Skip to main content
Log in

Price–quality relationship in the presence of asymmetric dynamic reference quality effects

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The purpose of this study is to examine the relationship between price and reference quality and their combined effect on profits. An analytical modeling approach aimed at solving the optimal solution for the profit maximization problem under these conditions is developed, enabling the exact path of the optimal price and quality over time to be depicted. Based on separating the effects of price and reference quality on demand, this analysis also provides insight into the contribution of these two effects to the steady-state solution through elasticities. Our results show that a monotonic inverse relationship exists between price and quality, such that a steady-state level is obtained where the quality–price ratio is lower when reference quality effects exist than when such effects do not exist. In other words, consumers obtain higher quality for a higher price but with a lower price per unit of quality. Overall, accounting for reference quality effects will increase a firm’s profits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. If the quality is held constant, q(t) = q, then the reference quality can be written as \(r(q)=q+\left( r_{q}^{0}-q\right) e^{-\beta t}\) and the exponential term e  − βt reaches a very small value if \(t>3/\beta =3 \hat{T}_{\rm RQ}\) because e  − 3 ≈ 0.05.

  2. Hereafter, we assume the regularity condition a − δ 2 c > 0.

  3. The parameters we use are: \(a=10,\gamma =0.7,\delta _{1}=0.5,\delta _{2}=1,c=1,\beta =2,\alpha =0.1,r_{q}^{0}\) takes the values 3.4 (lower curves) or 0.1 (upper curves).

  4. The time unit of convergence towards a steady-state condition (see footnote 1)

  5. Observe that since m > β, it follows that \(T_{\rm RQ}<\hat{T}_{\rm RQ}\) where \( \hat{T}_{\rm RQ}=1/\beta \) is the time scale of the reference effects defined below Eq. 1.

  6. The parameters we use are: a = 10, δ 1 = 1.5, δ 2 = 2, γ = 1.5, c = 1, β = 0.1, α = 0.1 and \(r_{q}^{0}=3.5\).

References

  • Bass, F. M. (1969). A new product growth model for consumer durables. Management Science, 15, 215–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Consumer Reports (2009). Available at: http://www.consumerreports.org/cro/magazine-archive/december-2009/home-garden/paper-towels/overview/paper-towels-ov.htm.

  • Fershtman, C., & Kamien, M. I. (1987). Dynamic duopolistic competition with sticky prices. Econometrica, 55, 1151–1164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fibich, G., Gavious, A., & Lowengart, O. (2003). Explicit solutions of optimization models and differential games with nonsmooth (asymmetric) reference-price effects. Operations Research, 51(5), 721–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fibich, G., Gavious, A., & Lowengart, O. (2005). The dynamics of price elasticity of demand in the presence of reference price effects. Journal of The Academy of Marketing Science, 33(1), 66–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fibich, G., Gavious, A., & Lowengart, O. (2007). Optimal price promotion in the presence of asymmetric reference-price effects. Managerial and Decision Economics, 28, 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerstner, E. (1985). Do higher prices signal higher quality? Journal of Marketing, 22, 209–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenleaf, E. A. (1995). The impact of reference price effects on the profitability of price promotions. Marketing Science, 14, 82–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardie, B. G. S., Johnson, E. J., & Fader, P. S. (1993). Modeling loss aversion and reference dependence effects on brnad choice. Marketing Science, 12, 378–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalyanaram, G., & Little. J. D. C. (1994). An empirical analysis of latitude price acceptance in consumer package goods. Journal of Consumer Research, 21, 408–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M. I., & Schwartz N. L. (1991). Dynamic optimization: The calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management. New York: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kopalle, P. K., Rao, A. C., & Assuncao, J. L. (1996). Asymmetric reference price effects and dynamic pricing policies. Marketing Science, 15, 60–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopalle, P. K., & Winer, R. S. (1996). A dynamic model of reference price and expected quality. Marketing Letters, 7(1), 41–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lattin, J. M., & Bucklin, R. E. (1989). Reference effects of price and promotion on brand choice behavior. Journal of Marketing Research, 26, 229–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowengart, O. (2002). Reference price conceptualizations: An integrative framework of analysis. Journal of Marketing Management, 18(1–2), 145–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monroe, K. B., & Dodds, W. B. (1988). A research program for establishing the validity of the price–quality relationship. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 16(1), 151–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narasimhan, R., & Mendez, D. (2001). Strategic aspects of quality: A theoretical analysis. Production and Operations Management, 10(4), 514–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paulson Gjerde, K. A., & Slotnick, S. A. (2004). Quality and reputation: The effects of external and internal factors over time. International Journal of Production Economics, 89, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorger, G. (1988). Reference price formation and optimal pricing strategies. In G. Feichtinger (Ed.) Optimal control theory and economic analysis 3 (pp. 97–120). Amsterdam: Elsevier (North Holland).

    Google Scholar 

  • Starr, A. W., & Ho, Y. C. (1969). Nonzero-sum differential games. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 3, 184–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion and riskless choice: A reference dependence model. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 106, 1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winer, R. S. (1986). Reference price model of brand choice for frequently purchased products. Journal of Consumer Research, 13, 250–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winer, R. S. (1988). Behavioral perspective on pricing: buyers’ subjective perceptions of price revisited. In T. M. Devinney (Ed.), Issues in pricing: Theory and research.. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This research was supported by The Israel Science Foundation (grant No. 285/07)

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Oded Lowengart.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1

The current value Hamiltonian is given by

$$ H=\left(p(t)-c\right)Q(t)-q^{2}(t)+\lambda \beta \left(q(t)-r_{q}(t)\right)~. $$

Therefore, the first-order conditions for optimality are

$$ \frac{\partial H}{\partial p} =a+\delta _{1}q-2\delta _{2}p+\gamma \left(q-r_{q}\right)+\delta _{2}c=0~, $$
(18)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial q} =(p-c)\left(\delta _{1}+\gamma \right)-2q+\lambda \beta =0~,$$
(19)
$$\begin{array}{rll}\frac{d\lambda }{\textrm{d}t} &=&\alpha \lambda -\frac{\partial H}{\partial r_{q}} ~=\left(\alpha +\beta \right)\lambda +\gamma (p-c),\\ \frac{\textrm{d}r_{q}}{\textrm{d}t} &=&\beta \left(q-r_{q}\right)~, \end{array} $$

with the initial condition \(r_{q}(0)={r_{q}^{0}}\) and the assumption that lim t→ ∞  p(t) < ∞. In steady-state \(\frac{d\lambda }{\textrm{d}t}=0\) and thus, λ in steady-state \(\lambda _{\rm ss}=-\frac{\gamma }{ \alpha +\beta }(p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}-c)\). Furthermore, in steady-state \( q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}=r_{q}^{\rm ss}\). Substituting λ ss in Eq. 19 and solving with Eq. 19 gives Eq. 11. The above equations are reduced to a linear differential equation that can be easily solved to get Eqs. 9 and 10. However, to avoid excessive detail, we note that substitution of Eqs. 9 and 10 in the above equations shows that Eqs. 9 and 10 is indeed the solution.

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 4

This proof will show that under asymmetric conditions, optimal price and quality paths will not create a situation in which consumers’ evaluation of these variables will switch from gains to losses or vice versa. We use the technique introduced in Fibich et al. (2003) for that purpose. Throughout this proof, the notations q optimal(t), p optimal(t) represent the optimal solution for the symmetric problem given by Eqs. 9 and 10. To prove this proposition, we will need the following three lemmas.

Lemma 1

The steady-state quality, \(q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss},\) given in Eq.  11 is a monotonic increasing function of γ .

Proof

Differentiating \(q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\gamma )\) with respect to γ gives

$$ \frac{d}{\textrm{d}\gamma }q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\gamma )=\frac{4\left(a-\delta _{2}c\right)\frac{ \alpha }{\alpha +\beta }\delta _{2}}{\left[ 4\delta _{2}-\delta _{1}^{2}-\delta _{1}\gamma \frac{\alpha }{\alpha +\beta }\right] ^{2}}>0. $$

Lemma 2

\(\left( q_{\rm optimal}(t)-r_{q}(t)\right) \) does not change this sign for any t .

Proof

From Eqs. 9 and 12, we have

$$ q_{optimal}(t)-r_{q}(t)=-\frac{m}{\beta }\left(r_{q}^{0}-q^{\rm ss}\right)e^{-mt} $$

which has a constant sign.□

Let us denote the profits under any quality–price strategy q(t), p(t) by

$$ g(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q(t),p(t)):=\int_{0}^{\infty }e^{-\alpha t} \bigg[(p(t)-c)Q(t)-q^{2}(t)\bigg]\,\textrm{d}t~, $$

where Q is given by Eq. 5 and γ is given by Eq. 6 and define

$$ G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss}\right):=\sup_{q(t),p(t)}g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q(t),p(t)\right)~. $$
(20)

Lemma 3

$$ G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss}\right)\leq G\left(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma}\right)\text{ \ \ \ \ for all }\gamma _{\rm gain}\leq \tilde{\gamma}\leq \gamma _{\rm loss}.\qquad \label{eq:GG} $$
(21)

Proof

The function g(γ gain, γ loss; q(t), p(t)) increases monotonically in γ gain and decreases monotonically in γ loss. Thus,

$$ g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q(t),p(t)\right)\leq g\left(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma };q(t),p(t)\right) \quad \text{for all }\gamma _{\rm gain}\leq \tilde{\gamma}\leq \gamma _{\rm loss}. $$
(22)

Then, by Eq. 22 we have that

$$ \sup_{q(t),p(t)}g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q(t),p(t)\right) \! \leq \! \sup_{q(t),p(t)}g\left(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma};q(t),p(t)\right) \ \ \ \text{for all }\gamma _{gain} \! \leq \! \tilde{\gamma} \! \leq \! \gamma _{\rm loss}, $$
(23)
  1. 1.

    and since the right hand side of Eq. 23 is G(γ gain, γ loss) and the left hand side of Eq. 23 is \(G( \tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma})\) we get

    $$ G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss}\right)\leq G(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma})\text{ \ \ \ \ for all }\gamma _{\rm gain}\leq \tilde{\gamma}\leq \gamma _{\rm loss}.\qquad $$

We now turn to proving the proposition in which we have three possible cases with respect to the relationship between the initial reference quality \( r_{q}^{0}\) and the steady-state quality level q ss:

  1. 1.

    We start with the first case and show that if \(r_{q}^{0}<q^{\rm ss}(\gamma _{\rm gain})\) then, q optimal(t), p optimal(t) given by Eqs. 9 and 12 with γ = γ gain is the optimal solution for the asymmetric case. As we show by Lemma 2, \(\left( q_{\rm optimal}(t)-r_{q}(t)\right) \) does not change its sign and thus, substituting γ = γ gain in q optimal(t) we have that q optimal(t) ≥ r q (t) for all t ≥ 0. Therefore,

    $$\begin{array}{rll} g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q_{\rm optimal}(t),p_{\rm optimal}(t)\right) &=& g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm gain};q_{\rm optimal}(t),p_{\rm optimal}(t)\right) \\ &=& G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm gain}\right) \end{array} $$
    (24)

    where the last equality follows because g(γ gain, γ gain; q optimal(t), p optimal(t)) is symmetric in γ. Thus, q optimal(t), p optimal(t) is the optimal strategy that maximizes g. On the other hand, from Eq. 20 and the monotonicity of G(γ gain, γ loss) given by Lemma 3 we have that

    $$ g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q_{\rm optimal}(t),p_{\rm optimal}(t)\right)\leq G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss}\right)\leq G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm gain}\right). $$
    (25)

    Combining Eqs. 24 and 25 yields

    $$ g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};q_{\rm optimal}(t),p_{\rm optimal}(t)\right)=G\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss}\right)~, $$

    which proves that the symmetric solution q optimal(t), p optimal(t) with γ gain is the optimal solution for the asymmetric problem.

  2. 2.

    The second case is where \(r_{q}^{0}>q^{\rm ss}(\gamma _{\rm gain})\). Then, q optimal(t), p optimal(t) given by Eqs. 9 and 12 with γ = γ loss is the optimal solution for the asymmetric case is proved similarly.

  3. 3.

    Last, we show that for the case where \(q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\gamma _{\rm loss})\leq r_{0}\leq q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\gamma _{\rm gain})\), then \(q(t)\equiv r_{q}(t)\equiv {r_{q}^{0}}\) and \(p(t)=p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\tilde{\gamma})\) for specific \(\tilde{\gamma}\) is the optimal solution for the asymmetric case. Let \(\tilde{\gamma}\) be the solution to \(q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\tilde{\gamma})={ r_{q}^{0}}\). By the monotonicity of \(q_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\gamma )\) given in Lemma 1 there exists \(\tilde{\gamma}\), \(\gamma _{\rm gain}\leq \tilde{\gamma}\leq \gamma _{\rm loss}\) that solves this equation. Therefore, when we use \(q(t)={r_{q}^{0}}\) and \(p(t)=p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\tilde{ \gamma})\) there is no loss or gain and thus,

    $$ g\left(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};{r_{q}^{0}},p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}\left(\tilde{\gamma} \right)\right)=g\left(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma};{r_{q}^{0}},p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}\left(\tilde{\gamma }\right)\right)=G\left(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma}\right)~. $$

    On the other hand, \(g(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss};{r_{q}^{0}} ,p_{\rm optimal}^{\rm ss}(\tilde{\gamma}))\leq G(\gamma _{\rm gain},\gamma _{\rm loss})\leq G(\tilde{\gamma},\tilde{\gamma})\). Combining the last two relationships gives g(γ gain,γ loss;p optimal(t)) = G(γ gain,γ loss).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gavious, A., Lowengart, O. Price–quality relationship in the presence of asymmetric dynamic reference quality effects. Mark Lett 23, 137–161 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-011-9143-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-011-9143-4

Keywords

Navigation