Skip to main content

Allyn Young on Increasing Returns

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Endogenous Growth in Historical Perspective

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Economic History ((PEHS))

  • 707 Accesses

Abstract

Allyn Young, a Harvard economist, shot into international fame for his contribution to Paris peace conference after WWI.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The use of capital-intensive methods (or roundabout methods) in Young does not depend on the rate of interest but on the size of the market. “[T]he actual industrialists (and bankers) deny that variations in the rate of interest influence the extent of their operations, providing their competitors pay the same. It is the ‘market’ on which they count” (Young 1990, p. 82). This point was also noted by Kaldor (1972, p. 1242) who wrote: “[Young] argued that the extent to which capital is used in relation to labour is predominantly a matter of the scale of operations – the capital/labour ratio in production is a function of the extent of the market rather than of relative factor prices”.

  2. 2.

    Young’s modesty has been noted by several students and colleagues in letters and obituaries written after his death. In a letter of condolence (dated 17 March 1929) to Mrs. Young after Young’s premature death, John M. Keynes wrote: “His was an outstanding personality in the economics world and the most lovable. His influence as a teacher and a critic and as one who would always share with others all his best ideas was far greater than anyone would suppose who only knew his printed words; for it was his own work – unfortunately perhaps – which always came last”. Schumpeter (1954, p. 876, f.n.) also wrote of his habit hiding rather than highlighting his best ideas.

  3. 3.

    The theme of equilibrium rate of growth also appears in his LSE Lectures (See Young 1990, p. 45). Demand curve is not constant, as in Marshall, but shifts as a result of the very forces shifting the supply curve. It was therefore more appropriate to have a theory or equilibrium or optimum rate of progress which would keep the supply curve close up to the demand curve. See also Chandra (2020, p. 165).

  4. 4.

    “Seeking equilibrium conditions under increasing returns is as good as looking for a mare’s nest” (Young 1990, p. 45).

  5. 5.

    Young (ibid., p. 26) felt that Marshall’s supply and demand curves hold ceteris paribus and cannot be integrated to give the whole economic structure or the social picture.

  6. 6.

    For a discussion of the role of pecuniary external economies vis-a-vis economies of scale in the theory of increasing returns, see Chandra and Sandilands (2006).

  7. 7.

    “If consolidation always meant economy, there would be no effective limit to consolidation. That means that competition would inevitably everywhere end in monopoly. But, as we all know, in most fields of economic life competition maintains its health and vigor. This proves that supposed benefits of consolidation are often illusory” (Young 1929d; Mehrling and Sandilands 1999, p. 222). At another place Young (1990, pp. 53–54) writes: “Most of the advantages of increasing returns can be had in an industry not consolidated – such, in fact, is the typical modern industry… The advantages of consolidation are not, generally speaking, those of increasing returns. Rather they are those of increased specialization, those of reorganization, not mere increase of size of operating units”.

  8. 8.

    See Machovec (1995, Chapter 10) who points out that both Knight and Chamberlin had a static view of competition while Young subscribed to a process view.

  9. 9.

    It is interesting to note that Young employed offer curves (or the principle of reciprocal demand) to analyse the growth process though he held money to be central to an economic system. As noted by Blitch (1995, pp. 173–74), perhaps the idea of reciprocal demand (or barter exchange) comes closest to explaining the cumulative process of growth. In offer curves demand and supply are interdependent; along such curves cost of production and marginal utility are released from the pound of ceteris paribus.

  10. 10.

    “Large production, not large-scale production, permits increasing returns” (Young 1990, p. 54).

  11. 11.

    Kaldor (1972, p. 1243) thought that Young’s 1928 paper was “so many years ahead of its time that the progress of economic thought passed it by”.

  12. 12.

    Schumpeter (1937, p. 154), for example, writing after his death, stated: “Rarely if ever has fame such as his been acquired on the basis of so little published work”.

  13. 13.

    Young (1928b), in fact, considered any distinction between theoretical and applied economics as largely artificial. He wrote: “Economic theory, divorced from its functional relations to economic problems, or with those relations obscured, is no better than an interesting intellectual game. It gives endless opportunities for dialectical ingenuity. But it cannot advance knowledge, for it leads up a blind alley” (also in Mehrling and Sandilands 1999, p. 20).

  14. 14.

    Young (1929e) related the concept of equilibrium with time, and was of the opinion that all economic equilibria are unstable. “Market price is the price which will be found in a given market at a given time. It may be regarded as the limiting form of the short-time or temporary equilibrium price” (also in Young 1990, p. 154).

  15. 15.

    Young (1990, pp. 41–43) noted that Marshall’s particular expenses curve should not be confused with the supply curve. It was not a true supply curve, but since not all the producers have the same costs, it was upward sloping. Everyone, including those producing at the lowest costs, sell at the equilibrium price, and the area under the curve gives the producers’ total expenses. See also Chandra (2020, p. 164).

  16. 16.

    For Kaldor’s interpretation of Smith and Young see Chandra (2019).

  17. 17.

    For Currie-Kaldor exchange on increasing returns see Sandilands (1990), and for Sandilands-Currie-Kaldor exchange see Chandra and Sandilands (2020, 2021).

References

  • Blitch, C. (1995). Allyn Young: The Peripatetic Economist. Basingstoke and London: Macmillan Press Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, James M., and Yong J. Yoon. 1999. Generalised increasing returns, Euler’s theorem, and competitive equilibrium. History of Political Economy 31 (3): 511–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, James M., and Yong J. Yoon. 2000. A Smithian perspective on increasing returns. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (1): 43–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, Edward H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh. 2004. Adam Smith, Allyn Young and the division of labour. Journal of Economic Issues 38: 787–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh. 2019. Nicholas Kaldor on Adam Smith and Allyn Young. Review of Political Economy 31 (3): 445–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh. 2020. Allyn Abbott Young. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh, and Roger J. Sandilands. 2006. The role of pecuniary external economies and economies of scale in the theory of increasing returns. Review of Political Economy 18 (2): 193–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh, and Roger J. Sandilands. 2020. Nicholas Kaldor, Increasing returns and Verdoorn’s law. Strathclyde Discussion Papers in Economics, No. 20-02. Glasgow: University of Strathclyde.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, Ramesh, and Roger J. Sandilands. 2021. Nicholas Kaldor, increasing returns and Verdoorn’s law. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 44 (2): 315–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clapham, J.M. 1922. On empty economic boxes. Economic Journal 32: 305–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colacchio, Georgio. 2005. Reconstructing Allyn A. Young’s theory of increasing returns. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 (3): 321–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ely, Richard T., Thomas S. Adams, Max O. Lorenz, and Allyn A. Young. 1908. Outlines of Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ely, Richard T., Thomas S. Adams, Max O. Lorenz, and Allyn A. Young. 1916. Outlines of Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ely, Richard T., Thomas S. Adams, Max O. Lorenz, and Allyn A. Young. 1923. Outlines of Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ely, Richard T., Thomas S. Adams, Max O. Lorenz, and Allyn A. Young. 1930. Outlines of Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, Nicholas. 1972. The irrelevance of equilibrium economics. Economic Journal 82: 1237–1255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, Nicholas. 1975. What is wrong with economic theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 89 (3): 347–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, Frank H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, Paul. 1990. Rethinking International Trade. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, Paul. 1993. Toward a counter-counterrevolution in development theory. Annual Conference on Development Economics 1992, 15–38. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laidler, David. 1993. Hawtrey, Harvard, and the origins of the Chicago tradition. Journal of Political Economy 101 (6): 1068–1103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laidler, David. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machovec, Frank H. 1995. Perfect Competition and the Transformation of Economics. London and New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, Alfred. 1890 (1938). Principles of Economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, Perry G. 1996. The monetary thought of Allyn Abbott Young. History of Political Economy 28 (4): 607–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, Perry G. 1997. The Money Interest and the Public Interest. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, Perry G., and Roger J. Sandilands. 1999. Money and Growth: Selected Papers of Allyn Abbott Young. London and New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Perala, Maiju. 2006. Looking at the other side of the coin: Allyn Young and the early development theory. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28 (4): 461–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raffaelli, Tiziano. 2003. Marshall’s Evolutionary Economics. Abingdon and New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, Lionel. 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Paul M. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–1038.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Paul M. 1989. Capital accumulation in the theory of long-run growth. In Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. Robert J. Barro. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, Paul. 1943. Problems of industrialisation in eastern and south-eastern Europe. Economic Journal 53: 202–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, Paul. 1961. Notes on the theory of the big push. In Economic Development of Latin America, ed. H.S. Ellis and H.C. Wallaich. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandilands, Roger J. 1990. The Life and Political Economy of Lauchlin Currie. Durham and London: Duke University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sandilands, Roger J. 2000. Perspectives on Allyn Young in theories of endogenous growth. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (3): 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1937. Allyn A. Young. In Encyclopedia of Social Sciences, 514–515.New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954 (1982). History of Economic Analysis. London: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, Tibor. 1954. Two concepts of external economies. Journal of Political Economy 62: 143–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, Piero. 1926. The laws of return under competitive conditions. Economic Journal 6: 535–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1913. Pigou’s wealth and welfare. Quarterly Journal of Economics 27 (4): 672–686. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 86–96).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1928a. Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal 38 (152): 527–542. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 49–61).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1928b. English political economy. Economica 8 (22): 1–15. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 15–28).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1929a. The creator of wealth. In The Book of Popular Science, 110–116. New York: The Grolier Society. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 149–152).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1929b. Supply and demand. In Encyclopaedia Britannica 1928, 579–580. London: The Encyclopaedia Britannica Company. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 143–146).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1929c. Big business: How the economic system grows and evolves like a living organism. In The Book of Popular Science, 5387–5394. New York: The Grolier Society. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 411–420).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1929d. The making of wealth. In The Book of Popular Science, 3377–3385. New York: The Grolier Society. Reprinted in Mehrling and Sandilands (1999, pp. 220–230).

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1929e. Price. In Encyclopedia Britannica 1928. London: The Encyclopedia Britannica Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, Allyn. 1990. Nicholas Kaldor’s notes on Allyn Young’s LSE lectures 1927–29. Journal of Economic Studies 17 (3/4): 18–114.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Chandra, R. (2022). Allyn Young on Increasing Returns. In: Endogenous Growth in Historical Perspective. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-83761-7_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-83761-7_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-83760-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-83761-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics