Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Equity, Emissions Allowance Trading and the Paris Agreement on Climate Change

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Disasters and Climate Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Conference of the Parties to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (COP21), held in Paris in December 2015, resulted in voluntary greenhouse gas (GHG) reduction pledges, independent of each other, by 195 countries. The purpose of this paper is to analyze the equity implications of this “bottom-up” approach to climate change negotiations in two major ways. First we analyze the GHG reduction targets specified in the COP21 agreement prior to any emissions trading in terms of the Gini Coefficient equity metric. We also compare the pledges with specific equity principles proposed by developing countries for many years, such as the Egalitarian and Ability to Pay equity. Second, we analyze the equity outcomes after emissions trading takes place for a sample of countries/regions. We find that international policy coordination through a system of tradable GHG emissions allowances can greatly lower the cost to all participants of reducing atmospheric concentrations of greenhouse gases. An emissions trading system involving all countries and regions that made unconditional pledges at COP21 could reduce total GHG mitigation costs from an estimated $1.71 trillion to $0.4 trillion (in 2015 dollars), a savings of 77%. The ensuing allowance sales revenues would greatly enhance the capability of lower-income countries to meet their COP21 pledges. Moreover, the cost-savings in high-income countries would facilitate contributions to the promised fund of $100 billion per year to assist climate policy implementation in low-income countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Some analysts, such as Barrett (2012) and Andresen (2015), label “top-down” as a misnomer because of an absence of central authority to distribute and enforce GHG reduction commitments. However, we follow the standard convention of utilizing the term to characterize the predominant approach to international climate negotiations until around 2009.

  2. The U.S. pointed to the lack of developing country commitments as the justification for not making international commitments of its own.

  3. According to the OECD (2015b), in 2013–2014 flows of $57 billion went to climate financing in developing countries, with projections to be on track for the $100 billion needed by 2020. These figures have been called in to question, however (see, e.g., a summary of the criticisms by Upton 2015) due to the inclusion of market rate loans and funding for projects that critics believe do not qualify as being climate relevant (Roberts and Weikmans 2015).

  4. Some have argued that equity principles have been more of a focus of academic discourse than actual policy-making. However, we take issue with this. Yes, several countries have proposed equity principles of their own with regard to the decisions of others, even before the bottom-up approach came into vogue, while others proposed reduction commitments without reference to equity principles, but the preponderance of negotiations have in fact revolved around equity. Some point to the Kyoto commitments being couched in terms of “common but differentiated responsibilities,” but Rose et al. (1998) and others have made a strong case that the pleading of special considerations by signatory countries, such as Australia (high dependence on coal exports) and Russia (transitioning economy), for example, were merely an appeal to fairness in terms of economic hardships.

  5. Rose (1992) makes the distinction between equity principles and “reference bases,” metrics by which to gauge the equity principle. For some, there is a one-to-one correspondence such as the Egalitarian principle always being associated with population. For others, such as Horizontal equity, various reference bases might be applied, such as emissions or energy use. Utilizing historical or future emissions is referred to as a “dynamic reference base.”

  6. The European Union elected to submit a single comprehensive pledge for its 28 countries. For simplicity, when referring to INDCs submitted for COP21, our use of the term “countries” includes the EU as a single entity.

  7. Once a country has officially registered its INDC with the UNFCCC, it is referred to as an NDC. However, since not all of the signatory countries in our dataset have done so, we continue to use INDC for the group.

  8. We acknowledge the limitations of a one-parameter characterization of an entire distribution (see, Braun 1988).

  9. We omit Andorra and Lichtenstein despite their positive reduction pledges because of their unusually low populations and high per capita incomes (which comprise only 0.02% of total emissions), so as not to skew the analysis. We also omit all countries with a negative reduction commitment, e.g., India and Russia, because of the difficulties negative numbers pose for constructing Lorenz Curves and calculating Gini coefficients. Note that although this reduces the percentage of world emissions covered to 75% (from 88%), we ran sensitivity tests on the results and found that these restrictions on our sample affected the Gini coefficients by only a few percent.

  10. The cumulative share of emissions reductions is calculated by first ordering the countries by per capita GDP in ascending order, then taking the emissions reduction percentage in each country, summing them, and finally rescaling to 100. The same approach is used in Figure 5a, with relevant reordering.

  11. Note that the Lorenz curve in Figure 2a is monotonically increasing but not at a monotonically increasing rate (a non-convexity). This might cause some to be suspicious of a Gini coefficient derived from it. As a counterpart to Figure 2a, we also specified a Lorenz curve in which countries are ordered by the ratio of the emission reduction and per capita GDP in ascending order. The Gini coefficient associated with this specification is 0.613, indicating a similar significant departure from Ability to Pay equity.

  12. One of the most prominent examples of an international linkage is that between California and Quebec C&T systems. Although it has led to relatively few transactions between the two entities, this has more to do with the similar marginal abatement costs in both regions than any issues inherent to a linked system. Rather, the linkage is proof that linking is possible. Moving forward, if Ontario’s recently established system, or Oregon’s proposed system were to join the link, we would expect to observe an increase in trade as more variation in marginal abatement costs are introduced to the system.

  13. For our analysis, we further disaggregate to 15 regions. See Appendix B for an explanation of the methodology.

  14. This is close to the 59.3 GtCO2e in 2030 for the countries we include in our analysis.

  15. Of the 90 countries in our analysis, 67 explicitly state in their INDC the intention to include the LULUCF sector in their emissions calculations, and we have used their provided data that reflects as much. However, we note that for the majority of high-income (and high emissions) countries this simply amounts to a fixed reduction in their annual emissions, as land use is relatively static, and forest preserves and national parks act as carbon sinks. Brazil is the biggest exception to this, the exclusion of LULUCF cuts their projected emissions by a third, though we note that their INDC explicitly mentions the inclusion of managed lands and forests in their emissions accounting.

  16. Some people view emissions trading as a way for the rich to buy their way out of responsibility entirely. However, in effect, those who purchase allowances (primarily high-income countries) are still paying for mitigation, though elsewhere in the world. Moreover, these payments fund the installation of new technology in countries that sell allowances (typically LMI countries).

  17. As done previously in relation to Fig. 4a, we adjust for countries attaining negative costs post-trading by scaling up all countries’ costs, so that no country has a negative cost. The difference in the approach we used as opposed to Fig. 4a is that we scale by the ratio of Cost/GDP rather than simple cost.

References

  • (CERP) Climate Equity Reference Project (2016) The climate equity reference calculator. Stockholm Environment Institute. Retrieved from: http://calculator.climateequityreference.org/

    Google Scholar 

  • (IPCC) Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (1995) IPCC second Assessment report: climate change 1995 (SAR). New York, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • (IPCC) Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (2014) Fifth Assessment report (AR5), Geneva

  • Aguiar A, Narayanan B, McDougall R (2016) An overview of the GTAP 9 Data Base. J Global Econ Anal 1(1):181–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andresen S (2015) International climate negotiations: top-down, bottom-up or a combination of both? Inter Spect 50(1):15–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averchenkova A, Bassi S (2016) Beyond the targets: assessing the political credibility of pledges for the Paris Agreement. Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Averchenkova A, Stern N, Zhenghelis D (2014) Taming the beasts of ‘burden-sharing’: an analysis of equitable mitigation actions and approaches to 2030 mitigation pledges. Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1992) ‘acceptable’ allocations of tradable carbon emission entitlements in a global warming treaty. In: Barrett S et al. combating global warming: study on a global system of tradable carbon emission entitlements. U.N. Conference on trade and Development, New York.

  • Barrett, S. 2012. Credible commitments, focal points and tipping. In R. Hand and S. Ulph (eds.), climate change and common sense. Essays in honor of Thomas Schelling. Oxford: Oxford University press.

  • Barrett S (2016) Presentation for the Panel on Climate and Energy Policy after the Paris Agreement. In: Annual Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Zürich, Switzerland, 24 June

  • Böhringer, C. 2000. Cooling Down Hot Air: A Global CGE Analysis of Post-Kyoto Carbon Abatement Strategies Energy Policy 28(11): 779–789.

  • Böhringer C, Rutherford TF (2008) Combining bottom-up and top-down. Energy Econ 30(2):574–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braun D (1988) Multiple measurements of U.S. income inequality. Rev Econ Stat 70(3):398–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bretschger L (2013) Climate policy and equity principles: fair burden sharing in a dynamic world. Environ Dev Econ 18(05):517–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bretschger L (2016) Presentation for the Panel on Climate and Energy Policy after the Paris Agreement. In: Annual Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Zürich, Switzerland, 24 June

  • Bretschger L, Lechthaler F, Rausch S, Zhang L (2017) Knowledge diffusion, endogenous growth, and the costs of global climate policy. Eur Econ Rev 93:47–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtraw D, Palmer KL, Munnings C, Weber P, Woerman M (2013) Linking by degrees: incremental alignment of cap-and-trade markets. Resources for the Future discussion paper 13-04. Retrieved from: http://www.rff.org/research/publications/linking-degrees-incremental-alignment-cap-and-trade-markets

  • Caney S (2012) Just Emissions. Philos Public Aff 40(4):255–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capros P, Van Regemorter D, Paroussos L, Karkatsoulis P, Revesz T, Fragkiadakis C, Tsani S, Charalampidis I (2013) Perry M, Abrell J, Ciscar JC, Pycroft J, Saveyn B (eds) GEM-E3 model documentation. JRC scientific and technical reports. EUR 26034 EN

  • U.S. Census Bureau (2015) Projected population and growth rates in population for baseline countries/regions 2010–2030. International Data Base. http://www.census.gov/ipc/www/idb/

  • Clarke-Sather A, Du J, Wang Q, Zeng J, Li Y (2011) Carbon inequality at the sub-national scale: a case study of provincial-level inequality in CO2 emissions in China 1997-2007. Energ Policy 39:5420–5428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Criqui P, Mima S, Viguier L (1999) Marginal abatement costs of CO2 emission reductions, geographical flexibility and concrete ceilings: an Assessment using the POLES model. Energ Policy 27(10):585–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edenhofer, O., Lessmann, K., Kemfert, C., Grubb, M., and Köhler, J. 2006. Induced technological change: exploring its implications for the economics of atmospheric stabilization: synthesis report from the innovation modeling comparison project. The Energy Journal: Special Issue on Endogenous Technological Change and the Economics of Atmospheric Stabilisation, 27: 57–107.

  • Ellerman AD, Decaux A (1998) Analysis of post-Kyoto CO2 emissions trading using marginal abatement curves. Report no 40, MIT, Cambridge

  • Flachsland C, Marschinski R, Edenhofer O (2009) To link or not to link: benefits and disadvantages of linking cap-and-trade systems. Clim Pol 9(4):358–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujimori S, Kubota I, Dai H, Takahashi K, Hasegawa T, Liu JY, Hijioka Y, Masui T, Takimi M (2016) Will International emissions trading help achieve the objectives of the Paris Agreement? Environ Res Lett 11(10):104001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green Climate Fund (2016) Resources Mobilized Accessed 22 Feb 2017. http://www.greenclimate.fund/partners/contributors/resources-mobilized

  • Groot L (2010) Carbon Lorenz Curves. Resour Energy Econ 32:45–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallegatte S, Rozenberg J (2017) Climate change through a poverty lens. Nat Clim Chang 7:250–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höhne M, den Elzen M, Weiss M (2006) Common but differentiated convergence (CDC): a new conceptual approach to long-term climate policy. Climate Policy 6(2):181–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hourcade, J.C., Jaccard, M., Bataille, C., Ghersi, F. 2006. Hybrid modelling: new answers to old challenges. Introduction to the Special Issue The Energy Journal: Special Issue on Hybrid Modeling of Energy-Environment Policies, 27: 1–11.

  • Klepper G, Peterson S (2006) Marginal abatement cost curves in general equilibrium: the influence of world energy prices. Resour Energy Econ 28(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuik O, Brander L, Tol RS (2009) Marginal abatement costs of greenhouse gas emissions: a meta-analysis. Energ Policy 37(4):1395–1403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kverndokk S, Rose A (2008) Equity and justice in climate change policy. Inter Rev Environ Res Econ 2(2):135–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane R (1986) Market justice, political justice. Am Polit Sci Rev 80:383–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Live Population (2016) Population Projections Retrieved from: http://www.livepopulation.com/population-projections/world-2030.html

  • Morris J, Paltsev S, Reilly J (2012) Marginal abatement costs and marginal welfare costs for greenhouse gas emissions reductions: results from the EPPA model. Environ Model Assess 17(4):325–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD, Boyer JG (1999) Requiem for Kyoto: an economic analysis of the Kyoto protocol. Energy J 20:99–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2015) The economic consequences of climate change. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Parry I, Veung C, Heine D (2015) How much carbon pricing is in Countries' own interests? The critical role of co-benefits. Climate Change Econ 6(4)

  • Prins G, Rayner S (2007) Time to ditch Kyoto. Nature 449:973–975

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rayner, S. 2010. How to eat an elephant: a bottom-up approach to climate policy. Climate Policy, 10(6): 615–621.

  • Roberts T, Weikmans R (2015) Is the ‘$100 billion by 2020 goal’ from Copenhagen being met!? A dispatch from the Paris climate conference. Planet Policy, The Brookings Institute Retrieved from: https://www.brookings.edu/blog/planetpolicy/2015/12/04/is-the-100-billion-by-2020-goal-from-copenhagen-being-met-a-dispatch-from-the-paris-climate-conference/

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogelj J, Den Elzen M, Höhne N, Fransen T, Fekete H, Winkler H, Schaeffer R, Sha F, Riahi K, Meinshausen M (2016) Paris Agreement climate proposals need a boost to keep warming well below 2 C. Nature 534(7609):631–639

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose A (1992) Equity considerations of tradable carbon emission entitlements. In: Barrett S et al (eds) Combating global warming: study on a global system of tradable carbon emission entitlements. U.N. Conference on Trade and Development, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose A, Wei D (2008) Greenhouse gas emissions trading among Pacific rim countries: an analysis of policies to bring developing countries to the bargaining table. Energ Policy 36:1420–1429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose A, Stevens B, Edmonds J, Wise M (1998) International equity and differentiation in global warming policy. Environ Resour Econ 12(1):25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teng F, He J, Pan X, Zhang C (2011) Metric of carbon equality: carbon Gini index based on historical cumulative emission per capita. Adv Clim Chang Res 2(3):134–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Economic Research Service ERS (2015) Projected Real GDP for Baseline Countries, Department of Agriculture Retrieved from: http://www.ers.usda.gov/datafiles/International_Macroeconomic_Data/Baseline_Data_Files/ProjectedRealGDPValues.xls

  • UNFCCC (2015) COP21 Final Draft Retrieved from: http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2015/cop21/eng/l09.pdf

  • UNFCCC (2016a) Report of the conference of the parties on its twenty-first session. Addendum part two: action taken by the conference of the parties, and decisions adopted by the conference of the parties. Retrieved from: http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2015/cop21/eng/10a01.pdf

  • UNFCCC (2016b) Submitted INDCs Retrieved from: http://unfccc.int/focus/indc_portal/items/8766.php

  • United Nations (2016) Country profiles. United Nations Statistics Division. Accessed 22 Feb 2016. http://data.un.org/CountryProfile.aspx

  • Upton J (2015) The $100 billion climate question. Climate central. Retrieved from: http://www.climatecentral.org/news/the-100-billion-climate-question-19726

  • van der Zwaan BCC, Gerlagh R, Klaassen G, Schrattenholzer L (2002) Endogenous technological change in climate change modelling. Energy Econ 24(1):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandyck T, Keramidas K, Saveyn B, Kitous A, Vrontisi Z (2016) A global Stocktake of the Paris pledges: implications for energy systems and economy. Glob Environ Chang 41:46–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Victor D, House J, Joy S (2005) A Madisonian approach to climate policy. Science 309(5742):1820–1821

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S, de Gouvello C (2015) Marginal abatement cost curves and the quality of emission reductions: a case study on Brazil. Clim Pol 15(6):703–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West JJ, Smith SJ, Silva RA, Naik V, Zhang Y, Adelman Z, Fry MM, Anenberg S, Horowitz LW, Lamarque J-F (2013) Co-benefits of mitigating global greenhouse gas emissions for future air quality and human health. Nat Clim Chang 3:885–889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westphal M, Hughes G, Brömmelhörster J (2013) Economics of climate change in East Asia. Asian Development Bank, Mandaluyong City, Philippines Available at: https://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/publication/30434/economics-climate-change-east-asia.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2010) Generating the Funding Needed for Mitigation and Adaptation. Ch. 6 in World Development Report: Development and Climate Change. The World Bank, Washington, DC. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2010/Resources/5287678-1226014527953/WDR10-Full-Text.pdf

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are, respectively, Research Professor, Research Assistant Professor, and Graduate Research Assistant, in the Sol Price School of Public Policy, University of Southern California; Scientific / Technical Support Officer, European Commission Joint Research Centre, Seville. We wish to thank Joshua Banks for his valuable assistance in compiling the data, and to Antonio Bento and Christian Flachsland for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this paper. We also acknowledge the valuable comments of Editor Stephane Hallegatte and two anonymous reviewers. The views expressed are purely those of the authors and may not in any circumstances be regarded as stating an official position of the European Commission or the University of Southern California.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam Rose.

Appendices

Appendix A. Basic Data

Table 6 presents the GHG emission reduction commitments for Year 2030 for 90 countries that made unconditional commitments at COP21 that could be quantified in terms of percentage emission reductions. Commitments for several counties needed to be translated from other base years (e.g., 15% below Year 2005 levels) and adjusted to Year 2030 mission projections.

Table 6 Unconditional GHG mitigation pledges, 2030
Table 7. Mapping of 90 Countries into 15 Regions
Table 8 Parameter estimates for 15 regional MAC curves

When calculating each country’s pledge to reduce emissions, data were first collected from their Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC) as submitted for the COP21 proceedings. This included their total GHG emissions in the Base year, projected business-as-usual (BAU) emissions, and any amount of pledged reduction. The pledges were then standardized as both a total and percentage reduction from a 2030 BAU scenario. Conditional and unconditional pledges were calculated separately as indicated in the country’s INDC. In Table 6, we present only the unconditional pledge data that are used in this analysis.

Given that not all countries conformed to the same baseline or projected year for their BAU emissions, nor the same way of measuring emissions or reductions, we first standardized each county to a 2030 BAU projection from which we then calculated their emission reduction target in both absolute and percentage terms. For example, if a country measured their emissions intensity (mtCO2e/GDP) or emissions per capita, we used current and 2030 projected GDP and population numbers to translate these into absolute and percentage terms. In some cases, the GDP and population projections were included in the INDC; in cases where they were not, projections were adopted from the U.S. Census Bureau (2015) and Live Population (2016) for population, and the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Economic Research Service (2015) for GDP.

Additionally, if a country provided its information in a year pre-2030, we assume that the pledge would hold as-is through 2030. If, however, a country provided their information in a post-2030 year, we linearly extrapolated backwards using either their current baseline emissions, or, if provided, an intermediate goal set forth in their INDC. For example, some countries offered both a final 2035 goal and an intermediate 2025 goal, which were averaged to calculate their approximate 2030 goal. Further complicating the issue, a few countries’ INDC’s did not provide exact numerical data, only graphs of their emissions and reduction levels. In these cases we used our best judgment to infer values from the graphs when they were drawn to-scale. If no numbers or graphs were reported for baseline or BAU emissions, values were adopted from the Climate Equity Reference Project (CERP 2016).

Appendix B. Marginal Abatement Cost Curves

The base GEM-E3 model contains 13 regions, with the Rest of World (ROW) region comprised of some very different countries with respect to GHG emissions and access to mitigation technologies. To account for this, we separate out two additional regions from ROW: Singapore and South Korea (SSK), and Mexico and South America (MSA). SSK’s MAC curve is approximated by a 50/50 split of the AUZ and JPN curves, while MSA’s MAC curve is approximated at 80% of the BRA curve. The new ROW curve is then re-approximated by pulling out the emissions-weighted SSK and MSA curves from the original ROW curve. Table 8 lists each region and its respective MAC curve parameter estimates.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rose, A., Wei, D., Miller, N. et al. Equity, Emissions Allowance Trading and the Paris Agreement on Climate Change. EconDisCliCha 1, 203–232 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41885-017-0012-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41885-017-0012-3

Keywords

Navigation