Skip to main content

Value Creation out of Innovation and Resources

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Value in Business

Part of the book series: Contributions to Management Science ((MANAGEMENT SC.))

  • 1004 Accesses

Abstract

Along with the development of modern technology, there have appeared unprecedented kinds of markets participated by traditional and nontraditional players. These new markets have simultaneously bought forward unparalleled challenges to the academic world and decision-making managers and entrepreneurs. To meet these challenges, this chapter, which is mainly based on (Forrest et al., to appear, Potentials of value creation and capture based on innovation, resources, strategic networks and blocks), explore potentials of value creation at the firm level from several diverse vantage points, and the next chapter looks at potentials of value capture at the firm level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Ahuja, G., Lampert, C. M., & Tandon, V. (2009). Moving beyond Schumpeter: Management research on the determinants of technological innovations. The Academy of Management Annals, 2(1), 1–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. (1993). Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14(1), 33–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amit, R., & Zott, C. (2001). Value creation in e-business. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6/7), 493–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baizakov, S., Forest, J. Y. L., & Baizakov, N. (2019). Modeling the managements of the economies of developing countries. Advances in Systems Science and Applications, 19(2), 101–119. https://doi.org/10.25728/assa.2019.19.2.673

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balakrishnan, A., Kumara, S. R. T., & Sundaresan, S. (1999). Manufacturing in the digital age: Exploiting information technologies for product realization. Information Systems Frontier, 1, 25–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17, 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1997). Gaining and sustaining competitive advantage. Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J., & Arikan, A. (2001). The resource-based view: Origins and implications. In M. Hitt, R. Freeman, & J. Harrison (Eds.), Handbook of strategic management (pp. 124–185). Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becheikh, N., Landry, R., & Amara, N. (2006). Lessons from innovation empirical studies in the manufacturing sector: A systematic review of the literature from 1993 to 2003. Technovation, 26(5), 644–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., & Whinston, M. D. (1990). Multimarket contact and collusive behavior. RAND Journal of Economics, 21(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cacciolatti, L., & Lee, S. H. (2016). Revisiting the relationship between marketing capabilities and firm performance: The moderating role of market orientation, marketing strategy and organisational power. Journal of Business Research, 69(12), 5597–5610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. N. S. (1992). On the new institutional economics. In L. Werin & H. Wijkander (Eds.), Contract economics (pp. 48–65). Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clemons, E. K., & Row, M. C. (1992). Information technology and industrial cooperation: The changing economics of coordination and ownership. Journal of Management Information Systems, 9, 9–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2003). Ownership and the externality problem. In T. L. Anderson & F. S. McChesney (Eds.), Property rights: Cooperation, conflict, and law. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, S., & Segev, A. (1999). Business transformation on the internet. European Management Journal, 17, 466–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. H. (1997). Effective interfirm collaboration: How firms minimize transaction costs and maximize transaction value. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 535–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt, K. M., & Martin, J. A. (2000). Dynamic capabilities: What are they? Strategic Management Journal, 21(10–11), 1105–1121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P. B., & Wurster, T. S. (1999). Blown to bits: How the new economics of information transforms strategy. Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang, E., Palmatier, R., & Grewal, R. (2011). Effects of customer and innovation asset configuration strategies on firm performance. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(3), 587–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y.-L., Baizakov, S., Haile, Y. G., Gyan, A., & Liu, Y. (n.d.) (to appear). Potentials of value creation and capture based on innovation, resources, strategic networks and blocks. Submitted for publication.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y. L., Buttermore, J., & Wajda, T. (2017). At Nash equilibrium when new market competitions appear? Kybernetes, the International of Cybernetics, Systems and Management Science, 46(2), 256–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y. L., Nicholls, N., Schimmel, K., & Liu, S. F. (2020). Managerial decision making: A holistic approach. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y. L., Shao, L., McKinney, R., & Shao, D. (2019). Firm performance and market expansion from the point of view of resources. International Journal of Business and Systems Research, accepted for publication.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y.-L., & Tallapally, P. (2018). Customers are less patient, sustainable advantage becomes transient and the key for firms to succeed in fast changing markets. Journal of Business, Economics and Technology, 21(1), 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forrest, J. Y. L., Tucker, R., Lin, C. C., & Mondal, S. (2018). Impacts of manufacturing firms’ culture, structure and leadership on innovation: A systemic approach. Proceedings of the 41st annual meeting of northeastern association of business, economics and technology, State College, PA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forrester Research Report. (2000). Global eCommerce approaches Hypergrowth. April 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuentelsaz, L., & Gómez, J. (2006). Multipoint competition, strategic similarity and entry into geographic markets. Strategic Management Journal, 27(5), 477–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagel, J., III, & Armstrong, A. G. (1997). Net gain: Expanding markets through virtual communities. Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harmancioglu, N., Droge, C., & Calantone, R. (2009). Strategic fit to resources versus NPD execution proficiencies: What are their roles in determining success? Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 37(3), 266–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haveman, H. A., & Nonnemaker, L. (2000). Competition in multiple geographic markets: The impact on growth and market entry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(2), 232–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes, R. H., Wheelwright, S. C., & Clark, K. B. (1988). Dynamic manufacturing. The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hitt, M., & Ireland, R. D. (2017). The intersection of entrepreneurship and strategic management research. In D. L. Sexton, H. Landstrom, & C. Jones (Eds.), The Blackwell handbook of entrepreneurship (pp. 45–63). Blackwell.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, D. A., & Klenow, P. J. (1994). Learning-by-doing spillovers in the semiconductor industry. Journal of Political Economy, 102(6), 1200–1227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaworski, B. J., & Kohli, A. K. (1993). Market orientation: Antecedents and consequences. Journal of Marketing, 57(July), 53–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotler, P., & Keller, K. L. (2016). A framework for marketing management (6th ed.). Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kozlenkova, I. V., Samaha, S. A., & Palmatier, R. W. (2014). Resource-based theory in marketing. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 42, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lei, D., Hitt, M. A., & Bettis, R. (1996). Dynamic core competences through meta-learning and strategic context. Journal of Management, 22, 549–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, S. X., & Greenwood, R. (2004). The effect of within industry diversification on firm performance: Synergy creation, multi-market contact and market structuration. Strategic Management Journal, 25(12), 1131–1153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, T., & Ma, J. H. (2015). Complexity analysis of dual-channel game model with different managers’ business objectives. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation, 20, 199–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Y. (2009). Systemic yoyos: Some impacts of the second dimension. Auerbach Publication, an imprint of Taylor and Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makadok, R. (2001). Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of rent creation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(5), 387–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGrath, R. G. (2013). The end of competitive advantage: How to keep your strategy moving as fast as your business. Harvard Business Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran, P., & Ghoshal, S. (1999). Markets, firms, and the process of economic development. Academy of Management Review, 24, 390–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1992). Transaction costs, institutions, and economic performance. ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ombaka, B. E., Awino, Z. B., Machuki, V. N., & Wainaina, G. (2015). Exploring resources and performance relationships in commercial enterprises: An empirical perspective. Journal of Management and Strategy, 6(4), 12–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. T. (1959). The theory of growth of the firm. Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 179–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peteraf, M. A., & Barney, J. (2003). Unraveling the resource-based tangle. Managerial and Decision Economics, 24(4), 309–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1979). How competitive forces shape strategy. Harvard Business Review, 57(2), 137–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. R. (1999). Information rules: A strategic guide to the network economy. Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations, books I-III, (1986 printing). Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. (1999). When giants stumble: Classic business blunders and how to avoid them. Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1987). Profiting from technological innovations: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing, and public policy. In D. J. Teece (Ed.), The competitive challenge: Strategies for industrial innovation and renewal (pp. 185–219). Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1983). Organizational innovation: The transaction cost approach. In J. Ronen (Ed.), Entrepreneurship (pp. 101–133). Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ye, G. L., Priem, R. L., & Alshwer, A. A. (2012). Achieving demand-side synergy from strategic diversification: How combining mundane assets can leverage consumer utilities. Organization Science, 23(1), 207–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, T., & Cannella, A. A., Jr. (2012). A comprehensive review of multimarket competition research. Journal of Management, 39, 76–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 12.1

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 12.1

What is assumed in this theorem implies that the said market is in a state of mutual forbearance (Bernheim & Whinston, 1990). The incumbent firms alleviate their rivalries by partitioning the market according to their strengths so that they surrender dominance to their stronger competitors in marketplaces where they are less efficient (Li & Greenwood, 2004). The codependence of these firms gradually decreases the rates of market entry and exit (Fuentelsaz & Gómez, 2006; Yu & Cannella Jr., 2012), while reducing interfirm hostility (Haveman & Nonnemaker, 2000). Due to this state of mutual forbearance, let us consider the aggregate of the incumbent firms as one imaginary firm with α being its market share in percentage. So, β = 1 − α denotes the percentage size of the consumer surplus.

As detailed in Chap. 3, let us assume that there are n incumbent firms and that all relevant boundary conditions are normalized such that incumbent firms’ individual selling prices, production costs, loyal customers’ reservation values within the said market, lower and upper boundary conditions and magnitudes of loyal-customer bases are all, respectively, normalized to Pi (0 ≤ Pi, ≤ 1), 0, 1, 0, 1, and α/n, i = 1, 2, …, n.

Proof of 1) ⇒ 2). Assume that by randomizing its price over the interval from production cost to loyal customers’ reservation value, or [0,1] after applying normalization, a firm enters into the said market of n incumbent firms, which are collectively seen as one aggregate firm. So, the consumer surplus must satisfy β = 1 − α > 0.

Proof of 2) ⇒ 1). Assume that the consumer surplus satisfies β = 1 − α > 0. Firstly, let α0 be a real number so that β = 1 − α > α0 > 0 and α = ℓα0, where is a natural number. Secondly, let us imagine that the aggregate firm is divided into many identical (imaginary) “firms,” named i, i = 1, 2, …, . Each of these firms provides consumers with an identical product and enjoys the market share α0 = α/ of loyal consumers. These firms compete over the switchers with adjustable prices. And thirdly, these imaginary firms do not have any symmetric pure strategy Nash equilibrium, for details see Chap. 3.

For the rest of this proof, it suffices to show that there is one firm that will be expected to profit by entering this market through uniformly randomizing its price strategy over the interval [0,1]. To this end, let F(P) be the price distribution of Firm j, one of the imaginary firms of the aggregate firm. The aggregate firm or equivalently each of the imaginary forms sets its price after considering the price of the entering firm and those of all other imaginary firms. Hence, the profits for Firm j from its loyal consumers is α0P and those from its share of the switchers is \( {\prod}_{i\ne j}^{\ell}\left(1-P\right)\left[1-F(P)\right]\beta P=\beta P\left(1-P\right){\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell -1} \). Hence, the profit Π Firm j generates when the firm sells its product at price P is

$$ {\alpha}_0P+\beta P\left(1-P\right){\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell -1} $$

and the objective of Firm j is to maximize the following by choosing its price distribution F(P)

$$ E\left(\Pi \right)=\underset{-\infty }{\overset{+\infty }{\int }}\left\{{\alpha}_0P+\upbeta P\left(1-P\right){\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell -1}\right\} dF(P) $$
$$ =\underset{0}{\overset{1}{\int }}\left\{{\alpha}_0P+\beta P\left(1-P\right){\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell -1}\right\} dF(P) $$

where E(Π) stands for Firm j’s expected profit for all possible prices. The reason why the upper and lower limits of the integral are changed respectively from +∞ and −∞ to 1 and 0 is because when P < 0 or when P > 1, the profits are zero.

The equilibrium indifference condition of Firm j is

$$ {\alpha}_0\times P+\beta \times P\left(1-P\right){\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell -1}={\alpha}_0\times 1. $$
(12.1)

So, for the imaginary firms, solving Eq. (12.1) leads to their symmetric equilibrium pricing strategy as follows:

$$ F(P)=1-{\left(\frac{\alpha_0}{\beta P}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\ell -1}}. $$
(12.2)

From β > α0, it follows that α0/β < 1. So, for any Price P, satisfying 1 ≥ P ≥ α0/β, Eq. (12.2) is well-defined as a probability distribution. This end implies that for the imaginary firms, or equivalently, the aggregate firm, the lowest allowed price is α0/β.

To complete this proof, it suffices to show that the entrant actually expects to make profits in this new market. To this end because \( {\mathit{\lim}}_{P\to {1}^{-}}F(P)=1-{\left({\alpha}_0/\beta \right)}^{1/\left(\ell -1\right)}\ne F(1)=1 \), the cumulative price distribution function F(P) has a jump discontinuity at the reservation value P = 1, where the amount of jump is (α0/β)1/( − 1). That is, F(P) has a mass point of size (α0/β)1/( − 1) at the reservation price P = 1. So, the expected profit of the entrant is the following:

$$ E\left(\Pi \right)=\underset{0}{\overset{\alpha_0/\beta }{\int }}\beta P dP+\underset{\alpha_0/\beta }{\overset{+\infty }{\int }}\beta P{\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell } dP $$
(12.3)
$$ =\underset{0}{\overset{\alpha_0/\beta }{\int }}\beta P dP+\underset{\alpha_0/\beta }{\overset{1}{\int }}\beta P{\left[1-F(P)\right]}^{\ell } dP+\beta {\left(\frac{\alpha_0}{\beta}\right)}^{\ell /\left(\ell -1\right)} $$
(12.4)

where the first term in the right-hand side of Eq. (12.3) stands for the expected profit of the entrant when it charges the lowest price in the marketplace and captures the entire consumer surplus, and the second term is the entrant’s expected profit when it is in direct competition with the incumbent firms.

It can be readily shown that all the terms on the left-hand side of Eq. (12.4) are positive. So, it implies that if the consumer surplus β = 1 − α > 0, there will be at least one entrant into the said market to compete with the incumbent firms.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Forrest, J.YL., Liu, Y. (2022). Value Creation out of Innovation and Resources. In: Value in Business. Contributions to Management Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-82898-1_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics