicity and advertising on new product sales. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 32, 408–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P., & Feldman, P. (2015). Price commitments with strategic consumers: Why it can be optimal to discount more frequently ... than optimal. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 17, 399–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P., & Swinney, R. (2009). Purchasing, pricing, and quick response in the presence of strategic consumers. Management Science, 55, 497–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, M. (2023). Multivariate supplier selection for asymmetric specification region: Using price and quality. Annals of Operations Research, 324, 1023–1040.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y.-H., & Jiang, B. (2021). Dynamic pricing and price commitment of new experience goods. Production and Operations Management, 30, 2752–2764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T.-M. (2018). Launching the right new product among multiple product candidates in fashion: Optimal choice and coordination with risk consideration. International Journal of Production Economics, 202, 162–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1972). Durability and monopoly. The Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 143–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, P. S., Krishnamoorthy, A., & Sainam, P. (2010). “Call for prices’’: Strategic implications of raising consumers’ costs. Marketing Science, 29, 158–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Disch, M. (2023). Estimating the costs of product development projects based on external data: The new product development cost benchmarking method. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management. https://doi.org/10.1109/TEM.2023.3237543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliashberg, J., & Robertson, T. S. (1988). New product preannouncing behavior: A market signaling study. Journal of Marketing Research, 25, 282–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fay, S., & Xie, J. (2010). The economics of buyer uncertainty: Advance selling vs. probabilistic selling. Marketing Science, 29, 1040–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, P., Papanastasiou, Y., & Segev, E. (2019). Social learning and the design of new experience goods. Management Science, 65, 1502–1519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuster, A., & Ericson, K. M. M. (2010). Expectations as endowments: Evidence on reference-dependent preferences from exchange and valuation experiments. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 1879–1907.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannakis, M., Dubey, R., Yan, S., Spanaki, K., & Papadopoulos, T. (2020). Social media and sensemaking patterns in new product development: Demystifying the customer sentiment. Annals of Operations Research, 308, 145–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hann, I.-H., & Terwiesch, C. (2003). Measuring the frictional costs of online transactions: The case of a name-your-own-price channel. Management Science, 49, 1563–1579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Tang, C. S., & Bell, D. R. (1998). Rational shopping behavior and the option value of variable pricing. Management Science, 44, S145–S160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hviid, M., & Shaffer, G. (1999). Hassle costs: The Achilles’ heel of price-matching guarantees. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 489–521.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ji, G., Fu, T., Choi, T.-M., Kumar, A., & Tan, K. H. (2022). Price and quality strategy in live streaming e-commerce with consumers’ social interaction and celebrity sales agents. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management. https://doi.org/10.1109/TEM.2022.3227106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, S. C., & Vroom, V. H. (1964). Division of labor and performance under cooperative-competitive conditions. Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 68, 313–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karle, H., & Peitz, M. (2014). Competition under consumer loss aversion. The RAND Journal of Economics, 45, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katona, G. (1972). Inflation and the consumer. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1972, 788–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopalle, P. K., & Lehmann, D. R. (2006). Setting quality expectations when entering a market: What should the promise be? Marketing Science, 25, 8–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lacava, G. J., & Tull, D. S. (1982). Determining the expected value of information for new product introduction. Omega, 10, 383–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai, G., Debo, L. G., & Sycara, K. (2010). Buy now and match later: Impact of posterior price matching on profit with strategic consumers. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 12, 33–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang, C., Çakanyıldırım, M., & Sethi, S. P. (2014). Analysis of product rollover strategies in the presence of strategic customers. Management Science, 60, 1033–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., Li, H., & Hu, F. (2013). Website attributes in urging online impulse purchase: An empirical investigation on consumer perceptions. Decision Support Systems, 55, 829–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lobel, I., Patel, J., Vulcano, G., & Zhang, J. (2016). Optimizing product launches in the presence of strategic consumers. Management Science, 62, 1778–1799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mellers, B., Schwartz, A., & Ritov, I. (1999). Emotion-based choice. Journal of Experimental Psychology-General, 128, 332–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minnema, A., Bijmolt, T. H., Gensler, S., & Wiesel, T. (2016). To keep or not to keep: Effects of online customer reviews on product returns. Journal of Retailing, 92, 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra, N., & Venkataraman, S. V. (2022). Optimal order quantity in the presence of strategic customers. Annals of Operations Research, 315, 1871–1894.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, J., & Dover, P. (1979). Disconfirmation of consumer expectation through product trial. Journal of Applied Psychology, 64, 179–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osadchiy, N., & Bendoly, E. (2015). Are consumers really strategic? Implications from an experimental study. SSRN 2593184.

  • Prasad, A., Stecke, K. E., & Zhao, X. (2011). Advance selling by a newsvendor retailer. Production and Operations Management, 20, 129–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rand, W., & Stummer, C. (2021). Agent-based modeling of new product market diffusion: An overview of strengths and criticisms. Annals of Operations Research, 305, 425–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, J., & Bijmolt, T. H. (2020). Accurately measuring willingness to pay for consumer goods: A meta-analysis of the hypothetical bias. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 48, 499–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spreng, R. A., MacKenzie, S. B., & Olshavsky, R. W. (1996). A reexamination of the determinants of consumer satisfaction. Journal of Marketing, 60, 15–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N. L. (1981). Rational expectations and durable goods pricing. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 112–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, X. (2009). Consumer returns policies and supply chain performance. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 11, 595–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, X., & Zhang, F. (2008). Strategic customer behavior, commitment, and supply chain performance. Management Science, 54, 1759–1773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, X., & Zhang, F. (2009). On the value of commitment and availability guarantees when selling to strategic consumers. Management Science, 55, 713–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulaga, W., & Chacour, S. (2001). Measuring customer-perceived value in business markets: A prerequisite for marketing strategy development and implementation. Industrial Marketing Management, 30, 525–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, M. M., & Zhang, F. (2018). Advance selling to strategic consumers: Preorder contingent production strategy with advance selling target. Production and Operations Management, 27, 1221–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, M. M., & Zhang, F. (2018). Recent research developments of strategic consumer behavior in operations management. Computers and Operations Research, 93, 166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitin, T. M. (1955). Inventory control and price theory. Management Science, 2, 61–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, M., Zhu, S. X., & Teunter, R. H. (2021). Advance selling and advertising: A newsvendor framework. Decision Sciences, 52, 182–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, M., Debo, L., & Kapuscinski, R. (2016). Strategic waiting for consumer-generated quality information: Dynamic pricing of new experience goods. Management Science, 62, 410–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, Y., Wang, Y., & Liu, Y. (2021). Product quality and quantity with responsive pricing. International Journal of Production Research, 59, 7160–7178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhan, Y., Tan, K., Li, Y., & Tse, M. (2018). Unlocking the power of big data in new product development. Annals of Operations Research, 270, 577–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, X., & Stecke, K. E. (2010). Pre-orders for new to-be-released products considering consumer loss aversion. Production and Operations Management, 19, 198–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, L., Tian, P., & Li, X. (2012). Dynamic pricing in the presence of consumer inertia. Omega, 40, 137–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, N., Wang, Q., Cao, P., & Wu, J. (2019). Dynamic pricing with reference price effect and price-matching policy in the presence of strategic consumers. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 70, 2069–2083.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng, R., Shou, B., & Yang, J. (2021). Supply disruption management under consumer panic buying and social learning effects. Omega, 101, 102238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Meng Wu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The research was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grants 72071136, 71911530461 and 71571125.

Appendices

Numerical investigation

In this section, we numerically discuss how reservation utility affects the region of each optimal strategy and how much profit loss can be if retailers ignore or overlook consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs. We set the parameters as follows: \(c=3\), \(v_0\in [3, 3.8]\), \(\beta =0.6\), \(N\sim N(120,40^2)\) and \(V\sim N(4,2.5^2)\).

1.1 The effect of reservation utility

We start with the effect of reservation utility by varying reservation utility \(r_b \in \{1.4,1.6,1.8\}\). Note that \(p_S=8\) and \(p_0 \in \{3.71,3.43,3.15\}\) under this setting. Figure 7 presents the critical market shares of BS consumers with varying reservation utility. It is clear that a higher reservation utility reduces the size of the area where selling to S and BS is optimal. Since a bigger price discount has to be offered to BS consumers if the reservation utility increases, selling to S and BS is less likely to be optimal.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Optimal strategy with varying reservation utility

1.2 The consequences of ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs

Next, we investigated the potential profit loss that retailers could face if they ignore or overlook consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs. We choose the baseline strategy of “selling to S only” as the benchmark. To examine the profit loss from ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs, we compare the retailer’s profit under the optimal strategy with the profit under the “selling to S only” strategy, i.e., \(\max \{\Pi _S,\Pi _A,\Pi _{S+BS}\}\) vs. \(\Pi _{S}\). Note that the percentage profit loss from ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs is measured by \(\Delta _{\text {Loss}}:=\frac{\Pi _{S}-\max \{\Pi _S,\Pi _A,\Pi _{S+BS}\}}{\Pi _{S}}\times 100\%\). Figure 8 presents the percentage loss from ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs when \(r_b=1.4\).

Fig. 8
figure 8

Profit loss from ignoring pre-purchase belief \(\Delta _{\text {Loss}}\)

Not surprisingly, ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs does not bring losses only if “selling to S only” is optimal, i.e., most consumers are purely surplus-driven. However, if pre-belief consumers account for a large proportion of the market, then continuing to use the “selling to S only” strategy will result in a considerable profit loss of up to more than 70%. Moreover, ignoring consumers’ pre-purchase beliefs can further exacerbate profit loss if consumers buying decisions are driven by both pre-purchase belief and surplus. For example, when the proportion of surplus-driven consumers is relatively high [low], i.e., \(\alpha _S\)=70% [30%], then the maximum profit loss is increased from 7.9% (selling to S and BS ) to 31.2% (selling to all) [from 72% to 206%]. This is because the reservation utility demanded by BS consumers further reduces the retailer’s profit.

Lemma and proofs

Lemma 1

If the mean pre-belief demand \(\mu _D(v_0)\) has an IBE and the market size distribution \(F_N(\cdot )\) has an IGFR, then the expected profit \(\Pi (Q^*, p^*)\) is quasi-concave in \(v_0\), and there exists a unique consumer pre-purchase belief \(v_0^*\) that maximizes the expected profit.

Proof

The first and second derivation of \(\Pi (Q^*,p^*)\) with respect to \(v_0\) are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0}= & {} -v_0f_v(v_0)\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}xdF_N(x) +\bar{F}_v(v_0)[\frac{c}{v_0}F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})\nonumber \\{} & {} -\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}F_N(x)dx],\end{aligned}$$
(B.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2\Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0^2}= & {} -v_0f_v'(v_0)\int _0^{F_N^{-1} (\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}xdF_N(x)-2f_v(v_0)[\frac{c}{v_0}F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})\nonumber \\{} & {} +\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}F_N(x)dx] +\frac{c^2\bar{F}_v(v_0)}{v_0^3f_N(F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0}))}. \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)

Note that \(\left. \frac{\partial \Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0}\right| _{v_0=c}=0\) and \(\left. \frac{\partial \Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0}\right| _{v_0=\bar{v}}=\bar{v}[\bar{F}_v(\bar{v})]'\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{\bar{v}-c}{\bar{v}})}xdF_N(x)<0\). Further, \(\frac{\partial ^2\Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0^2}\Big |_{v_0=c}=\frac{1}{cf_N(0)}>0\) indicates that there exists at least one solution \(v_0^*\in (c,\overline{v}_0)\) such that \(\frac{\partial \Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0}\Big |_{v=v_0^*}=0\). For the uniqueness of \(v_0^*\), we prove \(\left. \frac{\partial ^2\Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0^2}\right| _{v_0=v_0^*}<0\) in the following.

Since we assume that \(\mu _D(v_0)\) is IBE, then we have that \(\bar{F}_v(v_0)\) is IBE, and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de}{dv_0}= & {} -\frac{[v_0[\bar{F}_v(v_0)]''+[\bar{F}_v(v_0)]']\bar{F}_v(v_0)-v_0(\bar{F}_v'(v_0))^2}{\bar{F}_v^2(v_0)}\ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

which we can rewrite as

$$\begin{aligned}{}[-f_v(v_0)]'\le & {} \left( \frac{v_0f_v(v_0)}{\bar{F}_v(v_0)}+1\right) \frac{f_v(v_0)}{v_0}. \end{aligned}$$
(B.3)

Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2\Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0^2}\bigg |_{v=v_0^*}\le & {} -f_v(v_0^*)\big [(\frac{-v_0^*f_v(v_0^*)}{\bar{F}_v(v_0^*)}+1)\int _0^{F_N^{-1} (\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})}xdF_N(x)\\{} & {} +\frac{2c}{v_0^*}F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})\big ]\\{} & {} +\frac{c^2\bar{F}_v(v_0^*)}{{v_0^*}^3f_N(F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*}))} =\frac{c\bar{F}_v(v_0^*)}{{v_0^*}^2\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})}xdF_N(x)}\cdot A(v_0^*), \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} A(v_0^*)=-F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})\left( \int _0^{F_N^{-1} (\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})}xf_N(x)dx+\frac{c}{v_0^*}F_N^{-1} (\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})\right) \\ +\frac{c\int _0^{F_N^{-1} (\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})}xdF_N(x)}{v_0^*f_N(F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*}))}. \end{aligned}$$

To complete the proof, we need to show that \(A(v_0^*)\le 0\). Let \(t=F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^*-c}{v_0^*})\) and \(r(t)=\frac{f_N(t)}{1-F_N(t)}\). Then, we can rewrite \(A(v_0^*)\) as

$$\begin{aligned} A(t)= & {} -t\left( \int _0^txdF_N(x)+t(1-F_N(t))\right) +\frac{\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{r(t)}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(A(0)=0\) and N has an IGFR that implies that \(-\frac{tr'(t)}{r(t)}\le 1\). Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} A'(t)= & {} -\left( \int _0^txdF_N(x)+t(1-F_N(t))\right) -t\big (1-F_N(t)\big ) +\frac{tf_N(t)r(t)-r'(t)\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{r^2(t)}\\\le & {} -t\big (1-F_N(t)\big )-\int _0^txdF_N(x)+\frac{\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{tr(t)}. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(B(t)\triangleq -t\big (1-F_N(t)\big )-\int _0^txdF_N(x)+\frac{\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{tr(t)}\). Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t \rightarrow 0}B(t)=\lim _{t \rightarrow 0}{\frac{\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{tr(t)}}= & {} \lim _{t \rightarrow 0}{\frac{tf_N(t)}{r(t)+tr'(t)}}=0 \text { and } B'(t)=-\frac{[tr(t)]'\int _0^txdF_N(x)}{\big (tr(t)\big )^2}. \end{aligned}$$

By the definition of IGFR; that is, \([tr(t)]'\ge 0\), \(B'(t)\le 0\), which implies that \(B(t)\le 0\) holds. Since \(A'(t)\le B(t)\) and \(A(0)=0\), we have \(\frac{\partial ^2\Pi (Q^*,p^*)}{\partial v_0^2}\Big |_{v=v_0^*}\le 0\); that is, \(\Pi (Q^*,p^*)\) is quasi-concave in \(v_0\). This completes the proof. \(\square \)

1.1 Proof of Proposition 4.1

Since the highest price that consumers are willing to pay is \(v_0\), the retailer’s optimal selling price must satisfy \(p^*\le v_0\). Since the market demand \(D(v_0)\) is independent of the selling price and the expected profit is increasing in p, the retailer would price the product at \(v_0\) and extract all consumer surplus, i.e., \(p^*=v_0\). Differentiating \(\Pi (Q,p^*)\) with respect to Q gives

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\Pi (Q,p^*)}{dQ}=p^*-c-p^*F_N(\frac{Q}{\bar{F}_v(v_0)})\quad \text {and}\quad \frac{d^2\Pi (Q,p^*)}{dQ^2}=-p^*f(\frac{Q}{\bar{F}_v(v_0)})<0. \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, \(\Pi (Q,p^*)\) is concave in Q. Then there is a unique \(Q^*\) such that \(\frac{d\Pi (Q,p^*)}{dQ}|_{Q=Q^*}=0\), that is \(Q^*=\bar{F}_v(v_0)F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})\). Accordingly, \(\Pi (Q^*,p^*)=v_0\bar{F}_v(v_0)\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}xdF_N(x)\).

1.2 Proof of Proposition 4.2

We omit the proof details for optimal decisions. Here we only prove the monotonicity of \(p_0\). From Equation (4), the first derivation of \(p_0\) with respect to \(r_b\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dp_0}{dr_b}=\frac{F_v(p_0+r_b)+2r_bf_v(p_0+r_b)}{-1-2r_bf_v(p_0+r_b)+F_v(p_0+r_b)}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(-(1-F_v(p+r_b))\le 0\) and \(F_v(p+r_b)+2r_bf_v(p+r_b)\ge 0\), we have \(\frac{dp}{dr_b}\le 0\). Replacing \(v_0\) by \(p_0\) in Equation (4), we can find a critical \(\hat{r}_b\) such that \(U_{BS}(p_0(\hat{r}_b))=U_{BS}(v_0)=0\).

1.3 Proof of Proposition 5.1

Overpricing (i.e., \(p > v_0\)) will prevent pre-belief consumers. However, underpricing (i.e., \(p \le v_0\)) will attract both types of consumers, but may result in profit loss due to offering too much of a discount for BS consumers. Therefore, we discuss the problem in two cases: \(v_0<p\) and \(v_0\ge p\). For \(v_0< p\), since B consumers never buy in this case, selling to all is identical to selling to BS only. By Proposition 4.2, the optimal decisions and the correspondingly maximal expected profit are \(p^*=p_0\), \(Q^*=\alpha _{BS}\bar{F}_v(p_0+r_b)F_N^{-1}(\frac{p_0-c}{p_0})\) and \(\Pi _{BS}(p^*,Q^*)=\alpha _{BS}K(p_0,r_b)\). For \(v_0\ge p\), all consumers with pre-purchase beliefs consider buying. By Proposition 4.1, we have \(p^*=v_0\), \(Q^*=\bar{F}_v(v_0)F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})\) and \(\Pi _{A}(p^*,Q^*)=K(v_0,0)\). The profit difference between the two selling strategies is

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi= & {} \Pi _{A}-\Pi _{BS}=K(v_0,0)-\alpha _{BS}K(p_0,r_b)\\= & {} v_0\bar{F}_v(v_0)\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0-c}{v_0})}xdF_N(x) -\alpha _{BS}p_0\bar{F}_v(p_0+r_b)\int _0^{F_N^{-1}(\frac{p_0-c}{p_0})}xdF_N(x). \end{aligned}$$

Taking the first derivation of \(\Delta \Pi \) with respect to \(\alpha _{BS}\) gives \(\frac{d \Delta \Pi }{d\alpha _{BS}}=-K(p_0,r_b)<0\) which indicates that \(\Delta \Pi \) is decreasing in \(\alpha _{BS}\). Note that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=0}=K(v_0,0)>0\). If \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}=K(v_0,0)-K(p_0,r_b)>0\), then \(\Delta \Pi \ge 0\) always holds. Otherwise, there exists a critical market share \({{\tilde{\alpha }}}_{BS}\) such that \(\Delta \Pi ({{\tilde{\alpha }}}_{BS})=0\). If \(\alpha _{BS}\le {{\tilde{\alpha }}}_{BS}\), then \(\Delta \Pi \ge 0\); otherwise \(\Delta \Pi \le 0\). To complete the proof, we next verify the sign of \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}\).

It follows from Lemma 1 that \(K(v_0,0)\) is quasi-concave in \(v_0\). This implies that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}=K(v_0,0)-K(p_0,r_b)\) is quasi-concave in \(v_0\). Note that, by Proposition 4.2, selling to BS exists only if \(p_0\ge v_0\) for any given \(v_0\). Therefore, to ensure both strategies exist, the admissible range of \(v_0\) should be \([c,p_0]\). Since \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}(v_0=c)=-K(p_0,r_b)<0\) and \(\lim \limits _{v_0\rightarrow p_0}\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}(v_0)=K(p_0,0)-K(p_0,r_b)\ge 0\), there exists a unique \(\tilde{v_0}\) such that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}(\tilde{v}_0)=0\). If \(v_0\le \tilde{v}_0\), then \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}\le 0\); otherwise, \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _{BS}=1}\ge 0\).

1.4 Proof of Proposition 6.1

1.4.1 (a) \(p_0\le v_0^L\le v_0^H\)

The optimal decisions of high pricing are \(p^*=v_0^H\) and \(Q^*=\alpha _H\bar{F}_v(v_0^H)F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^H-c}{v_0^H})\). For low pricing, we have \(p^*=v_0^L\) and \(Q^*=[\alpha _H\bar{F}_v(v_0^H)+\alpha _L\bar{F}_v(v_0^L)]F_N^{-1}(\frac{v_0^L-c}{v_0^L})\). Correspondingly, the maximum profits of high and low pricing are \(\Pi _{H}=\Pi _{HB}+\Pi _{HBS}=\alpha _HK(v_0^H,0)\) and \(\Pi _{A}=\Pi _{HB}+\Pi _{HBS}+\Pi _{LB}+\Pi _{LBS}=\alpha _HK(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})+\alpha _LK(v_0^L,0)\), respectively. The profit difference between the two selling strategies is

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi= & {} \Pi _{A}-\Pi _{H}=\alpha _H(K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})-K(v_0^L,0)-K(v_0^H,0))+K(v_0^L,0). \end{aligned}$$

Since \(K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})\le K(v_0^L,0)\), it is clear that \(\Delta \Pi \) is decreasing in \(\alpha _H\). Note that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _H=0}>0\). So, there must exist a critical \(\hat{\alpha }_H^0\) such that \(\Delta \Pi (\hat{\alpha }_H^0)=0\). If \(\alpha _H\le {\hat{\alpha }}_H^0\), then \(\Delta \Pi \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\Delta \Pi \le 0\).

1.4.2 (b) \(v_0^L\le p_0\le v_0^H\)

By comparing the profits of any two strategies, we have the following results.

  1. (I)

    (Selling to All vs. Selling to H) See part (a).

  2. (II)

    (Selling to All vs. Selling to H and LBS) There exists a critical market share \(\hat{\alpha }_H^{1}\) such that \(\Pi _{H+LBS}(\hat{\alpha }_H^{1})=\Pi _{A}(\hat{\alpha }_H^{1})\). If \(\alpha _H\le \hat{\alpha }_H^{1}\), then \(\Pi _{A}\ge \Pi _{H+LBS} \); otherwise, \(\Pi _{A}\le \Pi _{H+LBS} \).

  3. (III)

    (Selling to H vs. Selling to H and LBS) There exists a critical market share of high-belief consumers \(\hat{\alpha }_H^2\) such that \(\Pi _{H+LBS}(\hat{\alpha }_H^{2})=\Pi _{H}(\hat{\alpha }_H^{2})\). If \(\alpha _H\le \alpha _H^{2}\), then \(\Pi _{H+LBS}\ge \Pi _{H} \); otherwise, \(\Pi _{H}\ge \Pi _{H+LBS}\).

Note that \(K(v_0^H,0)\ge K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)\ge K(v_0^L, \Delta _{v_0})\) for \(v_0^L< p_0\le v_0^H\). So we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\hat{\alpha }_H^1}{d\alpha _{BS}}= & {} \frac{K(p_0,r_b)(K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0}) -K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0))}{[K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)+K(v_0^L,0)-K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})-\alpha _{BS}K(p_0,r_b)]^2}\le 0,\\ \frac{d\hat{\alpha }_H^2}{d\alpha _{BS}}= & {} \frac{K(p_0,r_b)(K(v_0^H,0)-K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0))}{[K(v_0^H,0)+\alpha _{BS}K(p_0,r_b)-K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)]^2}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Further, we have \(\hat{\alpha }_H^2|_{\alpha _{BS}=0}=0\), \(\hat{\alpha }_H^2|_{\alpha _{BS}=1}=\frac{K(p_0,r_b)}{K(p_0,r_b)+K(v_0^H,0)-K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)}<1\), and

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\alpha }_H^1|_{\alpha _{BS}=0}= & {} \frac{K(v_0^L,0)}{K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)+K(v_0^L,0)-K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})}\\\ge & {} \frac{K(v_0^L,0)}{K(v_0^H,0)+K(v_0^L,0)-K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})}=\hat{\alpha }_H^0,\\ \hat{\alpha }_H^1|_{\alpha _{BS}=1}= & {} \frac{K(v_0^L,0)-K(p_0,r_b)}{K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)-K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})+K(v_0^L,0)-K(p_0,r_b)}<1. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(\hat{\alpha }_H^1\) and \(\hat{\alpha }_H^2\) intersect with \(\hat{\alpha }_H^0\) at \(\hat{\alpha }_{BS}^1\) and \(\hat{\alpha }_{BS}^2\), respectively. Further, it is easy to verify that \(\hat{\alpha }_{BS}^1=\hat{\alpha }_{BS}^2=\frac{K(v_0^L,0)}{K(p_0,r_b)}\cdot \frac{K(p_0,v_0^H-p_0)-K(v_0^H,0)}{K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})-K(v_0^H,0)}\). This implies that three critical market shares have a common intersection. Therefore, selling to all is best if \(\alpha _H\le \min \{{\hat{\alpha }}_H^0, {\hat{\alpha }}_H^1\}\); selling to H is best if \(\alpha _H\ge \max \{{\hat{\alpha }}_H^0, {\hat{\alpha }}_H^2\}\), otherwise selling to H and LBS is best.

1.4.3 (c) \(v_0^L\le v_0^H\le p_0\)

By comparing the profits of any two strategies, we have

  1. (I)

    (Selling to All vs. Selling to BS) There exists a critical market share of H consumers \({\check{\alpha }}_H^0\) such that \(\Pi _{A}({\check{\alpha }}_H^0)=\Pi _{BS}\). If \(\alpha _H\le {\check{\alpha }}_H^0\), then selling to all consumers is best; otherwise, selling to BS consumers is best.

  2. (II)

    (Selling to All vs. Selling to H and LBS consumer) There exists a critical market share of H consumers \({\check{\alpha }}_H^1\) such that \(\Pi _{A}({\check{\alpha }}_H^1)=\Pi _{H+LBS}({\check{\alpha }}_H^1)\). If \(\alpha _H\le {\check{\alpha }}_H^1\), then selling to all consumers is best; otherwise, selling to H and LBS is best.

  3. (III)

    (Selling to H and LBS vs. Selling to BS) There exists a critical market share of H consumers \({\check{\alpha }}_H^2\) such that \(\Pi _{H+LBS}({\check{\alpha }}_H^2)=\Pi _{BS}\). If \(\alpha _H\ge {{\check{\alpha }}}_H^2\), then selling to H and LBS is best; otherwise, selling to BS consumers is best.

Note that \(K(v_0^H,0)\ge K(v_0^L, \Delta _{v_0})\), \(K(v_0^H,0)\ge K(v_0^H, r_b)\) and \(K(v_0^L,0)\ge K(v_0^L, \Delta _{v_0})\). If critical market shares exist, then we have \(\frac{d\hat{\alpha }_H^0}{d\alpha _{BS}}\le 0\),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d{\check{\alpha }}_H^1}{d\alpha _{BS}}= & {} \frac{K(v_0^H,r_b)(K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0}) -K(v_0^H,0))}{[K(v_0^H,0)+K(v_0^L,0)-\alpha _{BS}K(v_0^H,r_b)-K(v_0^L,\Delta _{v_0})]^2}\le 0,\\ \frac{d{\check{\alpha }}_H^2}{d\alpha _{BS}}= & {} \frac{K(v_0^H,0)(K(p_0,r_b)-K(v_0^H,r_b))}{[K(v_0^H,0)-\alpha _{BS}K(v_0^H,r_b)]^2}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Note that \({\check{\alpha }}_H^0|_{\alpha _{BS}=0}\ge 1\), \({\check{\alpha }}_H^1|_{\alpha _{BS}=0}\ge 0\) and \({\check{\alpha }}_H^2|_{\alpha _{BS}=0}=0\). Further, it is easy to verify that \({\check{\alpha }}_H^0\), \({\check{\alpha }}_H^1\) and \({\check{\alpha }}_H^2\) intersect at the same point \({\check{\alpha }}_{BS}\), i.e., there is a critical \({\check{\alpha }}_{BS}\) such that \({\check{\alpha }}_H^0({\check{\alpha }}_{BS})={\check{\alpha }}_H^1({\check{\alpha }}_{BS})={\check{\alpha }}_H^2({\check{\alpha }}_{BS})\).

1.5 Proof of Proposition 6.2

By comparing the profits of any two strategies, we have

  1. (I)

    (Selling to S vs. Selling to All) The profit difference between selling to S and selling to all is \(\Delta \Pi =\Pi _S-\Pi _A=\alpha _SK(p_S,0)-K(v_0,0)\). Clearly, \(\Delta \Pi \) is increasing in \(\alpha _S\). Note that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=0}<0\) and \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=1}=K(p_S,0)-K(v_0,0)\). If \(K(p_S,0)-K(v_0,0)\le 0\), then \(\Delta \Pi <0\) always holds; otherwise, there exists a critical market share \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^0\) such that \(\Delta \Pi ({\hat{\alpha }}_S^0)=0\). If \(\alpha _S\ge {\hat{\alpha }}_S^0\), then selling to S consumers only is best; otherwise, selling to all consumers is best.

  2. (II)

    (Selling to S and BS vs. Selling to All) The profit difference between selling to S+BS and selling to all is

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi= & {} \Pi _{S+BS}-\Pi _{A}=\alpha _SK(p_0,0)+\beta (1-\alpha _{S})K(p_0,r_b)-K(v_0,0). \end{aligned}$$

    Taking the first derivation of \(\Delta \Pi \) with respect to \(\alpha _S\) gives that \(\frac{d\Delta \Pi }{d\alpha _S}=K(p_0,0)-\beta K(p_0,r_b)>0\) holds for any given \(\beta \), which indicates that \(\Delta \Pi \) is increasing in \(\alpha _S\). Note that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=1}=K(p_0,0)-K(v_0,0)\) and \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=0}=\beta K(p_0,r_b)-K(v_0,0)\). If \((K(p_0,0)-K(v_0,0))(\beta K(p_0,r_b)-K(v_0,0))\ge 0\), then \(\Delta \Pi >0\) or \(\Delta \Pi <0\) always holds; otherwise, there exists a critical market share \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^1\) such that \(\Delta \Pi ({\hat{\alpha }}_S^1)=0\). If \(\alpha _S\ge {\hat{\alpha }}_S^1\), then selling to S and BS is best; otherwise selling to all is best.

  3. (III)

    (Selling to S only vs. Selling to S and BS) The profit difference between selling to S and selling to S+BS is

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi= & {} \Pi _{S}-\Pi _{S+BS}=\alpha _SK(p_S,0)-\alpha _SK(p_0,0)-\beta (1-\alpha _{S})K(p_0,r_b)\\= & {} \alpha _S[K(p_S,0)-K(p_0,0)+\beta K(p_0,r_b)]-\beta K(p_0,r_b). \end{aligned}$$

    Taking the first derivation of \(\Delta \Pi \) with respect to \(\alpha _S\) gives \(\frac{d\Delta \Pi }{d\alpha _S}=K(p_S,0)-K(p_0,0)+\beta K(p_0,r_b)>0\), which indicates that \(\Delta \Pi \) is increasing in \(\alpha _S\). Note that \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=1}=K(p_S,0)-K(p_0,0)\) and \(\Delta \Pi |_{\alpha _S=0}=-\beta K(p_0,r_b)\le 0\). If \(K(p_S,0)-K(p_0,0)\le 0\), then \(\Delta \Pi <0\) always holds; otherwise, there exists a critical market share \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^2\) such that \(\Delta \Pi ({\hat{\alpha }}_S^2)=0\). If \(\alpha _S\ge {\hat{\alpha }}_S^2\), then selling to S only is best; otherwise, selling to S and BS is best.

Note that \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^0|_{v_0=c}=0\), \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^1|_{v_0=c}<0\), and \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^i\) exists only if \(K(p_s,0)\ge K(p_0,0)\ge K(v_0,0)\) where \(i\in \{1, 2,3\}\) and \(v_0\le p_0\le p_S\). By Lemma 1, we have \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^0\) and \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^1\) are quasi-concave in \(v_0\) and \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^2\) is independent with \(v_0\). Then, it is easy to verify that there is a critical \(\hat{v}_0\) such that \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^0(\hat{v}_0)={\hat{\alpha }}_S^1(\hat{v}_0)={\hat{\alpha }}_S^2\), i.e., \(\hat{v}_0\) satisfies \(K(\hat{v}_0,0)=\frac{\beta K(p_S,0)K(p_0,r_b)}{K(p_S,0)-K(p_0,0)+\beta K(p_0,r_b)}\). Therefore, selling to all is best if \(\alpha _S\le {\hat{\alpha }}_S^0\) for \(v_0\ge \hat{v}_0\) or \(\alpha _S\le {\hat{\alpha }}_S^1\) for \(v_0\le \hat{v}_0\); selling to S is best if \({\hat{\alpha }}_S^1\le \alpha _S\le {\hat{\alpha }}_S^2\); otherwise, selling to S and BS is best.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ran, Y., Zeng, Y., Dong, Y. et al. Optimizing pricing and ordering strategies for new products in the presence of consumers with pre-purchase beliefs. Ann Oper Res 337, 313–342 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-024-05894-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-024-05894-w

Keywords

Navigation