Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Sustainable farming practices adoption in agriculture supply chain: the role of indirect support versus cost subsidy

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Due to the growing environmental concerns and associated health issues of using fertilisers and pesticides in agriculture, Zero Budget Natural Farming (ZNBF) is gaining traction to guide farmers toward sustainable farming practices. Therefore, to promote sustainability and also to safeguard the interests of small farmers who adopt ZNBF, the government in developing economies are adopting two prevalent intervention mechanisms: (i) cost subsidy and (ii) indirect support. However, little has been done to provide clear-cut directives on when to employ these intervention mechanisms, especially in the presence of heterogeneous farmers and yield uncertainty. Therefore, in this paper, we consider a supply chain comprising a government, small farmers, and consumers, and we perform a comparative analysis to understand the prevailing conditions under which a particular policy outperforms another in maximizing social welfare by promoting ZBNF practices. We develop a government-farmer game-theoretic model wherein the government first selects the intervening mechanism to maximise social welfare, followed by farmers’ sowing decisions. Our analysis reveals that both policies positively impact the adoption of ZBNF practices; however, in the scenario of higher environmental damage, cost subsidy outperforms the indirect support mechanism. On the contrary, for medium and lower environmental damage, the choice of intervention depends on the proportion of environmentally conscious farmers. Specifically, the government should extend indirect support only if there exists a critical mass of environmentally conscious farmers. Our findings from analytical and numerical analysis assist the government in identifying and designing the appropriate intervention mechanisms whereas to farmers in their showing decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. https://www.mckinsey.com/industries/agriculture/our-insights/winning-in-africas-agricultural-market.

  2. According to FAO 2022, consumption of nitrogen-based fertilisers has increased from 1.55 kg/Hectare in 1961 to 111.41 kg/Hectare in 2019.

  3. https://pib.gov.in/FactsheetDetails.aspx?Id=148598.

  4. https://indiaclimatedialogue.net/2018/12/24/traditional-tribal-farming-shows-way-climate-smart-agriculture-2.

  5. According to the Hindu Bureau, the biggest challenge of adopting is the presence of yield uncertainty in the output. https://www.thehindu.com/sci-tech/agriculture/what-is-zero-budget-naturalfarming/article61590716.ece.

  6. Bharatiya Prakritik Krishi Paddhati (BPKP) was launched by the central government of India as a sub-scheme of the Paramparagat Krishi Vikas Yojana (PKVY) in 2020-21 to promote indigenous methods such as Natural Farming.

  7. In the Banswara district of Rajasthan, 7213 farmers were taught the various components of Zero Budget Natural Farming (ZBNF) at the gram panchayat level (Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare, 2021a).

  8. The state government of Karnataka has commenced ZBNF implementation on a pilot basis in ten Agro Climatic Zones through the different State Agriculture Universities as demonstrations/experimental scientific trials in farmer’s fields.

  9. Vernacular term for Farm Science Centre.

  10. Karnataka has adopted ZBNF in 2000 hectares through the State Agriculture/Horticulture Universities as demonstrations/scientific experimental trials in farmer’s fields, also Karnataka Rajya Raitha Sangha (KRRS), a farmer’s group, holds seminars and training camps to train farmers in ZBNF practices.

  11. https://pib.gov.in/FactsheetDetails.aspx?Id=148598.

  12. According to The Central government’s System of Air Quality and Weather Forecasting Research, the share of stubble burning in the States of north India that contributes to Delhi’s pollution rose to 26 percent in 2022.

References

  • Akkaya, D., Bimpikis, K., & Lee, H. (2021). Government interventions to promote agricultural innovation. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 23(2), 437–452.

    Google Scholar 

  • Albornoz, V. M., Véliz, M. I., Ortega, R., & Ortíz-Araya, V. (2020). Integrated versus hierarchical approach for zone delineation and crop planning under uncertainty. Annals of Operations Research, 286(1), 617–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aliano Filho, A., de Oliveira Florentino, H., Pato, M. V., Poltroniere, S. C., & da Silva Costa, J. F. (2022). Exact and heuristic methods to solve a bi-objective problem of sustainable cultivation. Annals of Operations Research, 314(2), 347–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alizamir, S., Iravani, F., & Mamani, H. (2019). An analysis of price vs. revenue protection: Government subsidies in the agriculture industry. Management Science, 65(1), 32–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, Z., Ma, L., Jin, S., Ma, W., Velthof, G. L., Oenema, O., Liu, L., Chadwick, D., & Zhang, F. (2016). Nitrogen, phosphorus, and potassium flows through the manure management chain in China. Environmental science & Technology, 50(24), 13409–13418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyabatlı, O., Nasiry, J., & Zhou, Y. (2019). Crop planning in sustainable agriculture: Dynamic farmland allocation in the presence of crop rotation benefits. Management Science, 65(5), 2060–2076.

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Water Commission, Ministry of Jal Shakti, Government of India (2021). Water and related statistics. http://www.cwc.gov.in/sites/default/files/water-and-related-statistics-2021compressed-2.pdf. [Online; accessed 11-December-2022].

  • Chen, J., & Chen, Y.-J. (2021). The impact of contract farming on agricultural product supply in developing economies. Production and Operations Management, 30(8), 2395–2419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y.-J., & Tang, C. S. (2015). The economic value of market information for farmers in developing economies. Production and Operations Management, 24(9), 1441–1452.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chintapalli, P., & Tang, C. S. (2021). Crop minimum support price versus cost subsidy: farmer and consumer welfare. Production and Operations Management, 31, 1753–1769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chintapalli, P., & Tang, C. S. (2021). The implications of crop minimum support price in the presence of myopic and strategic farmers. European Journal of Operational Research, 300, 336–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chintapalli, P., & Tang, C. S. (2021). The value and cost of crop minimum support price: Farmer and consumer welfare and implementation cost. Management Science, 67(11), 6839–6861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. C., Lobel, R., & Perakis, G. (2016). The impact of demand uncertainty on consumer subsidies for green technology adoption. Management Science, 62(5), 1235–1258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawande, M., Gavirneni, S., Mehrotra, M., & Mookerjee, V. (2013). Efficient distribution of water between head-reach and tail-end farms in developing countries. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 15(2), 221–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Zegher, J. F., Iancu, D. A., & Lee, H. L. (2019). Designing contracts and sourcing channels to create shared value. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 21(2), 271–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Department of agriculture and farmers welfare, Government of India (2021). Benefits of natural farming. https://ncof.dacnet.nic.in/BenefitsNaturalFarming. [Online; accessed 08-January-2023].

  • Dionne, K. Y., & Horowitz, J. (2016). The political effects of agricultural subsidies in Africa: Evidence from Malawi. World Development, 87, 215–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, S., Gulati, A., & Thorat, S. (2008). Investment, subsidies, and pro-poor growth in rural India. Agricultural Economics, 39(2), 163–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gopinath, K., Amrutsagar, V. M., Patel, N. I., Venkatesh, G., Visha, K., Bikram, B., Rai, A. P., Bhatt, S. N., Nataraja, K. C., Rajkumar, B., Abdul, R., & Singh, V. K. (2022). Potential of organic farming in rainfed areas of India. Indian Farming, 72(8), 59–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guda, H., Dawande, M., Janakiraman, G., & Rajapakshe, T. (2021). An economic analysis of agricultural support prices in developing economies. Production and Operations Management, 30, 3036–3053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gulati, A., Kapur, D., & Bouton, M. M. (2020). Reforming Indian agriculture. Economic and Political Weekly, 55(11), 35–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, X., Cheng, L., & Yu, Y. (2022). Government subsidy policy for green and efficient raw materials considering farmer heterogeneity. Production and Operations Management, 31, 4095–4112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huh, W. T., & Lall, U. (2013). Optimal crop choice, irrigation allocation, and the impact of contract farming. Production and Operations Management, 22(5), 1126–1143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ju, X. T., Kou, C. L., Christie, P., Dou, Z., & Zhang, F. (2007). Changes in the soil environment from excessive application of fertilizers and manures to two contrasting intensive cropping systems on the north china plain. Environmental Pollution, 145(2), 497–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korav, S., Dhaka, A., Chaudhary, A., & Mamatha, Y. S. (2020). Zero budget natural farming a key to sustainable agriculture: Challenges, opportunities and policy intervention. Indian Journal of Pure & Applied Bioscience, 8(3), 285–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liao, C.-N., & Chen, Y.-J. (2017). Farmers’ information management in developing countries-a highly asymmetric information structure. Production and Operations Management, 26(6), 1207–1220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liao, C.-N., Chen, Y.-J., & Tang, C. S. (2019). Information provision policies for improving farmer welfare in developing countries: Heterogeneous farmers and market selection. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 21(2), 254–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare (2021a). Zero budget farming. https://pib.gov.in/PressReleasePage.aspx?PRID=1778901. [Online; accessed 08-January-2023].

  • Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare (2021b). Zero budget natural farming. https://pib.gov.in/FactsheetDetails.aspx?Id=148598. [Online; accessed 30-November-2022].

  • Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare (2022). Icar has constituted a committee for developing syllabus and curricula of natural farming at under graduate and post graduate level. https://pib.gov.in/PressReleasePage.aspx?PRID=1795460. [Online; accessed 08-January-2023].

  • NITI-Aayog (2021). Workforce changes and employment. https://www.niti.gov.in/sites/default/files/2022-04/Discussion_Paper_on_Workforce_05042022.pdf. [Online; accessed 19-December-2022].

  • Perlman, Y., Ozinci, Y., & Westrich, S. (2022). Pricing decisions in a dual supply chain of organic and conventional agricultural products. Annals of Operations Research, 314(2), 601–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rădulescu, M., Rădulescu, C. Z., & Zbăganu, G. (2014). A portfolio theory approach to crop planning under environmental constraints. Annals of Operations Research, 219(1), 243–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tang, C. S., Wang, Y., & Zhao, M. (2015). The implications of utilizing market information and adopting agricultural advice for farmers in developing economies. Production and operations management, 24(8), 1197–1215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venkateswarlu, B., Balloli, S., Ramakrishna, Y., et al. (2008). Organic farming in rainfed agriculture: Opportunities and constraints (p. 185). Hyderabad: Central Research Institute for Dryland Agriculture.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xiao, S., Chen, Y.-J., & Tang, C. S. (2020). Knowledge sharing and learning among smallholders in developing economies: Implications, incentives, and reward mechanisms. Operations Research, 68(2), 435–452.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ye, F., Cai, Z., Chen, Y.-J., Li, Y., & Hou, G. (2021). Subsidize farmers or bioenergy producer? The design of a government subsidy program for a bioenergy supply chain. Naval Research Logistics (NRL), 68(8), 1082–1097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, Z., Wang, Y., & Chen, Y.-J. (2021). Financing an agricultural supply chain with a capital-constrained smallholder farmer in developing economies. Production and Operations Management, 30(7), 2102–2121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, J. J., Tang, C. S., & Shen, Z.-J.M. (2018). Improving consumer welfare and manufacturer profit via government subsidy programs: Subsidizing consumers or manufacturers? Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 20(4), 752–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, J., Fan, X., Chen, Y.-J., & Tang, C. S. (2021). Information provision and farmer welfare in developing economies. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 23(1), 230–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Suresh Kumar Jakhar.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

All authors have no conflict of interest to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 2 Using the incentive compatibility constraints of two types of farmers: environmentally conscious and neutral, we first prove that each farmer will cultivate either of the two crops, 1 or 2 in equilibrium. This proof is by contradiction. Let us assume a farmer of type \(k\in \{E, N\}\) located at \(x<\tau _k\) allocates \(\beta \) proportion of her capacity to crop 2 and \(1-\beta \) to crop 1. However, by the definition of \(\tau _k\) given by Eq. (9), it is clear that all farmers at \(x<\tau _k\) perceive higher utility by sowing crop 2 as compared to crop 1. Hence, by incentive compatibility, these farmers will allocate \(\beta = 1\), implying that they will sow only one type of crop in equilibrium, which is crop 2. Similarly, we can prove that a farmer of type \(k\in \{E, N\}\) located at \(x>\tau _k\) will sow one and only one crop in equilibrium, which is crop 1. Additionally, without loss of generality, we can assume that a farmer of type \(k\in \{E, N\}\) located at \(x=\tau _k\), who is indifferent between crop 1 and 2, sows crop 2 in equilibrium.

Next, we obtain the fraction of farmers who sow crop 2 and crop 1 in equilibrium. Using the rational expectation equilibrium concept, each farmer believes ex-ante that \(\phi \) fraction of farmers will grow crop 2 and \(1-\phi \) fraction of farmers will grow crop 1 in equilibrium. Accordingly, we can get the fraction of farmers growing crop 2 in equilibrium by solving the fixed point equation given by Eq. (10). Substituting the obtained fraction of farmers who sows crop 2 in equilibrium in Eq. (9), we get the expressions for \(\tau _k\).

Proof of Lemma 1 To ensure \(\tau _k\) \(\in \) \([-1, 1]\), the following two inequalities have to be satisfied: (a) \(\tau _E \le 1\) and (b) \(\tau _N \ge -1\). Simplifying these conditions, we get \(-1+d\cdot \beta \le \tau _E \le 1\). Accordingly, for condition (b) to hold, i.e., \(\tau _N \ge -1\) \(\implies \) \(\tau _E \ge -1+d\cdot \beta \). Using the equilibrium \(\tau _E\) from Eq. (11), we can easily get \(a>\frac{d\alpha (1+y^2+\frac{\theta ^2}{3})}{2(\gamma y-1)}-\frac{2}{(\gamma y-1)}\equiv a_1\). And to satisfy condition (a), i.e., \(\tau _E \le 1\) \(\implies \) \(a>\frac{\alpha (1+y^2+\frac{\theta ^2}{3})}{(\gamma y-1)}-\frac{2}{(\gamma y-1)}\equiv a_2\). Therefore, if \(a>min\{a_1,a_2\}\), then \(\tau _k\) \(\in \) \([-1, 1]\).

Proof of Lemma 3 Differentiating the aggregate threshold of the location of a farmer, \(\tau \), with respect to the different parameter values, we get the desired result.

  1. 1.

    \(\frac{d\tau }{d\theta } = -\frac{12 \theta (2 + d \alpha \beta +a (y \gamma -1))}{(9 + 3 y^2 +\theta ^2)^2)}<0\).

  2. 2.

    \(\frac{d\tau }{dd} = \frac{6\alpha \beta }{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}>0\) and \(\frac{d\tau }{d\gamma } = \frac{6ay}{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}>0\).

  3. 3.

    \(\frac{d\tau }{dy} = \frac{6 (6 y (-2 + a - d\alpha \beta ) - 3 a y^2 \gamma + a \gamma (9 + \theta ^2))}{(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)^2}\), which is positive if

    \(y<\frac{-12 + 6 a - 6 d \alpha \beta + \sqrt{36 (2 - a + d \alpha \beta )^2 + 12 a^2 \gamma ^2 (9 + \theta ^2)}}{6a\gamma }\equiv \tilde{y}\) and negative otherwise.

  4. 4.

    \(\frac{d\tau }{d\beta } = \frac{6d\alpha }{9+3y^2+\theta ^2} >0\).

  5. 5.

    \(\frac{d\tau _E}{d\alpha } = -d\beta \left( 1-\frac{6}{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}\right) <0\) and \(\frac{d\tau _N}{d\alpha } = -d\beta \left( 1-\frac{6}{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}\right) <0\) .

  6. 6.

    \(\frac{d\tau }{d\alpha } = \frac{6d\beta }{9+3y^2+\theta ^2} >0\).

Proof of Proposition 1: The total social welfare under the benchmark case is:

$$\begin{aligned} TSW_{Benchmark} = \frac{\begin{matrix}-2 + 4 a - 4 c - 4 d - 4 d \alpha \beta + d^2 \alpha \beta ^2 -d^2 \alpha ^2 \beta ^2 &{}\\ + \frac{6 (2 + d \alpha \beta + a (-1 + y\gamma )) (2 + d (2 + \alpha \beta ) + a (-1 + y \gamma ))}{{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}}\end{matrix}}{4} \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating with respect to \(\theta \), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dTSW_{Benchmark}}{d\theta } = - \frac{3 (2 + d \alpha \beta + a (-1 + y \gamma )) (2 + d (2 + \alpha \beta ) + a (-1 + y \gamma )) \theta }{(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)^2}<0. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Theorem 1 It is easy to verify that the government objective is concave in the decision variable s, i.e., \(\frac{d^2TSW_{SD}}{ds^2} =-\frac{3}{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}<0\). Hence, the optimal subsidy can be obtained by equating \(\frac{dTSW_{SD}}{ds}=0\), when solved for s, we get the optimal subsidy as \(min\{d,\bar{s}\}\), where \(\bar{s}\) is obtained from the constraint of the government problem and is given in Theorem 1.

Proof of Proposition 2 Differentiating the optimal subsidy, \(s^*\), with respect to the different parameter values, we get the desired result.

  1. 1.

    \(\frac{ds^*}{dd}=1>0\). Hence, as the environmental damage increases, the government increases the subsidy and should stop at \(\tilde{d}\) to ensure both crops are grown in equilibrium, where \(\tilde{d}=\frac{6(1+y^2+\frac{\theta ^2}{3}-a(\gamma y-1))}{6+3\beta (3+y^2(1-\alpha )-\alpha )+\beta \theta ^2(1-\alpha )}\).

  2. 2.

    \(\frac{ds^*}{d\theta }=\frac{(2-d(1-\alpha )\beta ) \theta }{2}>0\).

  3. 3.

    \(\frac{ds^*}{d\alpha }= \frac{d\beta (1+y^2+\frac{\theta ^2}{3})}{2}>0\).

  4. 4.

    \(\frac{ds^*}{d\beta }= -\frac{3 d (3 + y^2 (1 - \alpha ) - \alpha ) + d (1 - \alpha ) \theta ^2}{6}<0\).

  5. 5.

    \(\frac{ds^*}{d\gamma }= -ay<0\).

Proof of Corollary 1 It is easy to verify that \(\tau _E\) and \(\tau _N\) are interior points, i.e., \(\in \) \([-1, 1]\). And also, the difference between \(\tau _E\) and \(\tau _N\) is \(d\beta \), which is positive. Hence, the aggregate threshold of the location of a farmer, \(\tau \) \(\in \) \([-1, 1]\) as it is a convex combination of \(\tau _E\) and \(\tau _N\). Therefore, there exists a few farmers located beyond the threshold who grows crop 1 in equilibrium despite the presence of subsidies in crop 2.

Proof of Proposition 3 The total social welfare under the benchmark case is:

$$\begin{aligned} TSW_{Benchmark} = \frac{\begin{matrix}-2+4a-4c-4d-4d\alpha \beta + d^2\alpha \beta ^2-d^2\alpha ^2 \beta ^2&{}\\ +\frac{6(2+d\alpha \beta +a(-1+y\gamma ))\cdot (2+d(2+\alpha \beta )+a(-1+y \gamma ))}{{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}}\end{matrix}}{4} \end{aligned}$$

The total social welfare under the SD policy is:

$$\begin{aligned} TSW_{SD}=\frac{\begin{matrix}-2+4a-4c-4d-4d\alpha \beta + d^2\alpha \beta ^2-d^2\alpha ^2\beta ^2 &{}\\ +\frac{6 (2+d +d\alpha \beta +a(-1+y\gamma ))^2}{{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}}\end{matrix}}{4} \end{aligned}$$

Subtracting these two, we get

$$\begin{aligned} TSW_{SD}-TSW_{Benchmark}=\frac{3d^2}{2(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)}>0 \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition 4: We first calculate the total social under each intervention, followed by subtracting each other to compare the performance of the two interventions.

$$\begin{aligned} TSW_{SD}&= \frac{-2 + 4 a - 4 c - 4 d - 4 d \alpha \beta + d^2 \alpha \beta ^2 -d^2 \alpha ^2 \beta ^2+\frac{6 (2+d + d \alpha \beta + a (-1 + y\gamma ))^2}{{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}}}{4}\\ TSW_{IS}&= \frac{\begin{matrix}-2+4a-4c-4d-4d\alpha \beta + d^2\alpha \beta ^2-d^2\alpha ^2 \beta ^2&{}\\ +\frac{6(2+d\alpha \beta +a(-1+y\gamma ))\cdot (2-2g+d(2+\alpha \beta )+a(-1+y \gamma ))}{{9+3y^2+\delta ^2\theta ^2}}\end{matrix}}{4} \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\Delta TSW = TSW_{IS}-TSW_{SD}\), we get

\(\Delta TSW = \frac{\frac{6(2+d\alpha \beta +a(-1+y\gamma ))\cdot (2-2g+d(2+\alpha \beta )+a(-1+y \gamma ))}{9+3y^2+\delta ^2\theta ^2}-\frac{6 (2+d + d \alpha \beta + a (-1 + y\gamma ))^2}{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}}{4}\)

In case \(\Delta TSW\) is positive, indirect support would yield a higher total social welfare as compared to the subsidy. Hence to find the conditions under which IS policy performs better, we solve \(\Delta TSW(g) = 0\). After solving this, we observe that \(\Delta TSW\) is positive if \(g<F(\alpha )\), negative otherwise. This implies that if \(g<F(\alpha )\) holds, then total social welfare in case of indirect support exceeds that of subsidy otherwise, total social welfare in case of subsidy is more than that of indirect support, where \(F(\alpha )\) is given below.

\(F(\alpha )\!=\!\frac{2d(1+\alpha \beta )(2+a(-1+y\gamma ))(1 -\delta ^2)\theta ^2+(2+a(-1 + y \gamma ))^2(1-\delta ^2) \theta ^2 - d^2(9+3y^2+(-\alpha \beta (2+\alpha \beta )+(\delta + \alpha \beta \delta )^2) \theta ^2)}{2(2+d\alpha \beta +a(-1+y\gamma ))(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)}.\)

Next, we identify the necessary conditions under which \(g<F(\alpha )\) holds. It is easy to verify that \(F(\alpha )\) is a continuous monotonously increasing function in \(\alpha \), which can be proved by the construction technique. We plot \(\frac{dF(\alpha )}{d\alpha }\) over the entire range of \(\alpha \) and we find the derivate to be positive for all \(\alpha \in [0,1]\). This suggests \(F(\alpha )\) is a monotonously increasing function in \(\alpha \). Therefore, the maximum and minimum value is obtained at \(F(\alpha =1)\) and \(F(\alpha =0)\), respectively. For further analysis, we take \(F(\alpha =1)=\bar{g}\) and \(F(\alpha =0)=\underline{g}\) and consider three cases.

  1. 1.

    When \(0<d<\frac{(2+a(-1+y\gamma ))(1-\delta ^2)\theta ^2 - \sqrt{(2+a(-1+y\gamma ))^2(1-\delta ^2)\theta ^2(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)}}{9+3y^2+\delta ^2\theta ^2}\equiv d_1\).

    Under the above condition, \(F(\alpha =0)>0\). Hence the for all \(\alpha \in [0, 1]\) \(F(\alpha =0)>0\). However, the LHS of \(g>F(\alpha )\) is a constant term and if we closely look at the administration costs g, it can take three cases:

    1. (a)

      If \(g>\bar{g}\), then g is always greater than \(F(\alpha )\), Hence \(\Delta TSW < 0\), implying \(TSW_{SD}>TSW_{IS}\).

    2. (b)

      If \(\underline{g}\le g \le \bar{g}\), then according to intermediate value theorem there exists a \(\tilde{\alpha } \in [0, 1]\) such that if \(\alpha >\tilde{\alpha }\) then \(g<F(\alpha )\) implying \(\Delta TSW > 0\), hence \(TSW_{SD}<TSW_{IS}\). On the contrary, if \(\alpha <\tilde{\alpha }\) then \(g>F(\alpha )\) implying \(\Delta TSW < 0\), hence \(TSW_{SD}>TSW_{IS}\).

    3. (c)

      If \(0<g<\underline{g}\), then g will always be lower than \(F(\alpha )\), implying \(\Delta TSW > 0\), hence \(TSW_{SD}<TSW_{IS}\) for all \(\alpha \in [0,1]\).

  2. (2.)

    When \(d_1\le d\le \frac{(-2+a-ay\gamma )\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\theta }{(1+\beta )\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\theta -\sqrt{9+3y^2+\theta ^2}} \equiv d_2\). Under the above condition, \(F(\alpha =0)<o\), however, \(F(\alpha =1)>o\). Hence there exist two cases:

    1. (a)

      If \(g>\bar{g}\), then g is always greater than \(F(\alpha )\), implying \(TSW_{SD}>TSW_{IS}\).

    2. (b)

      If \(0<g<\bar{g}\), then according to intermediate value theorem there exists a \(\tilde{\alpha } \in [0, 1]\) such that if \(\alpha >\tilde{\alpha }\) then \(g<F(\alpha )\) implying \(TSW_{SD}<TSW_{IS}\). On the contrary, if \(\alpha <\tilde{\alpha }\) then \(g>F(\alpha )\) implying \(TSW_{SD}>TSW_{IS}\).

  3. 3.

    When \(d>d_2\). Under the above condition, \(F(\alpha =1)<o\). Hence the entire range is negative, implying \(g>F(\alpha ) \implies TSW_{SD}>TSW_{IS}\).

Proof of Proposition 5: Similar to Proposition 4, we compare the performance of two intervention mechanisms using \(\delta \) as a parameter as compared to \(\alpha \) in Proposition 4. We find that SD generates higher social welfare only when \(g<F(\delta )\). It is easy to verify that \(F(\delta )\) is a monotonous decreasing function in \(\delta \). We used the proof by construction to show \(F(\delta )\) is a monotonous decreasing function. For further analysis, we take \(F(\delta =0)= \tilde{g}\) and consider two cases:

  1. 1.

    When \(d<\frac{(1+\alpha \beta )(2+a(-1+y\gamma ))\theta ^2+\sqrt{(2+a(-1+y\gamma ))^2 \theta ^2(9+3y^2+\theta ^2)}}{9+3y^2-\alpha \beta (2+\alpha \beta )\theta ^2}\equiv d_0\). Under this condition, we find that \(\tilde{g}>0\) and \(F(\delta =1)<0\). Hence, by using the intermediate value theorem, we can say that if \(0<g<\tilde{g}\), then there exists a \(\tilde{\delta } \in [o, 1)\) at which \(g=F(\delta )\). Accordingly, if \(\delta <\tilde{\delta }\) then \(g<F(\delta )\) will hold and otherwise for \(\delta >\tilde{\delta }\), \(g>F(\delta )\) will hold.

  2. 2.

    When \(d\ge d_0\). Under this condition, we find that \(\tilde{g}<0\), which suggests that \(F(\delta )<0\) for every \(\delta \in [0,1]\). Hence \(g>F(\delta )\) will always hold.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ray, M., Singh, A.P. & Jakhar, S.K. Sustainable farming practices adoption in agriculture supply chain: the role of indirect support versus cost subsidy. Ann Oper Res (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-023-05559-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-023-05559-0

Keywords

Navigation