Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Behind the child penalty: understanding what contributes to the labour market costs of motherhood

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the short- and long-run effects of having a child on labour market outcomes of mothers compared to non-mothers. Using matched employer-employee data for Italy over 1985–2018, through an event study methodology around childbirth, we show that the long-run child penalty in annual earnings is 52 log points and the penalty largely depends on the reduction in weeks worked by mothers. We then investigate sorting of women with and without children across different types of firms, providing evidence that mothers work in firms with lower productivity, sales, capital and wages after childbirth. Differences in rent-sharing between mothers and non-mothers explain 11.3% of the long-run child penalty in weekly wages, mostly due to between-firm components. Finally, we explore the individual-level, firm-level, and cultural factors that influence the size of child penalties. We find that the child penalty is higher for young, low-wage mothers and those taking longer leaves. It is larger in small firms with less generous pay and worse peers, and in more gender-conservative regions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. De Philippis and Lo Bello (2022) study the child penalty in participation over time, offering a complementary view on the child penalty on the extensive margin, while our focus is mostly on the intensive margin.

  2. The measure of earnings is gross of labour income taxes and pension contributions on the side of the employee.

  3. The maternity leave has a mandatory duration of 5 months and can be taken 1 to 2 months before the expected childbirth and lasts until 3 to 4 months after.

  4. Connected groups contain all the individuals that have ever been employed at one of the firms in the group and all the firms that have ever hired one of the workers in the group. Thus, two groups are not connected if one person of the second group has never been employed by a firm of the first group and a firm in the first group has never employed a person of the second group (or viceversa). Since fixed effects are identified up to a normalising constant, different connected groups give fixed effects estimates that are not comparable across each other. Hence, we keep the largest connected group, only. This group comprises 94.5% of the original sample. Note that we estimate AKM worker and firm effects using the full sample of both men and women, although the main analysis will focus on the latter, only. We do this to maximise the size of the largest connected group and to reduce limited mobility bias (Andrews et al. 2008). Specifically, we estimate the following regression:

    $$ w_{it} = \alpha_{i} + \psi_{J(i,t)} + \mathbf{x}_{it}^{\prime} \gamma + \varepsilon_{it} $$

    where wit are log weekly wages of worker i in year t. αi and ψJ(i,t) are worker and firm fixed effects, where the firm is indexed by J(i,t). \(\mathbf {x}_{it}^{\prime } \) contains time-varying observables (cubic polynomials in age and tenure, occupation dummies, part-time dummy, and their interaction with a gender dummy) and year fixed effects. εit is an error term.

  5. Women having more than one child are included in the analysis, but we study only the impact of their first child.

  6. We also use averages over time in order to reduce noise in financial quantities and to interpolate missing values in cases in which a firm has gaps in the balance sheet data.

  7. The mandatory maternity leave lasts 5 months. There are no policy changes regarding mandatory maternity leave over the period of analysis. During mandatory leave, mothers receive 80% of their average daily wage in the month before the leave. After this period, parents can take an optional parental leave for up to 6 months until the child turns 8 years old before 2015 and 12 years old after 2015. Until the child turns 3 years old (6 years old after 2015), the parent receives a compensation equal to 30% of his or her wage for the period the parent is on parental leave. The total duration of the parental leave in a family cannot exceed 10 months, unless the father takes more than 3 months: in this case, the father-specific leave is extended to maximum 7 months and the family’s total parental leave duration is extended to 11 months.

  8. These results are based on log annual earnings in the main job, i.e. the one with the highest number of weeks worked or with the highest earnings. We find very similar results if we use total earnings across jobs as outcome (Figure A.2 in the Appendix).

  9. Since we can only identify births for women that, at the time of childbirth, are working and are employed in the non-agricultural private sector, the group of mothers has a relatively high attachment to the labour market. Moreover, we may incorrectly classify mothers, who have their child while not working in the non-agricultural private sector, in the control group of non-mothers. Both these data limitations likely generate a downward bias in the child penalty estimates.

  10. Note that, given the nature of our data, we are unable to measure whether women move to unemployment, self-employment, or public employment, as we only have information on employment in the non-agricultural private sector. Thus, we can only measure employment/non-employment in the latter.

  11. See footnote 7 for details on the legislation of maternity and parental leaves.

  12. Since we measure firm characteristics in the year before childbirth, we are restricting the sample to workers observed in that year. In Casarico and Lattanzio (2021) we define groups based on firm characteristics at each event time k to keep all the observations and find similar results to the ones reported here.

  13. Specifically, we compute weighted averages of responses for each region using the weights provided by the EVS itself.

  14. This is in line with cross-country evidence provided in Kleven et al. (2019b).

References

  • Abowd JM, Kramarz F, Margolis DN (1999) High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica 67(2):251–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji JG, Blank RM (1999) Race and gender in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of Labor Economics, vol 3 of Handbook of Labor Economics, chapter 48. Elsevier, pp 3143–3259

  • Andresen M, Nix E (2022) What causes the child penalty? Evidence from adopting and same-sex couples. Journal of Labor Economics

  • Andrews MJ, Gill L, Schank T, Upward R (2008) High wage workers and low wage firms: negative assortative matching or limited mobility bias? J R Stat Soc Ser A (Statistics in Society) 171(3):673–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelov N, Johansson P, Lindahl E (2016) Parenthood and the gender gap in pay. J Labor Econ 34(3):545–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G. (1991) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1985) Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor. J Labor Econ 3(1):S33–S58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M (2020) Gender in the twenty-first century. AEA Papers Proc 110:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau FD, Kahn LM (2017) The gender wage gap: extent, trends, and explanations. J Econ Lit 55(3):789–865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder A (1973) Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates. J Hum Resour 8(4):436–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boelmann B, Raute A, Schönberg U (2020) Wind of change? Cultural determinants of maternal labor supply. CReAM Discussion Paper Series 2020 Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration (CReAM), Department of Economics, University College London

  • Bruns B (2019) Changes in workplace heterogeneity and how they widen the gender wage gap. Am Econ J Appl Econ 11(2):74–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Cardoso AR, Heining J, Kline P (2018) Firms and labor market inequality: Evidence and some theory. J Labor Econ 36(S1):S13–S70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Cardoso AR, Kline P (2016) Bargaining, sorting, and the gender wage gap: quantifying the impact of firms on the relative pay of women. Q J Econ 131(2):633–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casarico A, Lattanzio S (2021) Behind the Child Penalty: Understanding What Contributes to the Labour Market Costs of Motherhood. CESifo Working Paper Series 9155, CESifo

  • Casarico A, Lattanzio S (2022) What firms do: Gender inequality in linked employer-employee data. Journal of Labor Economics, forthcoming

  • Cortés P, Pan J (2020) Children and the remaining gender gaps in the labor market. Working Paper 27980, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Coudin E, Maillard S, To M (2018) Family, Firms and the Gender Wage Gap in France. IFS Working Papers W18/01, Institute for Fiscal Studies

  • De Philippis M, Lo Bello S (2022) The ins and outs of the gender employment gap: Assessing the role of fertility. Mimeo

  • de Quinto A, Hospido L, Sanz C (2020) The child penalty in Spain. Occasional Papers 2017, Banco de España

  • EIGE (2021) Gender Equality Index 2021. Technical report, European Institute for Gender Equality

  • Fanfani B (2022) Tastes for discrimination in monopsonistic labour markets. Labour Econ 75(C)

  • Gerard F, Lagos L, Severnini E, Card D (2021) Assortative matching or exclusionary hiring? the impact of employment and pay policies on racial wage differences in Brazil. Am Econ Rev 111(10):3418–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotz VJ, Johansson P, Karimi A (2017) Parenthood, family friendly workplaces, and the gender gaps in early work careers. Working Paper 24173, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Kitagawa EM (1955) Components of a difference between two rates. J Am Stat Assoc 50:1168–1194

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleven H, Landais C, Posch J, Steinhauer A, Zweimuller J (2019a) Child penalties across countries: Evidence and explanations. AEA Papers Proc 109:122–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven H, Landais C, Søgaard JE (2021) Does biology drive child penalties? Evidence from biological and adoptive families. Am Econ Rev Insights 3(2):183–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven H, Landais C, Søgaard JE (2019b) Children and gender inequality: evidence from Denmark. Am Econ J Appl Econ 11(4):181–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuziemko I, Pan J, Shen J, Washington E (2018) The Mommy effect: do women anticipate the employment effects of motherhood? Working Paper 24740, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Le Barbanchon T, Rathelot R, Roulet A (2020) Gender differences in job search: trading off commute against wage. Q J Econ 136(1):381–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martino EM (2020) The labor cost of motherhood: Is a shorter leave helpful? Mimeo

  • Nieto A (2021) Native-immigrant differences in the effect of children on the gender pay gap. J Econ Behav Organ 183:654–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca RL (1973) Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets. Int Econ Rev 14:693–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pacelli L, Pasqua S, Villosio C (2013) Labor market penalties for mothers in Italy. J Lab Res 34(4):408–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilner L (2016) Worker-firm matching and the parenthood pay gap: Evidence from linked employer-employee data. J Popul Econ 29(4):991–1023

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestion. We would like to thank Francesca Carta, Augusto Cerqua, Francesco D’Amuri, Giulia Giupponi, Joanna Kopinska, Eliana Viviano, seminar participants at University of Rome La Sapienza, Bank of Italy, and SEHO 2022, and editor Terra McKinnish for useful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and are not the responsibility of the Bank of Italy or the Eurosystem.

Funding

Salvatore Lattanzio received financial support for PhD studies from ESRC DTP Studentship (nr. ES/J500033/1) and Cambridge Commonwealth European and International Trust.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Salvatore Lattanzio.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Terra Mckinnish

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 1.23 MB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Casarico, A., Lattanzio, S. Behind the child penalty: understanding what contributes to the labour market costs of motherhood. J Popul Econ 36, 1489–1511 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-023-00937-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-023-00937-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation