Skip to main content
Log in

Pricing, coalition stability, and profit allocation in the pull assembly supply chains under competition

  • Original Article
  • Published:
OR Spectrum Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider a pull assembly supply chain consisting of an assembler and its multiple upstream component suppliers/subsidiaries, in which the former buys complementary components from these upstream component suppliers, assembles them into a final product, and sells the final product competing against another assembly firm (rival). The assembler decides the retail price competing with its rival and with the upstream component suppliers can freely decide whether or not to cooperate with another, which can eliminate horizontal and vertical inefficiencies within supply chain members. Using a stylized duopoly model, we study the optimal retail prices of the assembler and the optimal wholesale prices of these component suppliers under different alliance structures and analyze the coalition stability and profit allocation scheme via a proper transfer price for the assembly supply chain. We show that when the upstream suppliers are not allowed to form coalitions, the increase in the number of the upstream component suppliers trading with their assembler are a good thing for the two assemblers. In addition, increasing the intensity of price competition in the market induces the two assemblers to decline the retail prices and the upstream subsidiaries to cut down the wholesale prices; however, all the parties’ profits are not necessarily monotonic in this intensity. In environments in which the upstream subsidiaries can freely form coalitions, the above two results remain unchanged. We also find that the cooperation between the assembler and its upstream subsidiaries can always bring more profit and eliminate inefficiencies for the assembly supply chain. Importantly, we show that the constructed cooperative game has a non-empty core and can design a profit allocation scheme for the grand coalition based on the Shapley value. We identify the transfer prices of the assembler to the upstream subsidiaries to realize the profit allocation scheme that is fair and show that increasing the intensity of price competition can reduce the proposed Shapley values of the upstream suppliers and transfer prices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To focus on the impact of market competition on alliance stability problem in an assembly supply chain, we consider a single assembler B (rather than another assembly supply chain) as a rival of firm A. For the case of the assembler B with its upstream component supplier(s), this does not facilitate the analysis on addressing the proposed research questions. (We thank one of the reviewers for drawing our attention to this case.) Nevertheless, when the assembly business with the assembler B is considered, it is not difficult to show that the structures of its equilibrium outcomes under the setting of a single assembler B remain unchanged, and thus, the main results are still true.

  2. Yan (2010) showed that market competition always has a negative effect on the competitors’ profits.

References

  • Alles M, Datar S (1998) Strategic transfer pricing. Manage Sci 44(4):451–461

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein F, DeCroix G (2006) Inventory policies for decentralized assembly systems. Oper Res 54(2):324–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Birge JR, Drogosz J, Duenyas I (1998) Setting single-period optimal capacity levels and prices for substitutable products. Int J Flex Manuf Syst 10(4):407–430

    Google Scholar 

  • Cao X, Fang X (2019) Component procurement for an assembly supply chain with random capacities and random demand. Decis Sci 50(6):1259–1280

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen LG, Ding D, Ou J (2015) Power structure and profitability in assembly supply chains. Prod Oper Manag 23(9):1599–1616

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen RR, Rom P (2011) Group buying of competing retailers. Prod Oper Manag 20(2):181–197

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi SC (1991) Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. Mark Sci 10(4):271–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Chopra S, Meindl P (2001) Supply chain management: strategy, planning and operation. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Deng S, Gu C, Cai S, Li Y (2018) Financing multiple heterogeneous suppliers in assembly systems: Buyer finance vs. bank finance. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 20(1):53–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Erickson GM (2012) Transfer pricing in a dynamic marketing-operations interface. Eur J Oper Res 216:326–333

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang X, Ru J, Wang Y (2014) Optimal procurement design of an assembly supply chain with information asymmetry. Prod Oper Manag 23(12):2075–2088

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang X, So KC, Wang Y (2008) Component procurement strategies in decentralized assemble-to-order systems with lead time-dependent product pricing. Manage Sci 54(12):1997–2011

    Google Scholar 

  • Feng YL, Li G, Sethi SP (2018) Pull and push contracts in a decentralised assembly system with random component yields. Int J Prod Res 56(24):7405–7425

    Google Scholar 

  • Feng T, Zhang F (2014) The impact of modular assembly on supply chain efficiency. Prod Oper Manag 23(11):1985–2001

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabrielsen TS, Schjelderup G (1999) Transfer pricing and ownership structure. Scand J Econ 101(4):673–688

    Google Scholar 

  • Granot D, Yin S (2008) Competition and cooperation in decentralized push and pull assembly systems. Manage Sci 54(4):733–747

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurnani H, Gerchak Y (2007) Coordination in decentralized assembly systems with uncertain component yields. Eur J Oper Res 176(3):1559–1576

    Google Scholar 

  • Helber S, de Kok T, Kuhn H, Manitz M, Matta A, Stolletz R (2019) Quantitative approaches in production management. OR Spectr 41:867–870

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsu VN, Lee CY, So KC (2006) Optimal components stocking policy for assembly-to-order systems with lead time-dependent component and product pricing. Manage Sci 52(3):337–351

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsu VN, Xiao W, Xu J (2019) The impact of tax and transfer pricing on a multinational firm’s strategic decision of selling to a rival. Prod Oper Manag forthcoming

  • Hirshleifer J (1956) On the economics of transfer pricing. J Bus 29(3):172–184

    Google Scholar 

  • IHS (2014) iPhone 6 Plus: \$100 costlier for consumers to buyjust \$15.50 more expensive for Apple to make. Accessed January 22, 2016, https://technology.ihs.com/511475/iphone-6-plus-100 -costlier-for-consumers-to-buyjust-1550-more-expensive-for-apple -to-make

  • Investopedia (2019) Transfer pricing. Available at https://www.investopedia.com/terms/t/transfer-pricing.asp

  • Iyer VA, Schwarz BL, Zenios AS (2005) A principal-agent model for product specification and production. Manage Sci 51(1):106–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang L, Wang Y (2009) Supplier competition in decentralized assembly systems with price-sensitive and uncertain demand. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 12(1):93–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang L, Wang Y (2009b) The effect of decision sequence on supplier competition in decentralized assembly systems. Working paper, Hong Kong Polytechnic University

  • Kim B, Park KS, Jung SY, Park SH (2018) Offshoring and outsourcing in a global supply chain: impact of the arm’s length regulation on transfer pricing. Eur J Oper Res 266(1):88–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuo CW, Chen CB, Chen CL, Yang YY (2021) Formulating cross-sector horizontal coalition strategies for multi-product assembly systems with a common component. Comput Ind Eng 159:107399

    Google Scholar 

  • Lan YF, Cai XQ, Shang CJ, Zhang LM, Zhao RQ (2020) Heterogeneous suppliers’ contract design in assembly systems with asymmetric information. Eur J Oper Res 286(1):149–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Lantz B (2009) The double marginalization problem of transfer pricing: theory and experiment. Eur J Oper Res 196(2):434–439

    Google Scholar 

  • Leng M, Parlar M (2009) Allocation of cost savings in a three-level supply chain with demand information sharing: a cooperative-game approach. Oper Res 57(1):200–213

    Google Scholar 

  • Leng M, Parlar M (2010) Game-theoretic analyses of decentralized assembly supply chains: non-cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with cost-sharing contracts. Eur J Oper Res 204(1):96–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Leng M, Parlar M (2012) Transfer pricing in a multidivisional firm: a cooperative game analysis. Oper Res Lett 40(5):364–369

    Google Scholar 

  • Li L, Zhang H (2008) Confidentiality and information sharing in supply chain coordination. Manage Sci 54(8):1467–1481

    Google Scholar 

  • Li TT, Chen J (2020) Alliance formation in assembly systems with quality-improvement incentives. Eur J Oper Res 285:931–940

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu SS, Papageorgiou LG (2018) Fair profit distribution in multi-echelon supply chains via transfer prices. Omega 80:77–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu SX, So KC, Zhao WH (2022) Direct supply base reduction in a decentralized assembly system with suppliers of varying market power. IISE Trans 54(6):590–602

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu Z, Zheng XX, Li DF, Liao CN, Sheu JB (2021) A novel cooperative game-based method to coordinate a sustainable supply chain under psychological uncertainty in fairness concerns. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 147:102237

    Google Scholar 

  • Lv F, Xiao L, Xu MH, Guan X (2019) Quantity-payment versus two-part tariff contracts in an assembly system with asymmetric cost information. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 129:60–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsui K (2012) Cost-based transfer pricing under R &D risk aversion in an integrated supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 139(1):69–79

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire TW, Staelin R (1983) An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Mark Sci 2(2):161–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R (1991) Game theory: analysis of conflict. Harvard University Press, Harvard

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan M, Bassok Y (2008) A bargaining framework in supply chains. Manage Sci 54(8):1482–1496

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan M, Sošić G (2009) Coalition stability in assembly models. Oper Res 57(1):131–145

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan M, Sošić G, Tong CY (2019) Coalition stability in assembly models. Oper Res 67(5):1269–1282

    Google Scholar 

  • Netessine S, Zhang F (2005) Positive vs. negative externalities in inventory management: implications for supply chain design. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 7(1):58–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Niu B, Liu Y, Liu F, Lee CK (2019) Transfer pricing and channel structure of a multinational firm under overseas retail disruption risk. Int J Prod Res 57(9):2901–2925

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2010) Review of comparability and of profit methods: revision of chapters I-III of the transfer pricing guidelines. https://www.oecd.org/ctp/transfer-pricing/45763692.pdf

  • Oner N, Kuyzu G (2021) Core stable coalition selection in collaborative truckload transportation procurement. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 154:102447

    Google Scholar 

  • Raju JS, Sethuraman R, Dhar SK (1995) The introduction and performance of store brands. Manage Sci 41(6):957–978

    Google Scholar 

  • Rau P, Spinler S (2017) Alliance formation in a cooperative container shipping game: performance of a real options investment approach. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 101:155–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal EC (2008) A game theoretic approach to transfer pricing in a vertically integrated supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 15(2):542–552

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1953) A value for \(n-\)person games. Ann Math Stud 28:307–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Shunko M, Debo L, Gavirneni S (2014) Transfer pricing and sourcing strategies for multinational firms. Prod Oper Manag 23(12):2043–2057

    Google Scholar 

  • Simchi-Levi D, Kaminsky P, Simchi-Levi E (2008) Designing and managing the supply chain: concepts, strategies, and case studies. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simchi-Levi D, Chen X, Bramel J (2014) The logic of logistics: theory, algorithms, and applications for logistics management, 3rd edn. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sošić G (2011) Impact of demand uncertainty on stability of supplier alliances in assembly models. Prod Oper Manag 20(6):905–920

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian L, Vakharia AJ, Tan Y, Xu YF (2018) Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid: strategic analysis of an emerging E-commerce model. Prod Oper Manag 27(8):1595–1610

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsay AA, Agrawal N (2000) Channel dynamics under price and service competition. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 2(4):372–391

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behaviour. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y, Gerchak Y (2003) Capacity games in decentralized assembly systems with random demand. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 5(3):1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y (2006) Joint pricing-production decisions in supply chains of complementary products with uncertain demand. Oper Res 54(6):1110–1127

    Google Scholar 

  • Wensing T, Kuhn H (2013) Analysis of a multi-component periodic review inventory system in an assembly environment. OR Spectrum 35:107–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Xia Y, Gilbert SM (2007) Strategic interactions between channel structure and demand enhancing services. Eur J Oper Res 181(1):252–265

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan R (2010) Product brand differentiation and dual-channel store performances of a multi-channel retailer. Eur J Mark 44(5):672–692

    Google Scholar 

  • Yin S (2010) Alliance formation among perfectly complementary suppliers in a price-sensitive assembly system. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 12(3):527–544

    Google Scholar 

  • Yin Z, Guan X, Xiao L (2017) Managing global sourcing with disruption risks in an assemble-to-order system. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 108:1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Yin Z, Wang C, Yin Q (2018) Coordinating overseas and local sourcing through a capacitated expediting transportation policy. Transp Res Part E Logist Transp Rev 118:258–271

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors appreciate the Editor and the two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Numbers 72071082, 71901096, 72074082), the Key Program of Natural Science Foundation of Universities of Anhui Province (Grant Number KJ2020A0044), the Social Science Foundation Project of Anhui Province (Grant Number AHSKY2018D22), and Institute for Enterprise Development, Jinan University, Guangdong Province (No. 22JNS04).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bin Cao.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Technical proofs

Appendix: Technical proofs

Proof of Proposition 1

According to the arguments in Sect. 4.1, it is easy to show that

$$\begin{aligned}\frac{d p_A^{NC*}}{d \theta }=a(1+2n)\frac{-4(n+1)-(8n+12)\theta -(6n+9)\theta ^2}{\big ((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)\big )^2}<0,\end{aligned}$$

and \(\frac{d p_B^{NC*}}{d \theta }=a\frac{-4(n+1)-(8n+12)(n+1)\theta -(2n+3)(4n+3)\theta ^2}{\big ((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)\big )^2}<0.\) Thus, for \(l=A,B\), it directly follows that \(\frac{d q_l^{NC*}}{d \theta }>0\), and \(\frac{d w_A^{*}}{d \theta }=(1+2n)\frac{d p_A^{NC*}}{d \theta }<0\). Hence, the first part is proved.

We then show the second part. Note that for \(i=1,2,...,n\), we have \(\pi _A^{0*}=(1+n)\pi _A^{i*}\). Thus, we just need to prove the impact of \(\theta\) on \(\pi _A^{0*}\) and \(\pi _B^{0*}\). By taking the first-order derivative of \(\pi _A^{0*}\) with respect to \(\theta\) and after some manipulations, we have \(\frac{d \pi _A^{0*}}{d \theta }=-\theta (\theta -\theta _1(n))(\theta +\theta _1(n)),\) where \(\theta _1(n)=\frac{-6+2\sqrt{9+3(n-1)(2n+3)}}{3(2n+3)}\). Clearly, \(\pi _A^{0*}\) is a quasi-concave function of \(\theta\); that is, if \(\theta <\theta _1(n)\), \(\pi _A^{0*}\) increases with \(\theta\), and otherwise, \(\pi _A^{0*}\) decreases with \(\theta\). Similarly, it is also not difficult to derive that \(\pi _B^{0*}\) is a quasi-concave function of \(\theta\), which means that there exists a threshold value \(\theta _2(n)(=\frac{4n^2-10n-12+4\sqrt{100n^4+268n^3+247n^2+87n+9}}{3(8n^2+18n+9)})\) such that, if \(\theta <\theta _2(n)\), \(\pi _B^{0*}\) increases with \(\theta\), and otherwise, \(\pi _B^{0*}\) decreases with \(\theta\). Then, we complete the proof of Proposition 1. \(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 1

From the definitions of these two thresholds in Proposition 1, it is trivial to prove this corollary and we omit the details. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

Similarly with the proof of Proposition 1, it is not difficult to prove the first and second parts of Proposition 2. For the third part of this proposition, it is clear that \(w_{Z_i}^{(N,k)*}\), \(q_{A}^{(N,k)*}\) and \(\pi _{Z_i}^{(N,k)*}\) are strictly decreasing in k. Taking the first-order derivative of \(p_l^{(N,k)*}(l=A,B)\) with respect to k yields, \(\frac{d p_A^{(N,k)*}}{d k}=\frac{a(2+3\theta )(2\theta ^2+8\theta +4)}{\big ((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)\big )^2}>0\) and \(\frac{d p_B^{(N,k)*}}{d k}=\frac{a\theta (2\theta ^2+10\theta +6)}{\big ((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)\big )^2}>0.\) It directly follows that \(\frac{d q_B^{(N,k)*}}{d k},~\frac{d \pi _B^{(N,k)*}}{d k}>0\). Similarly, it is easy to show that \(\frac{d \pi _B^{(N,k)*}}{d k}<0\). Then, the proof is completed. \(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 2

From Proposition 2, we know that as the number of upstream-subsidiary alliance k increases, \(p_{l}^{(N,k)*}\) and \(\pi _{B}^{(N,k)*}\) increase, but \(\pi _{Z_i}^{(N,k)*}\) and \(\pi _{0}^{(N,k)*}\) decrease. Note that when \(k=n\), this case is in fact the same as the one-player coalition case. Consequently, when \(k<n\), we can derive the first part of Corollary 2. For the second part, it is not difficult to prove it according to the definitions of \(\theta _A^{(N,k)}\) and \(\theta _B^{(N,k)}\) in Proposition 2, and we omit the details of the proof. \(\square\)

Proofs of Proposition 3 and Corollary 3

With the proofs of Proposition 2 and Corollary 2, we can similarly prove the results in Proposition 3 and Corollary 3, and the fact that \(\theta _l^{(N_0,k)}=\theta _l^{(N,t)}\big |_{t=k-1}\) where \(\theta _l^{(N,t)}\) defined in Proposition 2. \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 1

From Proposition 1, we known that for a given one-subsidiary coalition \(\big \{j\big \}\), the profit of each coalition \(\big \{j\big \}\) decreases with the number of subsidiaries in the coalition that all the other subsidiaries form. Therefore, all the other subsidiaries’ strategies affect the profit of the coalition \(\big \{j\big \}\). However, Proposition 1 also shows that the coalition \(\big \{j\big \}\) can achieve at least its profit in the case of a single-player alliance. Then, according to the definitions of the characteristic values of coalitions and the arguments in Sect. 4.1, it directly follows that

$$\begin{aligned}v(0)=\pi _A^{0*}=\frac{1+n}{1+\theta }\Big [\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)}\Big ]^2,\end{aligned}$$

and for \(i=1, 2, ..., n\), \(v(i)=\pi _A^{i*}=\frac{1}{1+\theta }\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)}\Big )^2\). \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 2

Note that for any \(r\in (r=2,3, ..., n+1)\) and any \(\mathbb {C}_r\subseteq N_0\), there are two possible situations, that is, \(0\in \mathbb {C}_r\) and \(0\notin \mathbb {C}_r\). Then we divide the analysis into two cases above.

Case 1: \(0\in \mathbb {C}_r\). In this case, the given coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\) contains firm A; and thus, there are only \((n-r+1)\) upstream subsidiaries of firm A not belonging to the coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\). Clearly, the number of the upstream subsidiaries of firm A forming the alliance is at most \((n-r+2)\). From Proposition 3, it follows that the profit of coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\) decreases with the number of these possible coalitions. As a result, the profit that this coalition can be guaranteed to achieve is at least equal to the one that it can get when there are \((n-r+2)\) coalitions. Therefore, according to the definitions of the characteristic values of the coalitions and the results argued in Sect. 4.3, we have

$$\begin{aligned} v(\mathbb {C}_r)=\frac{n-r+2}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}\Big ]^2. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Case 2: \(0\notin \mathbb {C}_r\). This means that firm A is not in the coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\). In this regard, there are \((n-r)\) subsidiaries of firm A not belonging to the coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\). It directly follows that the number of the coalitions of firm A forming an alliance is at most \((n-r+1)\). Following Proposition 2, which shows that the profit of coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\) decreases with the number of possible coalitions, we get that the profit that the coalition \(\mathbb {C}_r\) is guaranteed to achieve is at least equal to the one that it can achieve when there are \((n-r+1)\) coalitions. Similar to the previous part, combining the definitions of the characteristic values of coalitions and the analysis in Sect. 4.2, we have

$$\begin{aligned} v(\mathbb {C}_r)=\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}\Big ]^2. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Hence, we complete the proof. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4

According to Theorem 2, (1) when \(0\in \mathbb {C}_r\), by taking the first-order derivative of \(v(\mathbb {C}_r)\) in Eq. (9), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d v(\mathbb {C}_r)}{d r}=\frac{a^2(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)^2}{1+\theta }\cdot \frac{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}{\left( (2n-2r+5)^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)\right) ^3}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(r\le n,\) \(\frac{d v(\mathbb {C}_r)}{d r}>0\). This means that in this case, \(v(\mathbb {C}_r)\) is an increasing function of r.

(2) When \(0\notin \mathbb {C}_r\), it is easy to show that \(g(n-r+1)\) is a decreasing function of r, where \(g(n)=(2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)\). It directly follows that \(v(\mathbb {C}_r)\) in Eq. (10), which can be written as \(\frac{a^2(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)^2}{1+\theta }\cdot \frac{1}{(g(n-r+1))^2}\) is an increasing function of r. Therefore, the characteristic value \(v(\mathbb {C}_r)\) increases with r, that is, the cooperative game \((N_0,v)\) is strictly increasing. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 5

For any coalition S, similar to the proof of Theorem 2, here we also divide the analysis into two cases, that is, \(0\in S\) and \(0\notin S\).

(1) For \(0\in S\) and \(i\in \{1, 2, ..., n\}\), suppose the size of coalition S is \(|S|=r\), then we have

$$\begin{aligned}&v\left( S\bigcup \{i\}-v(S)\right) =v(\mathbb {C}_{r+1})-v(\mathbb {C}_r)\\&\quad =\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [(n-r+1)\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+1)\theta +4(n-r+1)}\Big )^2\\&\qquad -(n-r+2)\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}\Big )^2\Big ]. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(H(r)=(1+\theta )(v(\mathbb {C}_{r+1})-v(\mathbb {C}_r))\). Thus, it is easy to show that \(\frac{d H(r)}{d r}=h(r+1)-h(r)\), where

$$\begin{aligned} h(r)=\frac{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}{\left( (2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)\right) ^3}. \end{aligned}$$

By taking the first-order derivative of h(r) with respect to r, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dh(r)}{dr}=\frac{8(\theta ^2+4\theta +2)\left( (n-r+1)\theta ^2+4(n+2-r)\theta +2(n+2-r)\right) }{\left( (2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)\right) ^4}>0, \end{aligned}$$

where the inequality holds since \(r\le n\). This further implies that \(h(r+1)-h(r)>0\). That is, \(\frac{d H(r)}{dr}>0\). Hence, if \(0\in S\), \(v(S\bigcup \{i\}-v(S))\) is an increasing function of |S|.

(2) Next, for \(0\notin S\), we have

$$\begin{aligned}&v\left( S\bigcup \{i\}-v(S)\right) =v(\mathbb {C}_{r+1})-v(\mathbb {C}_r)\\&\quad =\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+1)\theta +4(n-r+1)}\Big )^2\\&\qquad -\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}\Big )^2\Big ]. \end{aligned}$$

Similarly with the analysis in part (1), it is not difficult to show that \(v(S\bigcup \{i\}-v(S))\) is a decreasing function of |S|. \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 3

By the definition of the Shapley value in Shapley (1953) and Myerson (1991), the Shapley value of firm A in the cooperative game \((N_0, v)\) is given as

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} Y_{0}^{n}&=\sum \limits _{S\subseteq {{N}_{0}}\backslash D}{\frac{\left| S \right| !\left( \left| {{N}_{0}} \right| -\left| S \right| -1 \right) !}{\left| {{N}_{0}} \right| !}}\left( v\left( S\bigcup \{D\} \right) -v\left( S \right) \right) \\&=\sum \limits _{r=1}^{n}{C_{n}^{r}\frac{r!\cdot \left( n-r \right) !}{(n+1)!}}\left( v\left( {{\mathbb {C}}_{r}}\bigcup \{D\} \right) -v\left( {{\mathbb {C}}_{r}} \right) \right) +C_{n}^{0}\frac{0!\cdot n!}{(n+1)!}\left( v\left( D \right) -v\left( \varnothing \right) \right) \\&=\sum \limits _{r=1}^{n}{\frac{1}{n+1}}\cdot \left( v\left( {{\mathbb {C}}_{r}}\bigcup \{D\} \right) -v\left( {{\mathbb {C}}_{r}} \right) \right) +\frac{1}{n+1}v\left( D \right) \\&=\frac{1}{(1+n)(1+\theta )}\cdot \left[ \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2+\sum _{j=1}^n j \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1)}\Big )^2\right] . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Due to the symmetry of the upstream subsidiaries, the Shapley values of the upstream subsidiaries should satisfy \(Y_{1}^{n}=Y_{2}^{n}= \cdots =Y_{n}^{n}\). Since the profit of the assembly supply chain with firm A is \(v({{N}_{0}})=\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2\), the upstream subsidiaries \(U_i(i = 1,2,...,n)\) are as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&Y_{i}^{n}=\frac{v(N_0)-Y_{0}^{n}}{n} =\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \frac{1}{n(1+n)(1+\theta )}\cdot \\&\quad \left[ n\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2-\sum _{j=1}^n j \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1)}\Big )^2\right] \end{aligned}$$

for \(i=1,2,...,n\). Then, we complete the proof of this theorem. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 1

With the definition of \({{\varphi }_{1}}(r+1,n)\), we have, after some manipulations,

$$\begin{aligned}&{{\varphi }_{1}}(r+1,n)-{{\varphi }_{1}}(r,n)=Y_{i}^{n}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+1)\theta +4(n-r+1)}\Big )^2\nonumber \\&\quad -\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+5)\theta ^2+8(n-r+2)\theta +4(n-r+2)}\Big )^2\Big ]. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

From Theorem 3, it follows that the Shapley values of the upstream subsidiaries are not associated with r. Then, with the proof of the second part of Proposition 5, which can show that the second term in Eq. (12) decreases with r Thus, \({{\varphi }_{1}}(r+1,n)-{{\varphi }_{1}}(r,n)\) is an increasing function of r. On the other hand, by some manipulations on the difference of \({{\varphi }_{2}}(r+1,n)\) and \({{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n)\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&{{\varphi }_{2}}(r+1,n)-{{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n) =Y_{i}^{n}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [(n-r)\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+1)\theta ^2+8(n-r)\theta +4(n-r)}\Big )^2\\&\quad -(n-r+1)\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+1)\theta +4(n-r+1)}\Big )^2\Big ]. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Then, according to the first part of Proposition 5, which can show that the second term in Eq. (13) increases with r, it directly follows that \({{\varphi }_{2}}(r+1,n)-{{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n)\) is a decreasing function of r. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 2

We sufficiently show the proof of the first part, and the second part can be proven similarly. By the mathematical induction, we begin with showing that for \(n=2,3,...\), \({{\varphi }_{1}}(1,n)\ge 0.\) When \(n=2\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} \varphi _{1}(1,2)&{}= Y_{i}^{2}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{7\theta ^2+24\theta +12}\Big )^2\\ &{}=\frac{a^2(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)^2}{1+\theta }\cdot \frac{7936+63488\theta +206336{{\theta }^{2}}+349184{{\theta }^{3}}+328512{{\theta }^{4}}+171264{{\theta }^{5}}+47280{{\theta }^{6}}+5984{{\theta }^{7}}+209{{\theta }^{8}}}{6(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2(5\theta ^2+16\theta +8)^2(7\theta ^2+24\theta +12)^2}, \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

which is always positive. Suppose that for \(n=m\), \(\varphi _{1}(1,m)>0\). Thus, it follows that

$$\begin{aligned}\varphi _{1}(1,m)&=Y_{i}^{m}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+3) \theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1)}\Big )^2\nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{(m^2+m)(1+\theta )}\cdot \Big [m\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2\\&\quad -\sum \limits _{j=1}^{m}j\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1)}\Big )^2\Big ]\\&\quad -\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1)}\Big )^2 \ge 0, \end{aligned}$$

which is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{m}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}-\frac{m(m+1)}{((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2}\nonumber \\&\quad \ge \sum \limits _{j=1}^{m}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Next, we need to show that it holds for \(n=m+1\). To do this, when \(n=m+1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} &{}\varphi _{1}^{(1,m+1)} =Y_{i}^{m+1}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2)}\Big )^2\\ &{}\quad = \frac{1}{(1+\theta )(m+2)}\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2-\frac{1}{(m+1)(m+2)(1+\theta )}\cdot \Big (-\sum \limits _{j=1}^{m}j\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1)}\Big )^2\\ &{}\qquad -(m+1)\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2)}\Big )^2\Big )-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2)}\Big )^2\\ &{}\quad \ge \frac{1}{(1+\theta )(m+2)}\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2+\frac{m}{(m+2)(1+\theta )}\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1)}\Big )^2\\ &{}\qquad -\frac{m+3}{(m+2)(1+\theta )}\cdot \Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2)}\Big )^2\\ &{}\quad =\frac{1}{1+\theta } \frac{a^2(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)^2({{F}_{1}}{{m}^{4}}+{{F}_{2}}{{m}^{3}}+{{F}_{3}}{{m}^{2}}+{{F}_{4}}m+{{F}_{5}})}{(m+1)(m+2)(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2(2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1)^2(2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2)^2} \\ &{}\quad \ge 0, \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

where the first inequality holds because of the fact in Eq. (14), and

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} F_{1}=256+2048\theta +6656{{\theta }^{2}}+11264{{\theta }^{3}}+10624{{\theta }^{4}}+5632{{\theta }^{5}}+1664{{\theta }^{6}}+256{{\theta }^{7}}+16{{\theta }^{8}} \\{} & {} F_{2}=1280+10240\theta +33408{{\theta }^{2}}+57088{{\theta }^{3}}+54832{{\theta }^{4}}+29888{{\theta }^{5}}+9104{{\theta }^{6}}\\{} & {} \qquad +1440{{\theta }^{7}}+92{{\theta }^{8}}, \\{} & {} F_{3}=2304+18432\theta +60288{{\theta }^{2}}+103680{{\theta }^{3}}+100704{{\theta }^{4}}+55680{{\theta }^{5}}+17072{{\theta }^{6}}\\{} & {} \qquad +2656{{\theta }^{7}}+160{{\theta }^{8}}, \\{} & {} F_{4}=1536+12288\theta +40192{{\theta }^{2}}+69120{{\theta }^{3}}+67024{{\theta }^{4}}+36672{{\theta }^{5}}+10784{{\theta }^{6}}\\{} & {} \qquad +1472{{\theta }^{7}}+57{{\theta }^{8}}, \\{} & {} F_{5}=256+2048\theta +6656{{\theta }^{2}}+11264{{\theta }^{3}}+10544{{\theta }^{4}}+5312{{\theta }^{5}}+1240{{\theta }^{6}}+48{{\theta }^{7}}-18{{\theta }^{8}}. \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, for \(r=2,3,...\), and \(n=2,3,...\), we can prove that \(\varphi _1(r,n)\ge 0\).

Then we prove that for \(n=2,3,...\), \(\varphi _1(2,n)-\varphi _1(1,n)\ge 0\). For \(n=2\), on one hand, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} &{}{{\varphi }_{1}}(2,2)-{{\varphi }_{1}}(1,2)=\frac{1}{6+6\theta }\Big [\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{3\theta ^2+8\theta +4}\Big )^2-\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{5\theta ^2+16\theta +8}\Big )^2 -2\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{7\theta ^2+24\theta +12}\Big )^2\Big ]\\ &{}\qquad -\frac{1}{1+\theta }\Big [\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{5\theta ^2+16\theta +8}\Big )^2-\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{7\theta ^2+24\theta +12}\Big )^2\Big ] \\ &{}\quad =\frac{a^2(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)^2}{1+\theta }\cdot \frac{6400+51200\theta +166400{{\theta }^{2}}+2816000{{\theta }^{3}}+265152{{\theta }^{4}}+139008{{\theta }^{5}}+39312{{\theta }^{6}}+5408{{\theta }^{7}}+263{{\theta }^{8}}}{6(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2(5\theta ^2+16\theta +8)^2(7\theta ^2+24\theta +12)^2}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

It is clear that \({{\varphi }_{1}}(2,2)-{{\varphi }_{1}}(1,2)\ge 0\). On the other hand, for \(n=3, 4, ...\), we get that,

$$\begin{aligned}&{{\varphi }_{1}}(2,n)-{{\varphi }_{1}}(1,n)=Y_{i}^{n}-\frac{1}{1+\theta }\cdot \Big [\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n+1)\theta ^2+8n\theta +4n}\Big )^2\\&\quad -\Big (\frac{a(2+5\theta +3\theta ^2)}{(2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1)}\Big )^2 \Big ]. \end{aligned}$$

Note that for any given \(\theta\) and \(n=3, 4, ...\), \(\frac{1}{((2n+1)\theta ^2+8n\theta +4n)^2}-\frac{2}{((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1))^2}\le 0\). As a result, it is not difficult to show that \(\varphi _{1}(2,n)-\varphi _{1}(1,n)\ge 0\). With the results above, the proof of Lemma 2 is completed. \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 4

With the definition of the core of the game (Nv) in Eq. (5), we sufficiently need to prove that \(\sum \limits _{i\in S}{Y_{i}^{n}}\ge v(S)\), for \(\forall S\subseteq {{N}_{0}}\); that is, the individual or collective rationality holds, since the Shapley value \(Y_{i}^{n}\) satisfies the efficiency: \(\sum \limits _{i\in {{N}_{0}}}{Y_{i}^{n}}=v({{N}_{0}})\). As such, for any \(S\subseteq N_0\), there are only two possible cases, i.e., \(0\notin S\) and \(0\in S\).

Case 1: \(0\notin S\). In this case, if \(|S|=1\), by Lemma 2(i), it follows that \(\sum \limits _{i\in S}{Y_{i}^{n}}\ge v(S)\). If \(n\ge |S|>1\), then \(\sum \limits _{i\in S}{Y_{i}^{n}}\ge v(S)\) can be derived directly from Lemma 2(ii) (for the details, see the proof of Lemma 2).

Case 2: \(0\in S\). Then, if \(|S|=1\), we need to prove \(Y_{0}^{n}\ge v(\{0\})\); that is,

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{n+1}\Big (\frac{1}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}+\sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}\Big )\\&\quad \ge \frac{1+n}{((2n+3)\theta ^2+8(n+1)\theta +4(n+1))^2}, \end{aligned}$$

which can be shown by the following mathematical induction. When \(n=2\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} &{}Y_{0}^{2}-v(\{0\}) =\frac{1}{3}\Big (\frac{1}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}+\frac{1}{(5\theta ^2+16\theta +8)^2} +\frac{2}{(7\theta ^2+24\theta +12)^2}\Big )-\frac{3}{(7\theta ^2+24\theta +12)^2}\\ &{}\quad =\frac{4352+34816\theta +113152{{\theta }^{2}}+191488{{\theta }^{3}}+180096{{\theta }^{4}}+93696{{\theta }^{5}}+25632{{\theta }^{6}}+3136{{\theta }^{7}}+91{{\theta }^{8}}}{3(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2(5\theta ^2+16\theta +8)^2(7\theta ^2+24\theta +12)^2}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

Obviously, the above result holds for \(n=2\). Suppose it holds for \(n=m\), that is, assume that

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{m+1}\Big (\frac{1}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}+\sum \limits _{j=1}^{m}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}\Big )\\&\quad \ge \frac{1+m}{((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Then when \(n=m+1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{m+2}\Big (\frac{1}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}+\sum \limits _{j=1}^{m}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}\\&\qquad\quad + \frac{1+m}{((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2}\Big )\\&\qquad\quad -\frac{m+2}{((2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2))^2} \\&\quad\quad \ge \frac{1}{m+2}\Big ( \frac{{{(m+1)}^{2}}}{((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2}\\&\quad\qquad +\frac{m+1}{((2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2))^2} \Big )\\&\quad\qquad -\frac{m+2}{((2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2))^2}\\&\quad\quad =\frac{1}{m+2}\Big ( \frac{{{(m+1)}^{2}}}{((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2}\\&\quad\qquad -\frac{m^2+3m+3}{((2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2))^2} \Big )\\&\quad\quad =\frac{{{G}_{1}}{{m}^{3}}+{{G}_{2}}{{m}^{2}}+{{G}_{3}}m+{{G}_{4}}}{(m+2)((2m+3)\theta ^2+8(m+1)\theta +4(m+1))^2((2m+5)\theta ^2+8(m+2)\theta +4(m+2))^2}\\&\quad\quad \ge 0, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where \({{G}_{1}}=16+64\theta +80{{\theta }^{2}}+32{{\theta }^{3}}+4{{\theta }^{4}}\), \({{G}_{2}}=48+192\theta +240{{\theta }^{2}}+96{{\theta }^{3}}+12{{\theta }^{4}}\), \({{G}_{3}}=48+192\theta +232{{\theta }^{2}}+80{{\theta }^{3}}+7{{\theta }^{4}}\), and \({{G}_{4}}=16+64\theta +72{{\theta }^{2}}+16{{\theta }^{3}}-2{{\theta }^{4}}\). Hence, we can obtain that \(Y_{0}^{n}\ge v(\{0\})\).

In addition, if \(n+1\ge |S|>1\), we just need to prove that \(Y_{0}^{n}+\sum \limits _{i\in S\backslash \{0\}}{Y_{i}^{n}}\ge v(S)\). Let \(|S|=r+1\), then it is sufficient to prove that

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{n+1}\Big (\frac{1}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}+\sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}\Big )\\&\quad\qquad +\frac{r}{n(n+1)}\Big (\frac{n}{(3\theta ^2+8\theta +4)^2}-\sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}\frac{j}{((2j+3)\theta ^2+8(j+1)\theta +4(j+1))^2}\Big )\\&\quad\quad \ge \frac{n-r+1}{((2n-2r+3)\theta ^2+8(n-r+1)\theta +4(n-r+1))^2}, \end{aligned}$$

which means that, to show this inequality, we need to prove \({{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n)\ge 0\). According to Lemma 1, \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\doteq {{\varphi }_{2}}(r+1,n)-{{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n)\) is a decreasing function of r. Then, \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\) has three possible cases: (1) \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\ge 0\), for all \(r=1, 2, \cdots , n\); (2) \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\le 0\), for all \(r=1, 2, \cdots , n\); (3) there exists \({{r}^{*}}\in \big \{1, 2, \cdots , n\big \}\), \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\ge 0\) for \(r=1, 2,\cdots , {{r}^{*}}\) and \({{\phi }_{2}}(r,n)\le 0\) for \(r={{r}^{*}},{{r}^{*}}+1, \cdots , n\). In any of the three cases, following Lemma 2(ii), and \({{\varphi }_{2}}(n,n)=0\), we can get that for \(r=1, 2, \cdots , n,~n=2, 3,\cdots\)\({{\varphi }_{2}}(r,n)\ge 0\). Therefore, we have \(Y_{0}^{n}+\sum \limits _{i\in S\backslash \{0\}}{Y_{i}^{n}}\ge v(S)\).

With the arguments above, one can easily see that the Shapley value \(\{Y_{i}^{n},i=0, 1, 2, \cdots , n\}\) is in the core of the cooperative game \((N_0, v)\). \(\square\)

Proof of Theorem 5

According to the allocation rule generated by Theorem 4, it is not difficult to derive the transfer prices between firm A and each upstream subsidiary \(U_i(i = 1,2,...,n)\). \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Li, C., Cao, B., Zhou, YW. et al. Pricing, coalition stability, and profit allocation in the pull assembly supply chains under competition. OR Spectrum 45, 977–1011 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-023-00707-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-023-00707-1

Keywords

Navigation